Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-7479d7b7d-q6k6v Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-11T22:19:04.176Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

15 - The Transatlantic Slave Trade and the Evolution of Political Authority in West Africa

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 September 2014

Warren C. Whatley
Affiliation:
University of Michigan
Emmanuel Akyeampong
Affiliation:
Harvard University, Massachusetts
Robert H. Bates
Affiliation:
Harvard University, Massachusetts
Nathan Nunn
Affiliation:
Harvard University, Massachusetts
James Robinson
Affiliation:
Harvard University, Massachusetts
Get access

Summary

Since the publication of Douglas North’s Structure and Change in Economic History (1981), social scientists have accumulated an abundance of new evidence showing how institutions shape the structures and performance of economies as they move through time. African economies are no exception. The term patrimonial (or neo-patrimonial) is controversial, but it is often used to describe a class of postcolonial African nation-states where a weak federal authority attempts to rule over ethnically based local authorities. Political stability often rests on an unstable coalition of patrons and clients who extract large amounts of national income through personal networks, intimidation, corruption, and bribes. In these kinds of “failed states,” public policy is influenced more by a political calculation to retain the privileges of power than by the political authorities’ credibly committed to improve growth and welfare. The recent spread of democratic institutions like multiparty politics has improved accountability, but stability and violence are often more pressing concerns. It is difficult for people to prosper under this kind of uncertainty, unless of course they have access to a personal network of patrons and clients that defines the resources available to them.

What are the historical origins of this type of political system? The traditional view links it to the era of colonial rule and how it birthed a disjointed and decentralized nation-state. Mamdani (1996) is perhaps the best-known proponent of this view. He sees the most important political outcome of colonial rule to be a kind of dual legal system – European laws for colonial rulers and a variety of “customary” laws for colonial “subjects.” In a very real sense, the postcolonial nation-state is the colonial state adjusted to new political realities like democratic elections, new global economic forces, stronger internal challenges, and mounting international debt.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2014

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, Daron and Johnson, Simon. (2005). “Unbundling Institutions.” Journal of Political Economy, 113(5): 949–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Johnson, Simon, and Robinson, James A.. (2002). “Reversal of Fortune: Geography and Institutions in Making of Modern World Income Distribution.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117: 1231–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Johnson, Simon, and Robinson, James A.. (2001). “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation.” American Economic Review, 91(5): 1369–1401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Albouy, David. (2013). “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation: A Comment.” American Economic Review, 102(6): 3059–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. (2004). “Path Dependence and Competitive Equilibrium.” In History Matters: Essays in Economic Growth, Technology and Demographic Change, edited by Guinnane, Timothy W., Sundstrom, William A., and Whatley, Warren C., 23–35. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Austen, Ralph A. (1979). “The Trans-Saharan Slave Trade: A Tentative Census.” In The Uncommon Market: Essays in the Economic History of the Atlantic Slave Trade, edited by Gemery, Henry. A. and Hogendorn, Jan. S., 23–75. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Austen, Ralph A. (1987). African Economic History: Internal Development and External Dependency. London: James Curry.Google Scholar
Austin, Gareth. (2008). “Resources, Techniques, and Strategies South of the Sahara: Revising the Factor Endowments Perspective on African Economic Development, 1500–2000.” Economic History Review, 61: 587–624.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barry, Boubacar. (1998). Senegambia and the Atlantic Slave Trade. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bates, Robert. (2008). When Things Fell Apart: State Failure in Late-Century Africa. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bates, Robert. (2010). Prosperity and Violence: The Political Economy of Development. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Bates, Robert, Greif, Avner, and Singh, Smita. (2002). “Organizing Violence.” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46(5): 599–628.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bean, Richard. (1974). “A Note on the Relative Importance of Slaves and Gold in West African Exports.” The Journal of African History, 5(3): 351–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bertocchi, G. and Canova, F. (2002). “Did Colonization Matter for Growth? An Empirical Exploration into the Causes of Africa’s Underdevelopment.” European Economic Review 46(10): 1851–1871.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boone, C. (2003). Political Topographies of the African State: Territorial Authority and Institutional Choice. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chabal, Patrick and Daloz, Jean-Pascal. (1999). Africa Works: Disorder as Political Instrument. Bloomington: Indiana University Press.Google Scholar
Daaku, Kwame Yeboa. (1970). Trade and Politics on the Gold Coast, 1600–1720: A Study of the African Reaction to European Trade. London: Clarendon.Google Scholar
David, Paul. (1985). “Clio and the Economics of Qwerty.” American Economic Review, 76: 332–7.Google Scholar
Davidson, Basil. (1992). The Black Man’s Burden: Africa and the Curse of the Nation-State. New York: Three Rivers Press.Google Scholar
Ekeh, Peter P. (1975). “Colonialism and the Two Publics in Africa: A Theoretical Statement.” Comparative Studies in Society and History, 17(1): 91–112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ekeh, Peter P. (1990). “Social Anthropology and Two Contrasting Uses of Tribalism in Africa.” Comparative Studies in Society and History, 32(4): 660–700.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eltis, David. (1994). “The Relative Importance of Slaves and Commodities in the Atlantic Trade of Seventeenth-Century Africa.” Journal of African History, 35(2): 237–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eltis, David. (2009). Voyages Database. Voyages: The Transatlantic Slave Trade Database. (accessed October 1, 2010).
Eltis, David, Behrendt, Stephen D., Richardson, David, and Klein, Herbert S.. (1999). The Trans-Atlantic Slave Trade: A Database on CD-Rom. London: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Eltis, David and Jennings, Lawrence C.. (1988). “Trade between West Africa and the Atlantic World in the Pre-Colonial Era.” American Historical Review, 9(4): 936–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eltis, David and Richardson, David. (2004). “Prices of African Slaves Newly Arrived in the Americas, 1673–1865: New Evidence on Long-Run Trends and Regional Differentials.” In Slavery in the Development of the Americas, edited by Eltis, David, Lewis, Frank. D., and Sockoloff, Kenneth. L., 181–218. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Englebert, Pierre. (2000). “Pre-Colonial Institutions, Post-Colonial States, and Economic Development in Tropical Africa.” Political Science Research Quarterly, 53(1): 7–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fage, John. (1980). “Slaves and Society in Western Africa C.1445-C.1700.” Journal of African History, 21(3): 289–310.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fenske, James. (2010). “The Causal History of Africa: A Response to Hopkins.” Economic History of Developing Regions, 25(2): 177–212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Firmin-Sellers, Kathryn. (2000). “Institutions, Context, and Outcomes: Explaining French and British Rule in West Africa.” Comparative Politics, 32(3): 253–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, Humphrey. (2001). Slavery in the History of Muslim Black Africa. London: Hurst and Company.Google Scholar
Gemery, Henry A. and Hogendorn, Jan S.. (1979). “The Economic Cost of West African Participation in the Atlantic Slave Trade: A Preliminary Sampling for the Eighteenth Century.” In The Uncommon Market: Essays in the Economic History of the Atlantic Slave Trade, edited by Gemery, H. A. and Hogendorn, J. S.. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Gemery, Henry and Hogendorn, Jan. (1990). “Evidence on English/African Terms of Trade and 18th Century.” Explorations in Economic History, 27: 157–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gennaioli, Nicola and Rainer, Ilia. (2007). “The Modern Impact of Precolonial Centralization in Africa.” Journal of Economic Growth, 12: 185–234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glaeser, Edward L. and Shleifer, Andrei. (2002). “Legal Origins.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4): 1193–1229.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Graham, James. (1965). “The Slave Trade, Depopulation and Human Sacrifice in Benin History: The General Approach.” Cahiers d’Etudes Africaines, 5(18): 317–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grief, Avner. (1989). “Reputation and Coalition in Medieval Trade: Evidence on the Maghribi Traders.” Journal of Economic History, 49(4): 857–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grief, Avner. (1994). “On the Political Foundations of the Late Medieval Commercial Revolution: Genoa during the Twelfth and Thirteenth Centuries.” Journal of Economic History, 54(4): 217–87.Google Scholar
Grief, Avner. (2006). Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herbst, Jeffrey. (2000). States and Power in Africa: Comparative Lessons in Authority and Control. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hopkins, Anthony. (1973). An Economic History of West Africa. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
IIASA. (2010). “Global Agro-Ecological Assessment for Agriculture in the 21st Century: Methodology and Results.” (Accessed October 1, 2010).
Iliffe, John. (2007). Africans: The History of a Continent. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Inikori, J., Ed. (1982). Forced Migration: The Impact of the Slave Trade on African Societies. New York, Africana Publishing Company.Google Scholar
Inikori, J. (2003). “The Struggle Against the Transatlantic Slave Trade: The Role of the State.” In Fighting the Slave Trade: West African Strategies. Diouf, S. A., (ed.). Athens, Ohio University Press.Google Scholar
Grier, R. M. (1999). “Colonial Legacy and Economic Growth.” Public Choice 98(3): 317–335.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iyer, Lakshmi. (2010). “Direct Versus Indirect Colonial Rule in India: Long-Term Consequences.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(4): 693–713.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
La Porta, Rafael, Lopez-de-Silanes, Florencio, and Shleifer, Andrei. (2008). “The Economic Consequences of Legal Origin.” Journal of Economic Literature, 46(2): 285–332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lange, Matthew. (2004). “British Colonial Legacy and Political Development.” World Development, 32(6): 905–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lange, Matthew. (2009). Lineages of Despotism and Development: British Colonialism and State Power. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Law, R. (1991). The Slave Coast of West Africa, 1550–1750 : The Impact of the Atlantic Slave Trade on an African Society. Oxford, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Lovejoy, Paul E. (2004). Slavery on the Frontiers of Islam. Princeton, NJ: Markus Wiener Publishers.Google Scholar
Mamdani, Mahmood, ed. (1996). Citizen and Subject: Contemporary Africa and the Legacy of Late Colonialism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Manning, Patrick. (1990). Slavery and African Life: Occidental, Oriental, and African Slave Trades. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
McEvedy, Colin and Jones, Richard. (1978). Atlas of World Population History. Harmondsworth: Penguin.Google Scholar
Michalopoulos, Stelios and Papaioannou, Elias. (2010). “Divide and Rule or the Rule of the Divided? Evidence from Africa.” Discussion Paper Series No. 8088. Center for Economic Policy Research.CrossRef
Michalopoulos, Stelios and Papaioannou, Elias. (2011). “The Long-Run Effects of the Scramble for Africa.” NBER Working Paper No. 17620.CrossRef
Murdock, G. P. (1949). Social Structure. New York, Macmillan Co.Google Scholar
Murdock, George P. (1967). Ethnographic Atlas. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.Google Scholar
North, Douglas. (1981). Structure and Change in Economic History. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Nunn, Nathan. (2008). “The Long Term Effects of Africa’s Slave Trades.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(1): 139–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nunn, Nathan. (2009). “The Importance of History for Economic Development.” Annual Review of Economics, 1: 65–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nunn, Nathan and Puga, Diego. (2012). “Ruggedness: The Blessings of Bad Geography in Africa.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 94(1): 20–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nunn, Nathan and Wantchekon, Leonard. (2011). “The Slave Trade and the Origins of Mistrust in Africa.” American Economic Review, 111(7): 3221–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olsson, Ola. (2009). “On the Democratic Legacy of Colonialism.” Journal of Comparative Economics, 37: 534–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patterson, Orlando. (1982). Slavery and Social Death: A Comparative Study. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Pitcher, Anne, Moran, Mary H., and Johnston, Michael. (2009). “Rethinking Patrimonialism and Neopatrimonialism in Africa.” African Studies Review, 52(1): 125–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Price, G. N. (2003). “Economic Growth in a Cross-Section of Nonindustrial Countries: Does Colonial Heritage matter for Africa?Review of Development Economics 7: 478–495.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Radelet, Steven. (2010). Emerging Africa: How 17 Countries Are Leading the Way. Washington, DC: Center for Global Development.Google Scholar
Rattray, Capt. R. S. (1929). Ashanti Law and Constitution. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Richardson, David. (1991). “Prices of Slaves in West and West Central Africa: Towards an Annual Series, 1698–1807.” Bulletin of Economic Research, 43(1): 21–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, J. A. (2002). “States and Power in Africa by Jeffrey I. Herbst: A Review Essay.” Journal of Economic Literature 40(2): 510–519.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodney, Walter. (1966). “African Slavery and Other Forms of Social Oppression on the Upper Guinea Coast in the Context of the Atlantic Slave Trade.” Journal of African History, 7(3): 431–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodney, Walter. (1972). How Europe Underdeveloped Africa. London: Bogle-L’Ouverture Publications.Google Scholar
Ryder, Alan F. (1969). Benin and the Europeans, 1485–1897. New York: Humanities Press.Google Scholar
Thornton, John K. (1999). Warfare in Atlantic Africa, 1500–1800. London: UCL Press.Google Scholar
UNESCO. (2010). “Unep Sioux Falls Clearninghouse.” . (Accessed October 1, 2010).
USGS. (2010). “Usgs Geographic Data Download.” . (Accessed October 1, 2010).
Van de Walle, Nicolas. (2001). African Economies and the Politics of Permanent Crisis, 1979–1999. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whatley, Warren and Gillezeau, Rob. (2011a). “The Fundamental Impact of the Slave Trade on African Economies.” In Economic Evolution and Revolution in Historical Time, edited by Rhode, Paul, Rosenbloom, Joshua, and Weiman, David, 86–110 . Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Whatley, Warren and Gillezeau, Rob. (2011b). “The Impact of the Slave Trade on Ethnic Stratification in Africa.” American Economic Review, 101(3): 571–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilks, Ivor. (1975). Asante in the Nineteenth Century: The Structure and Evolution of a Political Order. London, New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Wilks, Ivor. (1982). “Wangara, Akan and Portuguese in the 15th and 16th Centuries, II: The Struggle for Trade.” The Journal of African History, 23(4): 463–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilks, Ivor. (1993). Forests of Gold: Essays on the Akan and the Kingdom of Asante. Athens: Ohio University Press.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×