Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-7479d7b7d-m9pkr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-12T21:27:25.803Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

2 - Repeated moral hazard with low discount rates

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 November 2011

Roy Radner
Affiliation:
AT&T Bell Laboratories
Walter P. Heller
Affiliation:
University of California, San Diego
Ross M. Starr
Affiliation:
University of California, San Diego
David A. Starrett
Affiliation:
Stanford University, California
Get access

Summary

Introduction

The owner of an enterprise wants to put it in the hands of a manager. In each of a number of successive periods (month, quarter, year) the profit of the enterprise will depend both on the actions of the manager and on the environment in which the enterprise is operating. The owner cannot directly monitor the manager's actions, nor can the owner costlessly observe all of the relevant aspects of the environment. The owner and the manager will have to agree on how the manager is to be compensated, and the owner wants to pick a compensation mechanism that will motivate the manager to provide a good return on the owner's investment, net of the payments to the manager.

This is the well-known principal–agent problem, with the additional feature that the relationship between the owner (principal) and the manager (agent) may last more than one decision period. Some other principal–agent relationships in economic life are client–lawyer, customer–supplier, regulator–public utility, and insurer–insured. The insurer–insured relationship gave rise to the term moral hazard, and the first formal economic analysis of moral hazard was probably given by K. J. Arrow.

Early formal analyses of principal–agent relationships focused on “short-term” or “one-period” situations. The simplest of these can be modeled as a two-move game, in which (1) the principal chooses a compensation function (made known to the agent) and (2) the agent chooses the action. The outcome is then determined as a function of the agent's action and some exogenous stochastic event, and the principal compensates the agent as a function of that outcome, according to the compensation function the principal previously announced in the first move.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 1986

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×