Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-nr4z6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-11T20:40:53.974Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

6 - Understanding conservation conflicts: an economic perspective

from PART II - Contrasting disciplinary approaches to the study of conflict in conservation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 May 2015

Nick Hanley
Affiliation:
University of Stirling
Stephen M. Redpath
Affiliation:
University of Aberdeen
R. J. Gutiérrez
Affiliation:
University of Minnesota
Kevin A. Wood
Affiliation:
Bournemouth University
Juliette C. Young
Affiliation:
NERC Centre for Ecology and Hydrology, UK
Get access

Summary

Economics is concerned with understanding human behaviour and with analysing the consequences of the interactions between economic ‘agents’, be they firms, consumers, bird watchers or trade unions. As a field of study, it is interested in modelling how agents respond to changes in incentives, and how institutions like markets and firms help us manage competing wants given our limited resources. Economics has developed a body of theory and empirical methods which can be applied to analyse the consequences of policy-making on both individual and social well-being. As such, it offers an interesting insight into conflicts. Economics can help us understand why conservation conflicts occur, through measuring the benefits and costs to different parties, and showing how identification of these values can help mitigate conflicts by determining appropriate compensation for losses. Here, I describe the potential contributions that economics can make to conflict management before presenting two case studies to provide some illustration.

Understanding why conservation conflicts occur

Economists would point to three interrelated issues that help explain why conservation conflicts occur. These are incentives, property rights and market failures.

Incentives

Sporting estate managers in Scotland, farmers in African villages and forest owners in Malaysia all respond to incentives of various types. Profit incentives can drive land uses which are detrimental to conservation interests. For example, changes in the price of different outputs from land, such as timber and corn, alter the production plans of farmers, increasing deforestation in Central America (Barbier and Burgess, 1996). Increases in ivory prices heighten incentives for elephant poaching in Kenya, while rising bushmeat prices can encourage local people to allocate more time to illegal hunting in the Serengeti (Campbell et al., 2001). Profits from palm oil production increase forest clearance for replanting with palm oil trees, with consequent negative effects on biodiversity in peat swamps in SE Asia (Jaenicke et al., 2008). High prices for agricultural crops under the Common Agricultural Policy in the 1970s and 1980s drove intensification of land management in Europe, with resultant losses in farmland species and landscape quality (Bowers and Cheshire, 1983).

Changes to incentives can also produce beneficial actions to conservation.

Type
Chapter
Information
Conflicts in Conservation
Navigating Towards Solutions
, pp. 79 - 93
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2015

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acs, S., et al. (2010). The effect of decoupling on marginal agricultural systems: implications for farm incomes, land use and upland ecology. Land Use Policy, 27, 550–563.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bain, C. G., et al. (2011). IUCN UK Commission of Inquiry on Peatlands. Edinburgh: IUCN UK Peatland Programme.Google Scholar
Barbier, E. B. and Burgess, J. (1996). Economic analysis of deforestation in Mexico. Environ. Dev. Econ., 1, 203–239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barua, M., Bhagwat, S. A. and Jadhav, S. (2013). The hidden dimensions of human–wildlife conflict: health impacts, opportunity and transaction costs. Biol. Conserv., 157, 309–316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowers, J. and Cheshire, P. (1983). Agriculture, the Countryside and Land Use. London: Methuen and Co.Google Scholar
Brown, G. M. and Shogren, J. (1998). Economics of the Endangered Species Act. J. Econ. Perspect., 12, 3–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, L., Troutt, E., Edwards, C., Gray, B. and Hu, W. (2011). A uniform price auction for conservation easements in the Canadian Prairies. Environ. Resour. Econ., 50, 49–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bullock, C. H., Elston, D. A. and Chalmers, N. A. (1998). An application of economic choice experiments to a traditional land use – deer hunting and landscape change in the Scottish Highlands. J. Environ. Manage., 52, 335–351.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Busch, J. (2013). Supplementing REDD+ with biodiversity payments: the paradox of paying for multiple ecosystem services. Land Econ., 89, 655–675.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bush, G., Colombo, S. and Hanley, N. (2009). Should all choices count? Using the cut-offs approach to edit responses in a choice experiment. Environ. Resour. Econ., 44, 397–414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bush, G., Hanley, N., Moro, M. and Rondeau, D. (2013). Measuring the local opportunity costs of conservation: a provision point mechanism for willingness-to-accept estimates of hypothetical household loss of access to protected areas in Uganda. Land Econ., 89, 490–513.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, K., Nelson, V. and Loibooki, M. (2001). Sustainable Use of Wildland Resources: Economic, Ecological and Social Interactions. Chatham, Kent: Natural Resources Institute.Google Scholar
FC (2011). Woodland Carbon Code: Requirements for Voluntary Carbon Sequestration Projects. Edinburgh: Forestry Commission.
Hanley, N. and Sumner, C. (1995). Bargaining over common property resources: applying the Coarse Theorem to red deer in the Scottish Highlands. J. Environ. Manage., 43, 87–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hanley, N., Kirkpatrick, H., Oglethorpe, D. and Simpson, I. (1998). Paying for public goods from agriculture: an application of the Provider Gets Principle to moorland conservation in Shetland. Land Econ., 74, 102–113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hanley, N., Shogren, J. and White, B. (2007). Environmental Economics in Theory and Practice. Second edition. Basingstoke: Palgrave MacMillan.Google Scholar
Hanley, N., Czajkowski, M., Hanley-Nickolls, R. and Redpath, S. (2010). Economic values of species management options in human–wildlife conflicts: hen harriers in Scotland. Ecol. Econ., 70, 107–113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hanley, N., Banerjee, S., Lennox, G. and Armsworth, P. (2012a). How should we incentivise private landowners to produce more biodiversity? Oxford Rev. Econ. Pol., 28, 93–113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hanley, N., Moro, M., Brennan, D., Redpath, S. and Irvine, J. (2012b). A choice experiment analysis of preferences for red grouse shooting in the Scottish uplands. Discussion Papers in Economics. Stirling: University of Stirling.Google Scholar
Hardin, G. (1968). The tragedy of the commons. Science, 162, 1243–1248.Google ScholarPubMed
Hulme, D. and Murphee, M. (2001). Community conservation in Africa. In African Wildlife and Livelihoods; The Promise and Performance of Community Conservation, ed. Hulme, D. and Murphee, M., pp. 1–8. Portsmouth, NH: Heinemann.Google Scholar
Jack, B., Kousky, C. and Sims, K. (2008). Designing payments for ecosystem services: lessons from previous experience with incentive-based mechanisms. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA, 105, 9465–9470.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Jaenicke, J., Rieley, J. O., Mott, C., Kimman, P. and Siegert, F. (2008).Determination of the amount of carbon stored in Indonesian peatlands. Geoderma, 147, 151–158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kleijn, D., et al. (2006). Mixed biodiversity benefits of agri-environment schemes in five European countries. Ecol. Lett., 9, 243–254.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Krutilla, K. (2005). Using the Kaldor–Hicks Tableau format for cost–benefit analysis and policy evaluation. J. Pol. Anal. Manag., 24, 864–875.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindsey, P. A., Frank, L. G., Alexander, R., Mathieson, A. and Romanach, S. S. (2006). Trophy hunting and conservation in Africa: problems and one potential solution. Conserv. Biol., 21, 880–883.Google Scholar
Maron, M., et al. (2012). Faustian bargains? Restoration realities in the context of biodiversity offset policies. Biol. Conserv., 155, 141–148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moro, M., et al. (2013). An investigation using the choice experiment method into options for reducing illegal bushmeat hunting in western Serengeti. Conserv. Lett., 6, 37–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norton-Griffiths, M. and Southey, C. (1995). The opportunity cost of biodiversity conservation in Kenya. Ecol. Econ., 12, 125–139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
OECD (2010). Paying for Biodiversity. Paris: Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development.
Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, M. D. (2012). The new fisheries economics: incentives across many margins. Ann. Rev. Resour. Econ., 4, 379–402.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spash, C. and Simpson, I. (1993). Protecting Sites of Special Scientific Interest: intrinsic and utilitarian values. J. Environ. Manage., 39, 213–227.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
TEEB (2009). The Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity. Nairobi: United Nations Environment Programme.
Thirgood, S. and Redpath, S. (2008). Hen harriers and red grouse: science, politics and human wildlife conflict. J. Appl. Ecol., 45, 1550–1554.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
United Kingdom National Ecosystems Assessment (2011). Technical Report. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Womble, P. and Doyle, M. (2012). The geography of trading ecosystem services: a case study of wetlands and stream compensatory mitigation markets. Harvard Law Rev., 36, 229–296.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×