Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-75dct Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-30T12:55:55.889Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 November 2014

Brian Skyrms
Affiliation:
University of California, Irvine
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2014

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alexander, J. M. (2007). The Structural Evolution of Morality. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alexander, J. M., and Skyrms, B. (1999). “Bargaining with Neighbors: Is Justice Contagious?” The Journal of Philosophy 96:588–98.Google Scholar
Alexander, J. M., Skyrms, B., and Zabell, S. L. (2012). “Inventing New Signals.” Dynamic Games and Applications 2:129–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arbuthnot, J. (1710). “An Argument for Divine Providence, Taken from the Constant Regularity Observ’d in the Births of Both Sexes.” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society of London 27:186–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Argiento, R., Pemantle, R., Skyrms, B., and Volkov, S. (2009). “Learning to Signal: Analysis of a Micro-Level Reinforcement Model.” Stochastic Processes and their Applications 119: 373–419.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aristotle, (1985). Nicomachean Ethics Trans. Irwin, Terence. Indianapolis: Hackett.Google Scholar
Aumann, R. J. (1974). “Subjectivity and Correlation in Randomized Strategies.” Journal of Mathematical Economics 1:67–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aumann, R. J. (1987). “Correlated Equilibrium as an Expression of Bayesian Rationality.” Econometrica 55:1–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Axelrod, R. (1981). “The Emergence of Cooperation Among Egoists.” American Political Science Review 75:306–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Axelrod, R. (1984). The Evolution of Cooperation. New York: Basic.Google Scholar
Axelrod, R. (1997). “The Evolution of Strategies in the Iterated Prisoner’s Dilemma.” In The Dynamics of Norms. Ed. Bicchieri, C., Jeffrey, R., and Skyrms, B.New York: Cambridge University Press, 1–16.Google Scholar
Axelrod, R., and Hamilton, W. D. (1981). “The Evolution of Cooperation.” Science 211:1,390–6.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bala, V., and Goyal, S. (2000). “A Non-cooperative Model of Network Formation.” Econometrica 68:1181–229.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barry, B. (1989). Theories of Justice. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Bartos, O. (1978). “Negotiation and Justice.” Contributions to Experimental Economics 7:103–26.Google Scholar
Bergstrom, T. (2002). “Evolution of Social Behavior: Individual and Group Selection Models.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 16:231–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bergstrom, T. (2003). “The Algebra of Assortative Encounters and the Evolution of Cooperation.” International Game Theory Review. 5:1–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bicchieri, C. (1990). “Norms of Cooperation.” Ethics 100:838–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bicchieri, C. (1993). Rationality and Coordination. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bicchieri, C. (2006). The Grammar of Society: The Nature and Dynamics of Social Norms. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Binmore, K. (1993). Game Theory and the Social Contract I: Playing Fair. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Binmore, K. (1998). Game Theory and the Social Contract II: Just Playing. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Binmore, K. (2005). Natural Justice. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, K., Morgan, P., Shaked, A., and Sutton, J. (1991). “Do People Exploit Their Bargaining Power? An Experimental Study.” Games and Economic Behavior 3:295–322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, K., and Samuelson, L. (1992). “Evolutionary Stability in Repeated Games Played by Finite Automata.” Journal of Economic Theory 57:278–305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, K., Samuelson, L., and Young, P. (2003). “Equilibrium Selection in Bargaining Models.” Games and Economic Behavior 45:296–328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, K., Shaked, A., and Sutton, J. (1985). “Testing Non-Cooperative Bargaining Theory: A Preliminary Study.” American Economic Review 75:1,178–80.Google Scholar
Binmore, K., Shaked, A., and Sutton, J. (1988). “A Further Test of Non-Cooperative Bargaining Theory: Reply.” American Economic Review 78:837–9.Google Scholar
Bolton, G. (1991). “A Comparative Model for Bargaining: Theory and Evidence.” American Economic Review 81:1,096–136.Google Scholar
Bomze, I. (1986). “Non-Cooperative Two-Person Games in Biology: A Classification.” International Journal of Game Theory 15:31–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonacich, P., and Liggett, T. (2003). “Asymptotics of a Matrix Valued Markov Chain Arising in Sociology.” Stochastic Processes and their Applications 104:155–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borel, E. (1921). “La théorie de jeu et les équations intégrales à noyau symétrique.” Comptes Rendus de l’Académie des Sciences 173:1,304–8.Google Scholar
Boyce, W. E., and Di Prima, R. C. (1977). Elementary Differential Equations. 3rd ed. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Boyd, R., and Loberbaum, J. P. (1987). “No Pure Strategy Is Evolutionarily Stable in the Repeated Prisoner’s Dilemma Game.” Nature 327:59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boyd, R., and Richerson, P. (1985). Culture and the Evolutionary Process. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Boylan, R. T. (1992). “Laws of Large Numbers for Dynamical Systems with Randomly Matched Individuals.” Journal of Economic Theory 57:473–504.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Braithwaite, R. B. (1955). Theory of Games as a Tool for the Moral Philosopher. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bratman, M. (1987). Intention, Plans and Practical Reason. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Bratman, M. (1992). “Planning and the Stability of Intention.” Minds and Machines 2:1–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burgess, J. W. (1976). “Social Spiders.” Scientific American 234:100–6.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Busch, W. (1865). Max und Moritz: eine Bubengeschicte in sieben Streichen. Munchen: Braun und Schneider.Google Scholar
Cavalli-Sforza, L. L., and Feldman, M. (1981). Cultural Transmission and Evolution: A Quantitative Approach. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google ScholarPubMed
Charnov, E. (1982). The Theory of Sex Allocation. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google ScholarPubMed
Cheney, D. L., and Seyfarth, R. M. (1990). How Monkeys See the World. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Colinvaux, P. (1978). Why Big Fierce Animals Are Rare: An Ecologist’s Perspective. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Crawford, V. P. (1989). “Learning and Mixed Strategy Equilibria in Evolutionary Games.” Journal of Theoretical Biology 140:537–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crawford, V. P., and Sobel, J. (1982). “Strategic Information Transmission.” Econometrica 50:1431–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cubitt, R. P., and Sugden, R. (2003). “Common Knowledge, Salience and Convention: A reconstruction of David Lewis’ game theory.” Economics and Philosophy 19:175–210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Danielson, P. (1992). Artificial Morality: Virtuous Robots for Virtual Games. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
, Dante (1984). Paradiso Trans. Mandelbaum, Allen. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Darwin, C. (1859). On the Origin of Species. London: John Murray.Google Scholar
Darwin, C. (1871). The Descent of Man, and Selection in Relation to Sex. London: John Murray. 2nd ed. rev. 1898. New York: Appelton.Google Scholar
Davidson, D. (1984). Inquiries into Truth and Interpretation. Oxford: Oxford University Press (Clarendon Press).Google Scholar
Davies, N. B. (1978). “Territorial Defense in the Speckled Wood Butterfly.” Animal Behavior 26:138–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dawes, R., and Thaler, R. (1988). “Anomalies: Cooperation.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 2:187–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dawkins, R. (1983). The Extended Phenotype. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Dawkins, R. (1989). The Selfish Gene. 2nd ed. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Eells, E. (1982). Rational Decision and Causality. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eells, E. (1984). “Metatickles and the Dynamics of Deliberation.” Theory and Decision 17:71–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ellison, G. (1993). “Learning, Local Interaction and Coordination.” Econometrica 61:1047–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ellison, G. (2000). “Basins of Attraction, Long Run Stochastic Stability, and the Speed of Step-by-Step Evolution.” Review of Economic Studies 67:17–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eshel, I., and Cavalli-Sforza, L. L. (1982). “Assortment of Encounters and the Evolution of Cooperativeness.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, USA 79:1, 331–5.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Eshel, I., Samuelson, L., and Shaked, A. (1998). “Altruists, Egoists and Hooligans in a Local Interaction Model.” American Economic Review 88:157–79.Google Scholar
Fagen, R. M. (1980). “When Doves Conspire: Evolution of Nondamaging Fighting Tactics in a Nonrandom-Encounter Animal Conflict Model.” American Naturalist 115:858–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farrell, J. (1993). “Meaning and Credibility in Cheap-Talk Games.” Games and Economic Behavior 5:514–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farrell, J., and Ware, R. (1988). “Evolutionary Stability in the Repeated Prisoner’s Dilemma Game.” Theoretical Population Biology 36:161–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feldman, M., and Thomas, E. (1987). “Behavior-Dependent Contexts for Repeated Plays of the Prisoner’s Dilemma II: Dynamical Aspects of the Evolution of Cooperation.” Journal of Theoretical Biology 128:297–315.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fisher, R. A. (1930). The Genetical Theory of Natural Selection. Oxford: Oxford University Press (Clarendon Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Forsythe, R., Horowitz, J., Savin, N., and Sefton, M. (1988). “Replicability, Fairness and Pay in Experiments with Simple Bargaining Games.” Working paper, University of Iowa, Iowa City.
Foster, D., and Young, P. (1990). “Stochastic Evolutionary Game Dynamics.” Theoretical Population Biology 38:219–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, R. (1988). Passions Within Reason. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Frank, S. (1994). “Genetics of Mutualism: The Evolution of Altruism Between Species.” Journal of Theoretical Biology 170:393–400.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Frank, S. (1998). Foundations of Social Evolution. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, D. (1991). “Evolutionary Games in Economics.” Econometrica 59:637–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, D., and Maskin, E. (1986). “The Folk Theorem in Repeated Games with Discounting and with Complete Information.” Econometrica 54:533–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, D., and Maskin, E. (1990). “Evolution and Cooperation in Noisy Repeated Games.” American Economic Review 80:274–9.Google Scholar
Furrer, R. D., and Manser, M. B. (2009). “The Evolution of Urgency-Based and Functionally-Referential Alarm Calls in Ground-Dwelling Species.” American Naturalist 173:400–10.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gale, J., Binmore, K. L., and Samuelson, L. (1995). “Learning to be Imperfect: The Ultimatum Game.” Games and Economic Behavior 8:56–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gauthier, D. (1969). The Logic of the Leviathan. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Gauthier, D. (1985). “Bargaining and Justice.” Social Philosophy and Policy 2:29–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gauthier, D. (1986). Morals by Agreement. Oxford: Oxford University Press (Clarendon Press).Google Scholar
Gauthier, D. (1990). Moral Dealing: Contract, Ethics and Reason. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Gibbard, A. (1985). “Moral Judgement and the Acceptance of Norms.” Ethics 96:5–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gibbard, A. (1990a). “Norms, Discussion and Ritual: Evolutionary Puzzles.” Ethics 100:787–802.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gibbard, A. (1990b). Wise Choices, Apt Feelings: A Theory of Normative Judgement. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Gibbard, A. (1992). “Weakly Self-Ratifying Strategies: Comments on McClennen.” Philosophical Studies 65:217–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gibbard, A., and Harper, W. (1981). “Counterfactuals and Two Kinds of Expected Utility.” In IFS, ed. Harper, et al., pp. 153–90. Dordrecht: Reidel.Google Scholar
Gilbert, M. (1981). “Game Theory and Convention.” Synthese 46:41–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilbert, M. (1990). “Rationality, Coordination and Convention.” Synthese 84:1–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glass, L., and Mackey, M. (1988). From Clocks to Chaos: The Rhythms of Life. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Greif, A. (2006). Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons for Medieval Trade. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grice, H. P. (1957). “Meaning.” The Philosophical Review 66:372–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grim, P. (1993). “Greater Generosity Favored in a Spatialized Prisoner’s Dilemma.” Working paper, Dept. of Philosophy, SUNY, Stony Brook, N.Y.
Gross, T., and Sayama, H., eds. (2009). Adaptive Networks: Theory, Models and Applications. Berlin: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Güth, W. (1988). “On the Behavioral Approach to Distributive Justice – A Theoretical and Experimental Investigation.” In Applied Behavioral Economics. Vol. 2. Ed. Maital, S., pp. 703–17. New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
Güth, W., Schmittberger, R., and Schwarze, B. (1982). “An Experimental Analysis of Ultimatum Bargaining.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 3:367–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Güth, W., and Tietz, R. (1990). “Ultimatum Bargaining Behavior: A Survey and Comparison of Experimental Results.” Journal of Economic Psychology 11:417–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, W. D. (1963). “The Evolution of Altruistic Behavior.” American Naturalist 97:354–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, W. D. (1964). “The Genetical Evolution of Social Behavior.” Journal of Theoretical Biology 7:1–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, W. D. (1967). “Extraordinary Sex Ratios.” Science 156:477–88.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hamilton, W. D. (1971). “Selection of Selfish and Altruistic Behavior in Some Extreme Models.” In Man and Beast, ed. Eisenberg, J. F., and Dillon, W. S., pp. 59–91. Washington, D.C.: Smithsonian Institution Press.Google Scholar
Hamilton, W. D. (1975). “Innate Social Aptitudes of Man: An Approach from Evolutionary Genetics.” In Biosocial Anthropology, ed. Fox, R., pp. 133–53. London: Malaby Press.Google Scholar
Hamilton, W. D. (1980). “Sex Versus Non-Sex Versus Parasite.” Oikos 35:282–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, W. D. (1996). Narrow Roads of Gene Land. Oxford: W. H. Freeman.Google Scholar
Hampton, J. (1986). Hobbes and the Social Contract Tradition. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Harms, W. (1994). “Discrete Replicator Dynamics for the Ultimatum Game with Mutation and Recombination.” Technical report, University of California, Irvine.
Harms, W. (1997). “Evolution and Ultimatum Bargaining.” Theory and Decision 42:147–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harms, W. (2004). Information and Meaning in Evolutionary Processes. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harper, W. (1991). “Ratifiability and Refinements in Two-Person Noncooperative Games.” In Foundations of Game Theory: Issues and Advances, ed. Bacharach, M., and Hurley, S., pp. 263–93. Oxford: Blackwell Publisher.Google Scholar
Harper, W., Stalnaker, R., and Pearce, G., eds. (1981). IFS. Dordrecht: Reidel.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, J. (1953). “Cardinal Utility in Welfare Economics and the Theory of Risk Taking.” Journal of Political Economy 61:434–5.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, J. (1955). “Cardinal Welfare, Individualistic Ethics and Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility.” Journal of Political Economy 63:309–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, J. (1975). “Can the Maximin Principle Serve as a Basis for Morality?” American Political Science Review 69:594–606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, J. (1976). Essays in Ethics, Social Behavior and Scientific Explanation. Dordrecht: Reidel.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, J. (1977). Rational Behavior and Bargaining Equilibrium in Games and Social Situations. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, J. (1980). “Rule Utilitarianism, Rights, Obligations and the Theory of Rational Behavior.” Theory and Decision 12:115–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, J. (1982). Papers in Game Theory. Dordrecht: Reidel.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, J. C., and Selten, R. (1988). A General Theory of Equilibrium Selection in Games. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E., and Gintis, H.(2004). Foundations of Human Sociality: Experiments from 15 Small-Scale Societies. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E., Gintis, H., and McElreath, R. (2001). “In Search of Homo Economicus: Experiments in 15 Small-Scale Societies.” American Economic Review 91:73–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirsch, M. W., and Smale, S. (1974). Differential Equations, Dynamical Systems and Linear Algebra. San Diego, Calif.: Academic.Google Scholar
Hirshliefer, J. (1987). “On the Emotions as Guarantors of Threats and Promises.” In The Latest on the Best: Essays on Evolution and Optimality, ed. Dupré, J.Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Hirshliefer, J., and Martinez Coll, J. C. (1988). “What Strategies Can Support the Evolutionary Emergence of Cooperation?” Journal of Conflict Resolution 32:367–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hofbauer, J., and Huttegger, S. (2008). “Feasibility of Communication in Binary Signaling Games.” Journal of Theoretical Biology 254: 843–9.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hofbauer, J., and Sigmund, K. (1988). The Theory of Evolution and Dynamical Systems. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hoffman, E., McCabe, K., Shachat, K., and Smith, V. (1994). “Preferences, Property Rights and Anonymity in Bargaining Games.” Games and Economic Behavior 7:346–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holland, J. (1975). Adaptation in Natural and Artificial Systems. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Hu, Y., Skyrms, B., and Tarrès, P. (2011). “Reinforcement Learning in a Signaling Game” ArXiv.
Hume, D. (1739). A Treatise of Human Nature. London: John Noon.Google Scholar
Huttegger, S., Skyrms, B., Tarrès, P., and Wagner, E. (forthcoming). “Some Dynamics of Signaling Games. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the USA.
Huxley, T. H. (1888). “The Struggle for Existence and Its Bearing upon Man.” Nineteenth Century 23:161–80.Google Scholar
Jeffrey, R. (1965). The Logic of Decision. New York: McGraw-Hill. 2nd ed. rev. 1983. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Kahn, H. (1984). Thinking About the Unthinkable in the 1980s. New York: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J., and Thaler, R. (1986). “Fairness and the Assumptions of Economics.” Journal of Business 59:S285–S300. Reprinted in Rational Choice: The Contrast Between Economics and Psychology, ed. Hogarth, R. M., and Reder, M., pp. 101–16. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J., and Thaler, R. (1991). “The Endowment Effect, Loss Aversion and the Status Quo Bias.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 5:193–206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalai, E., and Smordinski, M. (1975). “Other Solutions to Nash’s Bargaining Problem.” Econometrica 43:513–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kamali, S. A., trans. (1963). Al-Ghazal’s Tahafut Al-Falasifah. Lahore: Pakistan Philosophical Congress.Google Scholar
Kandori, M. (1992). “Social Norms and Community Enforcement.” Review of Economic Studies 59:63–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kandori, M., Mailath, G., and Rob, R. (1993). “Learning, Mutation, and Long Run Equilibria in Games.” Econometrica 61:29–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kavanaugh, M. (1980). “Invasion of the Forest by an African Savannah Monkey: Behavioral Adaptations.” Behavior 73:239–60.Google Scholar
Kavka, G. (1978). “Some Paradoxes of Deterrence.” Journal of Philosophy 75:285–302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kavka, G. (1983a). “Hobbes’ War of All Against All.” Ethics 93:291–310.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kavka, G. (1983b). “The Toxin Puzzle.” Analysis 43:33–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kavka, G. (1986). Hobbesian Moral and Political Theory. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kavka, G. (1987). Paradoxes of Nuclear Deterrence. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kirchner, W., and Towne, W. (1994). “The Sensory Basis of the Honeybee’s Dance Language.” Scientific American (June):74–80.
Kitcher, P. (1993). “The Evolution of Human Altruism.” The Journal of Philosophy 10:497–516.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Konepudi, D. K. (1989). “State Selection Dynamics in Symmetry-Breaking Transitions.” Noise in Nonlinear Dynamical Systems. Vol. 2. Theory of Noise Induced Processes in Special Applications, ch. 10, pp. 251–70.
Koza, J. (1992). Genetic Programming: On the Programming of Computers by Natural Selection. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Krebs, J. R. (1982). “Territorial Defense in the Great Tit Parus Major: Do Residents Always Win?” Ecology 52:2–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krebs, J. R., and Davies, N. B. (1993). An Introduction to Behavioral Ecology. 3rd ed. London: Blackwell Publisher.Google Scholar
Kreps, D., and Wilson, D. (1982). “Sequential Equilibria.” Econometrica 50:863–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kropotkin, P. (1908). Mutual Aid: A Factor of Evolution. London: Heinemann. The chapters were originally published in Nineteenth Century. September and November 1890, April 1891, January 1892, August and September 1894, and January and June 1896.Google Scholar
Kummer, H. (1971). Primate Societies. Chicago: Aldine‑Atherton.Google Scholar
Lewis, D. (1969). Convention. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Lewis, D. (1979). “Prisoner’s Dilemma Is a Newcomb Problem.” Philosophy and Public Affairs 8:235–40.Google Scholar
Lewis, D. (1981). “Causal Decision Theory.” Australasian Journal of Philosophy 58:5–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, D. (1984). “Devil’s Bargains and the Real World.” In The Security Gamble, ed. MacLean, D., pp. 141–54. Totowa, N.J.: Rowman & Allenheld.Google Scholar
Lorenz, K. (1966). On Aggression. London: Methuen.Google Scholar
Luce, R. D., and Raiffa, H. (1957). Games and Decisions. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Lumsden, C., and Wilson, E. O. (1981). Genes, Mind and Culture. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Marx, K. (1979). “Letter to Engels, June 18, 1862.” In The Letters of Karl Marx, ed. Padover, S. K., p. 157. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Maynard Smith, J. (1964). “Group Selection and Kin Selection.” Nature. 201:1145–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maynard Smith, J. (1978). The Evolution of Sex. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Maynard Smith, J. (1982). Evolution and the Theory of Games. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maynard Smith, J., and Parker, G. R. (1976). “The Logic of Asymmetric Contests.” Animal Behavior 24:159–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maynard Smith, J., and Price, G. R. (1973). “The Logic of Animal Conflict.” Nature 146:15–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McClennen, E. (1990). Rationality and Dynamic Choice: Foundational Explorations. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mellers, B., and Baron, J., eds. (1993). Psychological Perspectives on Justice. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mengel, F. (2012). “Learning Across Games.” Games and Economic Behavior 74:601–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Michod, R., and Sanderson, M. (1985). “Behavioral Structure and the Evolution of Cooperation.” In Evolution: Essays in Honor of John Maynard Smith, ed. Greenwood, J., Harvey, P., and Slatkin, M., pp. 95–104. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Milgrom, P., North, D., and Weingast, B. (1990). “The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs.” Economics and Politics 2:1–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Millikan, R. (1984). Language, Thought and Other Biological Categories: New Foundations for Realism. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Muller, H. (1932). “Some Genetic Aspects of Sex.” American Naturalist 66:118–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Muller, H. (1964). “The Relation of Recombination to Mutational Advance.” Mutation Research 1:2–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myerson, R. B. (1978). “Refinements of the Nash Equilibrium Concept.” International Journal of Game Theory 7:73–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myerson, R. B., Pollock, G. B., and Swinkels, J. M. (1991). “Viscous Population Equilibria.” Games and Economic Behavior 3:101–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nachbar, J. (1990). “‘Evolutionary’ Selection Dynamics in Games: Convergence and Limit Properties.” International Journal of Game Theory 19:59–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nachbar, J. (1992). “Evolution in the Finitely Repeated Prisoner’s Dilemma.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 19:307–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nagel, T. (1974). “What Is It Like to Be a Bat?” Philosophical Review 83:435–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nash, J. (1950). “The Bargaining Problem.” Econometrica 18:155–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nash, J. (1951). “Noncooperative Games.” Annals of Mathematics 54:289–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nowak, M. A. (2006). Evolutionary Dynamics: Exploring the Equations of Life. Cambridge, Mass.: Belknap Press.Google Scholar
Nowak, M. A., and May, R. M. (1992). “Evolutionary Games and Spatial Chaos.” Nature 359:826–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nowak, M. A., and May, R. M. (1993). “The Spatial Dilemmas of Evolution.” International Journal of Bifurcation and Chaos 3:35–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nowak, M. A., Tarnita, C. E., and Wilson, E. O. (2010). “The Evolution of Eusociality.” Nature 66:1057–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nozick, R. (1969). “Newcomb’s Problem and Two Principles of Choice.” In Essays in Honor of C. G. Hempel, ed. Rescher, N., pp. 114–46. Dordrecht: Reidel.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nydegger, R. V., and Owen, G. (1974). “Two-Person Bargaining, an Experimental Test of the Nash Axioms.” International Journal of Game Theory. 3:239–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ochs, J., and Roth, A. (1989). “An Experimental Study of Sequential Bargaining.” American Economic Review 79:355–84.Google Scholar
Outtara, K., Lemasson, A., and Zuberbühler, K. (2009). “Campbell’s Monkeys Concatenate Vocalizations into Context-specific Call Sequences.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 106:22026–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pacheco, J., Santos, F., Souza, M., and Skyrms, B. (2009). “Evolutionary Dynamics of Collective Action in N-Person Stag Hunt Dilemmas.” Proceedings of the Royal Society B 276:315–21.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Packer, C., and Pusey, A. E. (1982). “Cooperation and Competition Within Coalitions of Male Lions: Kin Selection or Game Theory?” Nature 296:740–2.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pemantle, R., and Skyrms, B. (2004a). “Network Formation by Reinforcement Learning: The Long and the Medium Run.” Mathematical Social Sciences 48:315–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pemantle, R., and Skyrms, B. (2004b). “Time to Absorption in Discounted Reinforcement Models.” Stochastic Processes and their Applications 109:1–12.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pollock, G. B. (1989). “Evolutionary Stability in a Viscous Lattice.” Social Networks 11:175–212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poundstone, W. (1992). The Prisoner’s Dilemma. New York: Doubleday.Google Scholar
Prasnikar, V., and Roth, A. (1992). “Considerations of Fairness and Strategy: Experimental Data from Sequential Games.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 107:865–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quine, W. V. O. (1936). “Truth by Convention.” In Philosophical Essays for A. N. Whitehead, ed. Lee, O. H.New York: Longmans.Google Scholar
Quine, W. V. O. (1953). “Two Dogmas of Empiricism.” In From a Logical Point of View. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Quine, W. V. O. (1960). Word and Object. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Quine, W. V. O. (1969). “Foreword” to Lewis, D.Convention, pp. xi–xii. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Raiffa, H. (1953). “Arbitration Schemes for Generalized Two-Person Games.” In Contributions to the Theory of Games. Vol. 2. Ed. Kuhn, H., and Tucker, A. W. (Annals of Mathematics Studies, no. 28). Princeton, N.J.Google Scholar
Ramsey, F. P. (1931). The Foundations of Mathematics and Other Essays. New York: Harcourt Brace.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. (1957). “Justice as Fairness.” Journal of Philosophy 54:653–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rawls, J. (1971). A Theory of Justice. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. (1974). “Some Reasons for the Maximin Criterion.” American Economic Review 64:141–6.Google Scholar
Rescher, N. (1969). “Choice Without Preference: A Study of the History and Logic of ‘Buriden’s Ass.’” Essays in Philosophical Analysis, ch. V, pp. 111–70. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.Google Scholar
Richards, R. (1987). Darwin and the Emergence of Evolutionary Theories of Mind and Behavior. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Riley, J. R., Greggers, U., Smith, A. D., Reynolds, D. R., and Menzel, R. (2005). “The Flight Paths of Honeybees Recruited by the Waggle Dance.” Nature 435: 205–7.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Robson, A. (1990). “Efficiency in Evolutionary Games: Darwin, Nash and the Secret Handshake.” Journal of Theoretical Biology 144:379–96.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Roth, A., and Erev, I. (1995). “Learning in Extensive-Form Games: Experimental Data and Simple Dynamic Models in the Intermediate Term.” Games and Economic Behavior 8:164–212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, A., Prasnikar, V., Okuno-Fujiwara, M., and Zamir, S. (1991). “Bargaining and Market Behavior in Jerusalem, Ljubljana, Pittsburgh and Tokyo: An Experimental Study.” American Economic Review 81:1,068–95.Google Scholar
Rousseau, J.-J. (1984). A Discourse on Inequality. Trans. Cranston, Maurice. London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Rubinstein, A. (1991). “Comments of the Foundations of Game Theory.” Econometrica 58:909–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Russell, B. (1959). Common Sense and Nuclear Warfare. New York: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Samuelson, L. (1988). “Evolutionary Foundations of Solution Concepts for Finite Two-Player Normal Form Games.” In Proceedings of the Second Conference on Theoretical Aspects of Reasoning About Knowledge, ed. Vardi, M., pp. 211–26. Los Altos, Calif.: Morgan Kaufmann.Google Scholar
Samuelson, L. (1993). “Does Evolution Eliminate Dominated Strategies?” In Frontiers of Game Theory, ed. Binmore, K. et al., pp. 213–34. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Samuelson, L. (1997). Evolutionary Games and Equilibrium Selection. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Samuelson, L., and Zhang, J. (1992). “Evolutionary Stability in Asymmetric Games.” Journal of Economic Theory 57:363–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandholm, W. (2010). Population Games and Evolutionary Dynamics. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Santos, F., Pacheco, J., and Skyrms, B. (2011). “Co-evolution of Pre-play Signaling and Cooperation.” Journal of Theoretical Biology 274:30–5.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Savage, L. J. (1954). The Foundations of Statistics. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Schelling, T. (1960). The Strategy of Conflict. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Schuster, P., and Sigmund, K. (1983). “Replicator Dynamics.” Journal of Theoretical Biology 100:535–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Searcy, W. A., and Nowicki, S. (2005). The Evolution of Animal Communication: Reliability and Deception in Signaling Systems. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Searle, J. (1983). Intentionality: An Essay in the Philosophy of Mind. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Searle, J. (1984). Minds, Brains and Science. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Selten, R. (1965). “Spieltheoretische Behandlung eines Oligopolmodells mit Nachfragetragheit.” Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft 121:301–24, 667–89.Google Scholar
Selten, R. (1975). “Reexamination of the Perfectness Concept of Equilibrium in Extensive Games.” International Journal of Game Theory 4:25–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selten, R. (1978). “The Equity Principle in Economic Behavior.” In Decision Theory and Social Ethics, ed. Gottinger, H., and Leinfellner, W., pp. 289–301. Dordrecht: Reidel.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selten, R. (1980). “A Note on Evolutionarily Stable Strategies in Asymmetrical Animal Conflicts.” Journal of Theoretical Biology 84:93–101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selten, R., and Stocker, R. (1986). “End Behavior in Sequences of Finite Prisoner’s Dilemma Supergames.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 7:47–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, A. (1987). On Ethics and Economics. Oxford: Blackwell Publisher.Google Scholar
Sen, A., and Williams, B., eds. (1982). Utilitarianism and Beyond. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shaw, R. (1958). “The Theoretical Genetics of the Sex Ratio.” Genetics 43:149–63.Google ScholarPubMed
Sherman, P. W. (1977). “Nepotism and the Evolution of Alarm Calls.” Science 197:1,246–53.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Sillari, G. (2005). “A Logical Framework for Convention.” Synthese 147:379–400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skyrms, B. (1980). Causal Necessity. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Skyrms, B. (1984). Pragmatics and Empiricism. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Skyrms, B. (1990a). The Dynamics of Rational Deliberation. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Skyrms, B. (1990b). “Ratifiability and the Logic of Decision.” In Midwest Studies in Philosophy XV: The Philosophy of the Human Sciences, ed. French, P. A. et al., pp. 44–56. Notre Dame, Ind.: University of Notre Dame Press.Google Scholar
Skyrms, B. (1991). “Inductive Deliberation, Admissible Acts, and Perfect Equilibrium.” In Foundations of Decision Theory, ed. Bacharach, M., and Hurley, S., pp. 220–41. Oxford: Blackwell Publisher.Google Scholar
Skyrms, B. (1992). “Chaos in Game Dynamics.” Journal of Logic, Language and Information 1:111–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skyrms, B. (1993). “Chaos and the Explanatory Significance of Equilibrium: Strange Attractors in Evolutionary Game Dynamics.” In PSA 1992. Vol. 2. Philosophy of Science Association, pp. 374–94.Google Scholar
Skyrms, B. (1994a). “Darwin Meets ‘The Logic of Decision’: Correlation in Evolutionary Game Theory.” Philosophy of Science. 61:503–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skyrms, B. (1994b). “Sex and Justice.” The Journal of Philosophy 91:305–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skyrms, B. (1998a). “Evolution of an Anomaly.” In Protosoziologie 12:192–211.Google Scholar
Skyrms, B. (1998b). “Mutual Aid.” In Modeling Rationality, Morality and Evolution, ed. Danielson, P.New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Skyrms, B. (2000). “Stability and Explanatory Significance of Some Simple Evolutionary Models.” Philosophy of Science 67:94–113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skyrms, B. (2002). “Signals, Evolution and the Explanatory Power of Transient Information.” Philosophy of Science 69:407–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skyrms, B. (2002). “Altruism, Inclusive Fitness and ‘The Logic of Decision.’Philosophy of Science 69:S104–S111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skyrms, B. (2004). The Stag Hunt and the Evolution of Social Structure. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Skyrms, B. (2009a). “Evolution and the Social Contract.” The Tanner Lectures on Human Values 28. Ed. Peterson, G. B.. Salt Lake City: University of Utah Press.Google Scholar
Skyrms, B. (2009b). “Evolution of Signaling Systems with Multiple Senders and Receivers.” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B 364:771–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skyrms, B. (2010). Signals: Evolution, Learning and Information. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skyrms, B. (2014). Social Dynamics. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skyrms, B., and Pemantle, R. (2000). “A Dynamic Model of Social Network Formation.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the USA 97:9340–6.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Skyrms, B., and Pemantle, R. (2010). “Learning to Network.” In The Place of Probability in Science. Ed. Eells, E. and Fetzer, J., pp. 277–87. Berlin: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skyrms, B., and Zollman, K. (2010). “Evolutionary Considerations in the Framing of Social Norms.” Politics, Philosophy and Economics 9:265–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sober, E. (1992). “The Evolution of Altruism: Correlation, Cost and Benefit.” Biology and Philosophy 7:177–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sober, E. (1994). “The Primacy of Truth-telling and the Evolution of Lying.” In From a Biological Point of View: Essays in Evolutionary Philosophy, ch. 4. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sober, E., and Wilson, D. S. (1994). “A Critical Review on the Units of Selection Problem.” Philosophy of Science 61:534–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sober, E., and Wilson, D. S. (1998). Unto Others: The Evolution and Psychology of Unselfish Behavior. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Stalnaker, R. (1981). “Letter to David Lewis.” In IFS, ed. Harper, W., Stalnaker, R., and Pearce, G., pp. 151–2. Dordrecht: Reidel.Google Scholar
Stewart, I. and Golubitsky, M. (1992). Fearful Symmetry: Is God a Geometer?London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Stigler, S. (1986). The History of Statistics: The Measurement of Uncertainty Before 1900. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. (1986). The Economics of Rights, Cooperation and Welfare. Oxford: Blackwell Publisher. 2nd ed. 2005. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Taylor, P., and Jonker, L. (1978). “Evolutionarily Stable Strategies and Game Dynamics.” Mathematical Biosciences 40:145–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, P., and Sauer, A. (1980). “The Selective Advantage of Sex-Ratio Homeostasis.” American Naturalist 116:305–10.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. (1988). “Anomalies: The Ultimatum Game.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 2:195–206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trivers, R. (1971). “The Evolution of Reciprocal Altruism.” Quarterly Review of Biology 46:35–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ullman-Margalit, E. (1977). The Emergence of Norms. Oxford: Oxford University Press (Clarendon Press).Google Scholar
Vallentyne, P. (1991). Contractarianism and Rational Choice. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
van Damme, E. (1987). Stability and Perfection of Nash Equilibria. Berlin: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vanderschraaf, P. (1994). “Inductive Learning, Knowledge Asymmetries and Convention.” In Theoretical Aspects of Reasoning About Knowledge: Proceedings of the Fifth Conference (TARK 1994), ed. Fagin, R., pp. 284–304. Pacific Grove: Morgan Kaufmann.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vanderschraaf, P. (1995a). A Study in Inductive Deliberation. Ph.D. thesis, University of California, Irvine.
Vanderschraaf, P. (1995b). “Endogenous Correlated Equilibria in Noncooperative Games.” Theory and Decision 38:61–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vanderschraaf, P. (1995c). “Convention as Correlated Equilibrium.” Erkenntnis 42:65–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vanderschraaf, P. (1998). “Knowledge, Equilibrium and Convention.” Erkenntnis 49:337–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vanderschraaf, P., and Skyrms, B. (1993). “Deliberational Correlated Equilibria.” Philosophical Topics 21:191–227.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Verner, J. (1965). “Selection for Sex Ratio.” American Naturalist 99:419–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
von Frisch, K. (1967). The Dance Language and Orientation of Bees. Cambridge, Mass.: Belknap Press.Google Scholar
von Neumann, J., and Morgenstern, O. (1947). Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Waage, J. K. (1988). “Confusion over Residency and the Escalation of Damselfly Territorial Disputes.” Animal Behavior 36:586–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wärneryd, K. (1993). “Cheap Talk, Coordination and Evolutionary Stability.” Games and Economic Behavior 5:532–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Watts, A. (2001). “A Dynamic Model of Network Formation.” Games and Economic Behavior 34:331–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, G. C. (1979). “The Question of Adaptive Sex Ratio in Outcrossed Vertebrates.” Proceedings of the Royal Society of London B205:567–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, D. S. (1980). The Natural Selection of Populations and Communities. Menlo Park, Calif.: Benjamin/Cummings.Google Scholar
Wittgenstein, L. (1958). Philosophical Investigations. Trans. Anscombe, G. E. M.New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Wright, S. (1921). “Systems of Mating. III. Assortative Mating Based on Somatic Resemblance.” Genetics 6:144–61.Google ScholarPubMed
Wright, S. (1945). “Tempo and Mode in Evolution: A Critical Review.” Ecology 26:415–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, H. P. (1993a). “An Evolutionary Model of Bargaining.” Journal of Economic Theory 59:145–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, H. P. (1993b). “The Evolution of Conventions.” Econometrica 61:57–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, H. P. (1994). Equity. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Young, H. P. (1998). Individual Strategy and Social Structure. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Zeeman, E. C. (1980). “Population Dynamics from Game Theory.” In Global Theory of Dynamical Systems. Lecture Notes in Mathematics 819, ed. Nitecki, Z., and Robinson, C., pp. 471–9. Berlin: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zeeman, E. C. (1981). “Dynamics of the Evolution of Animal Conflict.” Journal of Theoretical Biology 89:249–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zollman, K. (2005). “Talking to Neighbors: The Evolution of Regional Meaning.” Philosophy of Science 72:69–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zollman, K. (2008). “Explaining Fairness in Complex Environments.” Politics, Philosophy and Economics 7:81–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zuberbühler, K. (2001). “Predator Specific Alarm Calls in Campbell’s Monkeys Cercopithicus Campbelli.” Bahavioral Ecology and Sociobiology 50:414–22.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Brian Skyrms, University of California, Irvine
  • Book: Evolution of the Social Contract
  • Online publication: 05 November 2014
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139924825.010
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Brian Skyrms, University of California, Irvine
  • Book: Evolution of the Social Contract
  • Online publication: 05 November 2014
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139924825.010
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Brian Skyrms, University of California, Irvine
  • Book: Evolution of the Social Contract
  • Online publication: 05 November 2014
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139924825.010
Available formats
×