Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-m9kch Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-01T01:57:02.529Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 June 2014

Randall S. Kroszner
Affiliation:
Booth School of Business, University of Chicago
Louis Putterman
Affiliation:
Brown University, Rhode Island
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
The Economic Nature of the Firm
A Reader
, pp. 363 - 387
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abelson, Reid, 2001, “Enron Board Comes under a Storm of Criticism,” The New York Times, December 16, C4.
Aghion, P., and Bolton, P., 1988, “An ‘Incomplete Contract’ Approach to Bankruptcy and the Financial Structure of the Firm,” Stanford University, Institute for Mathematical Studies in the Social Sciences Technical Report No. 536.
Aghion, P., Bolton, P., and Felli, L., 1997, “Some Issues on Contract Incompleteness,” London School of Economics Working Paper.Google Scholar
Agrawal, Anup, and Knoeber, Charles R., 1998, “Managerial Compensation and the Threat of Takeover,” Journal of Financial Economics, 47(2): 219–239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ahmadjian, Christina, and Lincoln, James, 1997, “Changing Firm Boundaries in Japanese Auto Parts Supply Networks,” draft, Columbia Business School.
Akerlof, George, 1982, “Labor Contracts as Partial Gift Exchange,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 47(4): 543–569.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, George A., and Katz, Lawrence F., 1988, “Workers' Trust Funds and the Logic of Wage Profiles,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 2548. (Published in 1989 as “Workers' Trust Funds and the Logic of Wage Profiles,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104(3): 525–536.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alchian, A. A., 1965, “The Basis of Some Recent Advances in the Theory of Management of the Firm,” Journal of Industrial Economics, 14: 30–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alchian, A. A., 1968, “Corporate Management and Property Rights,” in Economic Policy and the Regulation of Securities. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute.Google Scholar
Alchian, A. A., and Kessel, R. A., 1962, “Competition, Monopoly, and the Pursuit of Pecuniary Gain,” in National Bureau of Economic Research, Aspects of Labor Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Alchian, Armen, A., and Demsetz, Harold, 1972, “Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization,” American Economic Review, 62: 777–795.Google Scholar
Alchian, Armen A., 1969, “Corporate Management and Property Rights,” in Manne, Henry G. (ed.), Economic Policy and the Regulation of Corporate Securities. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research.Google Scholar
Alchian, Armen, 1984, “Specificity, Specialization, and Coalitions,” draft manuscript, February.
Altenberg, Lee, 1990, “An End to Capitalism: Leland Stanford's Forgotten Vision,” Sandstone and Tile, 14(1): 8–20.Google Scholar
Andersen, Erin, 1985, “The Salesperson as Outside Agent or Employee: A Transaction Cost Analysis,” Marketing Science, 4: 234–254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andersen, Erin, and Schmittlein, David, 1984, “Integration of the Sales Force: An Empirical Examination,” Rand Journal of Economics, 15: 385–395.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aoki, Masahiko, 1984, The Co-operative Game Theory of the Firm. London: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J., 1969, “The Organization of Economic Activity,” in The Analysis and Evaluation of Public Expenditure: The PPB System. 91st Congress, 1st Session, vol. 1, JEC, 47–64.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J., 1974, The Limits of Organization. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth, 1975, “Vertical Integration and Communication,” Bell Journal of Economics, 6: 173–182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Asanuma, Banri, 1989, “Manufacturer–Supplier Relationships in Japan and the Concept of Relation-Specific Skill,” The Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 3: 1–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Asanuma, Banri, 1992, “Japanese Manufacturer–Supplier Relationships in International Perspective,” in Sheard, Paul (ed.), International Adjustment and the Japanese Economy. St. Leonards, Australia: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Ashenfelter, O., and Johnson, G., 1972, “Unionism, Relative Wages, and Labor Quality in U.S. Manufacturing Industries,” International Economic Review, 13: 488–508.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atiyah, P. S., 1979, The Rise and Fall of Freedom of Contract. Oxford and New York: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Atwood, Jane, and Kobrin, Paul, 1977, “Integration and Joint Ventures in Pipelines,” Research Study No. 5, American Petroleum Institute.
Baker, George, 1989, “Price Rate Contracts and Performance Measurement Error,” Graduate School of Business, Harvard University.
Baker, George, Gibbons, Robert, and Murphy, Kevin J., 2002, “Relational Contracts and the Theory of the Firm,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(1): 39–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baker, George P., Jensen, Michael C., and Murphy, Kevin J., 1988. “Compensation and Incentives: Practice vs. Theory,” Journal of Finance, 63(3): 593–616.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Balsam, Steven, 2002, An Introduction to Executive Compensation. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Bardhan, Pranab K., and Roemer, John E. (eds.), 1993, Market Socialism: The Current Debate. New York: Oxford University Press.
Bar-Gill, Oren, and Bebchuk, Lucian, 2002, “Misreporting Corporate Performance,” Discussion Paper No. 400, Harvard Olin Center for Law, Economics, and Business.
Bar-Gill, Oren, and Bebchuk, Lucian, 2003a, “The Costs of Permitting Managers to Sell Shares,” mimeo, Harvard Law School.
Bar-Gill, Oren, and Bebchuk, Lucian, 2003b, “Corporate Transparency and Managerial Incentives,” mimeo, Harvard Law School.
Barnard, Chester, 1938, The Functions of the Executive. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Barnard, C. I., 1962, The Functions of the Executive, 2nd edition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Bartlett, F. C., 1932, Remembering. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Barzel, Yoram, 1982, “Measurement Costs and the Organization of Markets,” Journal of Law and Economics, 25: 27–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Batt, Francis R, 1929, The Law of Master and Servant. New York: Pitman Publishing Co.Google Scholar
Baumol, William J., 1959, Business Behavior, Value and Growth. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Bebchuk, Lucian, Coates, John IV, and Subramanian, Guhan, 2002, “The Powerful Antitakeover Force of Staggered Boards: Theory, Evidence, and Policy,” Stanford Law Review, 54: 887–951.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bebchuk, Lucian Arye, and Fried, Jesse M., 2003a, “Stealth Compensation,” mimeo, Harvard Law School and Boalt Hall School of Law.
Bebchuk, Lucian Arye, and Fried, Jesse M., 2003b, “Executive Compensation as an Agency Problem,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(3): 71–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bebchuk, Lucian Arye, and Fried, Jesse M., 2004, Pay without Performance, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Bebchuk, Lucian Arye, Fried, Jesse M., and Walker, David I., 2002, “Managerial Power and Rent Extraction in the Design of Executive Compensation.” University of Chicago Law Review, 69(3): 751–846.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bebchuk, Lucian Arye, and Kahan, Marcel, 1990, “A Framework for Analyzing Legal Policy Toward Proxy Contests,” California Law Review, 78: 1071–1136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S., and Stigler, George J., 1974, “Law Enforcement, Malfeasance, and Compensation of Enforcers,” Journal of Legal Studies, 3: 1–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beckmann, Martin, 1983, Tinbergen Lectures on Economic Organization. Berlin: Springer-Verlag.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benassy, Jean-Pascal, 1982, The Economics of Market Disequilibrium. Orlando, FL: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Benz, Matthias, Kucher, Marcel, and Stutzer, Alois, 2001, “Stock Options: The Managers' Blessing: Institutional Restrictions and Executive Compensation,” Working Paper No. 61, University of Zurich Institute for Empirical Research in Economics.
Ben-Ner, Avner, and Hoomissen, Theresa, 1991, “Nonprofit Organizations in the Mixed Economy: A Demand and Supply Analysis,” Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, 62: 519–550.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berhold, M., 1971, “A Theory of Linear Profit Sharing Incentives,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 85: 460–482.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berle, Adolf A., and Means, Gardiner C., 1932, The Modern Corporation and Private Property. New York: Commerce Clearing House.Google Scholar
Bertrand, Marianne, and Mullainathan, Sendhil, 2001, “Are CEO's Rewarded for Luck? The Ones without Principals Are,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(3): 901–932.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bettis, J. Carr, Bizjak, John, M., and Lemmon, Michael L., 2001, “Managerial Ownership, Incentive Contracting, and the Use of Zero-Cost Collars and Equity Swaps by Corporate Insiders,” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 36: 345–370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bettis, J. Carr, Coles, Jeffrey, L., and Lemmon, Michael L., 2000, “Corporate Policies Restricting Trading by Insiders,” Journal of Financial Economics, 57(2): 191–220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bewley, Truman F., 1999, Why Wages Don't Fall during a Recession. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Bizjack, John M., Lemmon, Michael L., and Naveen, Lalitha, 2000, “Has the Use of Peer Groups Contributed to Higher Levels of Executive Compensation?” Working Paper, Portland State University.
Blanchard, Olivier Jean, Lopez-de-Silanes, Florencio, and Shleifer, Andrei, 1994, “What Do Firms Do with Cash Windfalls?Journal of Financial Economics, 36: 337–360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blair, Margaret M., 1995, Ownership and Control. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Blair, Margaret M., and Stout, L., 1997, “A Theory of Corporation Law as a Response to Contracting Problems in Team Production,” The Brookings Institution Working Paper, available at www.brook.edu.
Blau, P., and Scott, W., 1962, Formal Organizations. San Francisco: Chandler.Google Scholar
Blinder, Alan (ed.), 1990, Paying for Productivity: A Look at the Evidence. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.
Blum, Milton L., 1956, Industrial Psychology and Its Social Foundations. New York: Harper and Brothers.Google Scholar
Bolster, Paul, Chance, Don, and Rich, Don, 1996, “Executive Equity Swaps and Corporate Insider Holdings,” Financial Management, 25: 14–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonin, John, P., Jones, Derek C., and Putterman, Louis, 1993, “Theoretical and Empirical Research on Producers' Cooperatives: Will Ever the Twain Meet?Journal of Economic Literature, 31: 1290–1320.Google Scholar
Bork, Robert, 1954, “Vertical Integration and the Sherman Act: The Legal History of an Economic Misconception,” University of Chicago Labor Review, 22: 157–201.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borokhovich, Kenneth A., Brunarski, Kelly R., and Parrino, Robert, 1997, “CEO Contracting and Anti-Takeover Amendments,” Journal of Finance, 52(4): 1495–1517.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, 1985, “The Production Process in a Competitive Economy: Walrasian, Neo-Hobbesian, and Marxian Models,” American Economic Review, 75: 16–36.Google Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, 1988, “Social Institutions and Technical Choice,” in DeMatteo, M., Vercelli, A., and Goodman, R. (eds.), Technological and Social Factors in Long-Term Economic Fluctuations. Berlin: Springer-Verlag.Google Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, and Boyer, Robert, 1990, “Labour Market Flexibility and Decentralization as Barriers to High Employment,” in Brunetta, Renato and Dell'Aringa, Carlo (eds.), Labor Relations and Economic Performance. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, and Gintis, Herbert, 1975, “The Problems with Human Capital Theory,” American Economic Review, 65: 74–82.Google Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, and Gintis, Herbert, 1976, Schooling in Capitalist America: Educational Reform and the Contradictions of Economic Life. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, and Gintis, Herbert, 1982a, “The Crisis of Liberal Democratic Capitalism,” Politics and Society, 10: 51–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, and Gintis, Herbert, 1982b, “The Welfare State and Long-Term Economic Growth: Marxian, Neoclassical, and Keynesian Approaches,” American Economic Review, 72: 341–345.Google Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, and Gintis, Herbert, 1990a, “Contested Exchange: New Microfoundations of the Political Economy of Capitalism,” Politics and Society, 18: 165–222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, and Gintis, Herbert, 1990b, “Bonding and Dismissal in Labor Discipline Models,” photocopy, University of Massachusetts.
Bowles, Samuel, and Gintis, Herbert, 1993a, “The Democratic Firm: An Agency Theory Evaluation,” in Bowles, Samuel, Gintis, Herbert, and Gustaffson, Bo (eds.), Markets and Democracy: Participation, Accountability, and Efficiency. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, and Gintis, Herbert, 1993b, “The Revenge of Homo Economics: Contested Exchange and the Revival of Economy,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7: 83–102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, and Gintis, Herbert, 1995, “Democratic Firms and the Distribution of Wealth,” in Roemer, J. E. (ed.), Property Relations, Incentives and Welfare. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, Gordon, David M., and Weisskopf, Thomas E., 1989, “Business Ascendancy and Economic Impasse: A Structural Retrospective on Conservative Economics, 1979–87,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3: 107–134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bradley, Keith, and Gelb, Alan, 1981, “Motivation and Control in the Mondragon Experiment,” British Journal of Industrial Relations, 19: 211–231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Branch, B., 1973, “Corporate Objectives and Market Performance,” Financial Management, 2: 24–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brickley, James, and Dark, Frederick, 1987, “The Choice of Organizational Form: The Case of Franchising,” Journal of Financial Economics, 18: 401–420.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James, Tollison, Robert, and Tolluck, Gordon, 1990, Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society. College Station: Texas A&M University Press.Google Scholar
Buttrick, John, 1952, “The Inside Contracting System,”Journal of Economic History, 12: 205–221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calvo, Guillermo, and Wellisz, Stanislaw, 1978, “Supervision, Loss of Control, and the Optimum Size of the Firm,” Journal of Political Economy, 86: 943–952.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, Colin, and Fehr, Ernst, 2004, “Measuring Social Norms and Preferences Using Experimental Games: A Guide for Social Scientists” (Chapter 3, pp. 55–95), in Foundations of Human Sociality: Economic Experiments and Ethnographic Evidence from Fifteen Small-Scale Societies (Henrich, Joseph, et al., eds.); Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Canes, M., 1970, “A Model of a Sports League,” doctoral dissertation, University of California at Los Angeles.
Carpenter, Jennifer N., 1998, “The Exercise and Valuation of Executive Stock Options,” Journal of Financial Economics, 48: 127–158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chandler, A., 1977, The Visible Hand. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Chandler, Alfred Dupont, 1962, Strategy and Structure: Chapters in the History of the Industrial Enterprise. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Cheng, Shun, Nagar, Venky, and Rajan, Madhar V., 2001, “Control Versus Risk in Stock-Based Incentives: Evidence from Antitakeover Regulation,” Working Paper, University of Michigan Business School.
Cheung, S. N. S., 1969, “Transaction Costs, Risk Aversion, and the Choice of Contractual Arrangements,” Journal of Law and Economics, 12: 23–42.Google Scholar
Cheung, Steven, 1983, “The Contractual Nature of the Firm,” Journal of Law and Economics, 26: 1–21.Google Scholar
Clague, Christopher, 1993, “Rule Obedience, Organizational Loyalty, and Economic Development,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 149: 393–414.Google Scholar
Clark, J. B., 1900, Distribution of Wealth. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Clark, Robert C., 1985, Principals and Agents: The Structure of Business. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Clarkson, Kenneth W., Miller, Roger LeRoy, and Muris, Timothy J., 1978, “Liquidated Damages Versus Penalties: Sense or Nonsense?Wisconsin Law Review, 1978: 351–390.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H., 1959, “The Federal Communications Commission,” Journal of Law and Economics, 2: 1–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, R. H., 1960, “The Problem of Social Cost,” Journal of Law and Economics, 15: 143–150.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, R. H., 1964, Discussion, American Economic Review, 3: 194–197.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H., 1972, “Durability and Monopoly,” Journal of Law and Economics, 15: 143–150.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald, 1991a, “The Nature of the Firm: Origin,” 34–47 in Williamson, Oliver and Winter, Sidney (eds.), The Nature of the Firm: Origins, Evolution, and Development. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald, 1991b, “The Nature of the Firm: Meaning,” 48–60 in Williamson, Oliver and Winter, Sidney (eds.), The Nature of the Firm: Origins, Evolution, and Development. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald, 1992, “The Institutional Structure of Production: 1991 Alfred Nobel Memorial Prize Lecture in Economic Sciences,” American Economic Review, 82: 713–719.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H., 1937, “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica, 4: 396–405; reprinted 331–351 in American Economic Association, Readings in Price Theory, Chicago: Irwin, 1952; reprinted, 33–55 in Coase, The Firm, the Market, and the Law, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1990; reprinted, G. J. Stigler and K. E. Boulding (eds.), Readings in Price Theory. Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin.Google Scholar
Commons, J., 1970, The Economics of Collective Action. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
Core, John E., Guay, Wayne, and Larcker, David F., 2001, “Executive Equity Compensation and Incentives: A Survey,” Working Paper, Wharton School. (Published in 2003 as “Executive Equity Compensation and Incentives: A Survey,”Economic Policy Review, 9(1): 27–50.)Google Scholar
Core, John E., Holthausen, Robert W., and Larcker, David E., 1999, “Corporate Governance, Chief Executive Compensation, and Firm Performance,” Journal of Financial Economics, 51: 371–406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Core, John E., and Larcker, David, 2002, “Performance Consequences of Mandatory Increases in Executive Stock Ownership,” Working Paper, Wharton School. (Published in 2002 as “Performance Consequences of Mandatory Increases in Executive Stock Ownership,” Journal of Financial Economics, 64(3): 317–340.)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, A., 1958, “The Legal Nature of Collective Bargaining Agreements,” Michigan Law Review, 57: 1–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crocker, K. J., and Masten, S. E., 1991, “Pretia ex Machina? Prices and Process in Long-Term Contracts,” Journal of Law and Economics, 34: 69–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crystal, Graef S., 1991, In Search of Excess. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Cyert, R. M., and Hedrick, C. L., 1972, “Theory of the Firm: Past, Present, and Future: An Interpretation,” Journal of Economic Literature, 10: 398–412.Google Scholar
Cyert, R. M., and March, J. G., 1963, A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Cyert, Richard, Kang, Sok-Hyon, and Kumar, Praveen, 2002, “Corporate Governance, Takeovers, and Top-Management Compensation: Theory and Evidence,” Management Science, 48(4): 453–469.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dahl, Robert A., 1985, A Preface to Economic Democracy. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Darby, Michael R., and Karni, Eli, 1973, “Free Competition and the Optimal Amount of Fraud,” Journal of Law and Economics, 16: 67–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
David, Parthiban, Kochar, Rahul, and Levitas, Edward, 1998, “The Effect of Institutional Investors on the Level and Mix of CEO Compensation,” Academy of Management Journal, 41(2): 200–208.Google Scholar
Dawes, Harry, 1934, “Labour Mobility in the Steel Industry,” The Economic Journal, 44: 84–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Demsetz, H., 1967, “Toward a Theory of Property Rights,” American Economic Review, 57: 347–359.Google Scholar
Demsetz, H., 1969,” Information and Efficiency: Another Viewpoint,” Journal of Law and Economics, 12: 1–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Demsetz, Harold, 1983, “The Structure of Ownership and the Theory of the Firm,” Journal of Law and Economics, 26: 375–390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Demsetz, Harold, and Lehn, Kenneth, 1985, “The Structure of Corporate Ownership: Causes and Consequences,” Journal of Political Economy, 93: 1155–1177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dickens, William T., Katz, Lawrence F., Lang, Kevin, and Summers, Lawrence H., 1989, “Employee Crime and the Monitoring Puzzle,” Journal of Labor Economics, 7: 331–347.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dobb, Maurice, 1925, Capitalist Enterprise and Social Progress. London: George Routledge and Sons, Ltd.Google Scholar
Doeringer, P., and Piore, M., 1971, International Labor Markets and Manpower Analysis. Lexington, MA: D.C. Heath and Co.Google Scholar
Dong, Xiao-Yuan, 1991, “Production and Monitoring Incentives in China's Collective Farming: Theory and Evidence,” Ph.D. dissertation, University of Alberta.
Dong, Xiao-Yuan, and Dow, Gregory, 1993, “Monitoring Costs in Chinese Agricultural Teams,” Journal of Political Economy, 101: 539–553.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dow, Greogry, 2003, Governing the Firm: Workers' Control in Theory and Practice. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dow, Gregory, and Putterman, Louis, 2000, “Why Capital Suppliers (Usually) Hire Workers: What We Know, and What We Need to Know,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 43: 319–336.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Durbin, E. F. M., 1936, “Economic Calculus in a Planned Economy,” Economic Journal, 46: 676–690.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Easterbrook, Frank, and Fischel, Daniel, 1983, “Voting in Corporate Law,” Journal of Law and Economics, 26: 305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eaton, B, and White, William, 1982, “Agent Compensation and the Limits of Bonding,” Economic Inquiry, 20: 330–343.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eccles, Robert G., 1981, “The Quasi Firm in the Construction Industry,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 2: 335–357.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edwards, Richard, 1979, Contested Terrain: The Transformation of the Workplace in the Twentieth Century. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Elster, John, 1979, Ulysses and the Sirens. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Eswaran, Mukesh, and Kotwal, Ashok, 1989, “Why Are Capitalists the Bosses?Economic Journal, 99: 162–176.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fama, E. F., 1970, “Multiperiod Consumption-Investment Decisions,” American Economic Review, 60: 163–174.Google Scholar
Fama, E. F., 1972, “Ordinal and Measurable Utility,” in Jensen, M. C. (ed.), Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets. New York: Praeger.Google Scholar
Fama, Eugene F., 1976, Foundations of Finance. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Fama, Eugene, 1978, “The Effects of a Firm's Investment and Financing Decisions on the Welfare of Its Security Holders,” American Economic Review, 68: 272–284.Google Scholar
Fama, Eugene, 1980, “Agency Problems and the Theory of the Firm,” Journal of Political Economy, 88: 288–307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fama, Eugene F., and Jensen, Michael C., 1983a, “Agency Problems and Residual Claims,” Journal of Law and Economics, 26: 327–349.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fama, Eugene F., and Jensen, Michael C., 1983b, “Separation of Ownership and Control,” Journal of Law and Economics, 26: 301–326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fama, Eugene F., and Jensen, Michael C., 1985, “Organizational Forms and Investment Decision,” Journal of Financial Economics, 14: 101–119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fama, Eugene F., and Miller, Merton H., 1972, The Theory of Finance. New York: Holt, Rinehart, and Winston.Google Scholar
Farrell, Joseph, and Shapiro, Carl, 1989, “Optimal Contracts with Lock-in,” American Economic Review, 79: 51–68.Google Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, and Gächter, Simon, 2000, “Cooperation and Punishment,” American Economic Review, 90: 980–994.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, and Schmidt, Klaus, 2003, “Theories of Fairness and Reciprocity – Evidence and Economic Applications,” in Dewatripont, M., Hansen, L., and Turnovsky, S. (eds.), Advances in Economics and Econometrics – 8th World Congress, Econometric Society Monographs. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Feldman, J., and Kanter, H., 1965, “Organizational Decision-Making,” in March, J. (ed.), Handbook of Organizations. Chicago: Rand McNally.Google Scholar
Feldman, Martha S., and March, James G., 1981, “Information in Organizations as Signal and Symbol,” Administrative Science Quarterly, 26: 171–186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feller, David E., 1973, “A General Theory of the Collective Bargaining Agreement,” California Labor Review, 3: 663–856.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferguson, Adam, 1767, An Essay on the History of Civil Society. Dublin: Boulter Grierson.Google Scholar
FitzRoy, Felix R., and Kraft, Kornelius, 1986, “Profitability and Profit-Sharing,” Journal of Industrial Economics, 35: 113–130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freeman, Richard, 1976, “Individual Mobility and Union Voice in the Labor Market,” American Economic Review, 66: 361–368.Google Scholar
Freeman, Richard B., and Rogers, Joel, 1999, What Workers Want, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Fried, Jesse M., 1998, “Reducing the Profitability of Corporate Insider Trading through Pre-trading Disclosure,” Southern California Law Review, 71(2): 303–392.Google Scholar
Friedman, James, 1971, “A Non-Cooperative Equilibrium for Supergames,” Review of Economic Studies, 38: 1–12.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, M., 1970, “The Social Responsibility of Business Is to Increase Its Profits,” The New York Times Magazine, September 13, 32ff.Google Scholar
Fudenberg, Drew, and Tirole, Jean, 1991, Game Theory. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Fudenberg, D., Holmstrom, B., and Milgrom, P., 1990, “Short-Term Contracts and Long-Term Agency Relationships,” Journal of Economic Theory, 51(1): 1–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Furubotn, E. G., and Pejovich, S., 1972, “Property Rights and Economic Theory: A Survey of Recent Literature,” Journal of Economic Literature, 10: 1137–1162.Google Scholar
Garnier, Germain, 1815, Abrege elementaire des principes de l'Economie Politique. Paris: Agasse.Google Scholar
Ghemawat, Pankaj, 1995, “Competitive Advantage and Internal Organization: Nucor Revisited,” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 3: 685–717.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gillan, Stuart, 2001, “Has Pay for Performance Gone Awry: Views from a Corporate Governance Forum,” Research Dialogue, TIAA CREF Institute, 68: 1–16.Google Scholar
Gintis, Herbert, 1976, “The Nature of the Labor Exchange and the Theory of Capitalist Production,” Review of Radical Political Economics, 8(2): 36–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gintis, Herbert, and Ishikawa, Tsuneo, 1987, “Wages, Work Discipline, and Unemployment,” Journal of Japanese and International Economies, 1: 195–228.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gleitman, Henry, 1995, Psychology. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Goetz, Charles J., and Scott, Robert E., 1983, “The Mitigation Principle: Toward a General Theory of Contractual Obligation,” Virginia Law Review, 69: 967–1025.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Golbe, Devra, and White, Lawrence, 1988, “Mergers and Acquisitions in the United States Economy: An Aggregate and Historical Overview,” Mergers and Acquisitions, Chicago: University of Chicago Press for the NBER.Google Scholar
Golbe, Devra, and White, Lawrence, 1993, “Catch a Wave: The Time Series Behavior of Mergers,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 75: 493–499.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldberg, Victor P., 1976, “Regulation and Administered Contracts,” Bell Journal of Economics, 7: 426–448.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldberg, Victor, 1980a, “Relational Exchange: Economics and Complex Contracts,” American Behavioral Scientist, 23(3): 337–352.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldberg, Victor, 1980b, “Bridges Over Contested Terrain: Exploring the Radical Account of the Employment Relationship,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 1: 249–274.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldberg, Victor, and Erickson, John R., 1987, “Quantity and Price Adjustment in Long-Term Contracts: A Case Study of Petroleum Coke,” Journal of Law and Economics, 30: 369–398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gouldner, A. W., 1961, “The Norm of Reciprocity,” American Sociological Review, 25: 161–179.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granovetter, Mark, 1983, “Loyalty Filters,” American Economic Review, 73(1): 54–63.Google Scholar
Greenberg, Edward S., 1986, Workplace Democracy: The Political Effects of Participation. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Greenwald, Bruce, and Stiglitz, Joseph, 1986, “Externalities in Economies with Imperfect Information and Incomplete Markets,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101: 229–264.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, Sanford J., and Hart, Oliver D., 1980, “Takeover Bids, the Free Rider Problem, and the Theory of Corporation,” Bell Journal of Economics, 11: 42–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, Sanford J., and Hart, Oliver D., 1984, “The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical Integration,” unpublished manuscript, March.
Grossman, Sanford J., and Hart, Oliver D., 1986, “The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration,” Journal of Political Economy, 94: 691–719.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, Sanford J., and Hart, Oliver D., 1988, “One Share–One Vote and the Market for Corporate Control,” Journal of Financial Economics, 20: 175–202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gustafson, W. Eric, 1959, Periodicals and Books, in Hall, Max (ed.), Case Studies in Metropolitan Manufacturing. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Habib, Michel A., and Ljungqvist, Alexander P., 2000, “Firm Value and Managerial Incentives,” Working Paper, London Business School.
Hadlock, Charles, and Lumer, Gerald, 1997, “Compensation, Turnover, and Top Management Incentives: Historical Evidence,” Journal of Business, 70: 153–188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Brian J., 1999, “A Better Way to Pay CEO's?,” in Executive Compensation and Shareholder Value: Theory and Evidence, Carpenter, Jennifer and Yermack, David (eds.), Kluwer Academic, 35–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Brian, and Liebman, Jeffrey, 1998, “Are CEOs Really Paid Like Bureaucrats?The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(3): 653–691.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Brian J., and Murphy, Kevin J., 2003, “The Trouble with Stock Options,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(3): 49–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansmann, H., 1996, The Ownership of the Enterprise. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University.Google Scholar
Hansmann, Henry, 1988, “Ownership of the Firm,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 4: 267–304.Google Scholar
Harris, Milton, and Raviv, Artur, 1988, “Corporate Governance: Voting Rights and Majority Rules,” Journal of Financial Economics, 20: 203–235.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, Oliver, 1983, “The Market Mechanism as an Incentive Scheme,” Bell Journal of Economics, 14: 366–382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, Oliver, 1989, “An Economist's Perspective on the Theory of the Firm,” Columbia Law Review, 89: 1757–1774.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, Oliver, and Holmstrom, Bengt, 1987, “The Theory of Contracts,” in Bewley, Truman F. (ed.), Advances in Economic Theory – Fifth World Congress. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hart, Oliver, and Moore, J., 1988, “Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm,” Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Department of Economics Working Paper No. 495.
Hart, Oliver D., and Moore, John, 1990, “Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm,” Journal of Political Economy, 98: 1119–1158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hartzell, Jay C., and Starks, Laura T., 2002, “Institutional Investors and Executive Compensation,” Working Paper, New York University Stern School of Business (Published in 2003 as “Institutional Investors and Executive Compensation,” Journal of Finance, 58 (6): 2351–2374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, F. A., 1933, “The Trend of Economic Thinking,” Economica, 13: 121–137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, F. A., 1945, “The Use of Knowledge in Society,” The American Economic Review, 35: 519–530.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich, 1972, Individualism and Economic Order. Chicago: Henry Regnery Company.Google Scholar
Healy, Paul M., Palepu, Krishna G., and Ruback, Richard S., 1992, “Does Corporate Performance Improve after Mergers?Journal of Financial Economics, 31: 135–175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heckerman, D. G., 1975, “Motivating Managers to Make Investment Decisions,” Journal of Financial Economics, 2: 273–292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Helper, Susan, 1991, “Strategy and Irreversibility in Supplier Relations: The Case of the U.S. Automobile Industry,” Business History Review, 65: 781–824.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henderson, Hubert D., 1922, Supply and Demand. New York: Harcourt, Brace, and Co.Google Scholar
Henry, Robert S., 1942, This Fascinating Railroad Business. New York: Bobbs-Merrill.Google Scholar
Himmelberg, Charles, Hubbard, R. Glenn, and Palia, Darius, 1999, “Understanding the determinants of managerial ownership and the link between ownership and performance,”Journal of Financial Economics, 53(3): 353–384.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirschman, A. O., 1970, Exit, Voice, and Loyalty. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hodgeskin, Thomas, 1827, Popular Political Economy. London: Charles Tait.Google Scholar
Holderness, Clifford, Kroszner, Randall, and Sheehan, Dennis, 1995, “Changes in Corporate Stock Ownership since the Great Depression,” Working Paper, University of Chicago, Graduate School of Business.
Holderness, Clifford G., Kroszner, Randall S., and Sheehan, Dennis P., 1999, “Were the Good Old Days that Good? Changes In Managerial Stock Ownership since the Great Depression,”Journal of Finance, 54: 435–469.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holderness, Clifford G., Kroszner, Randall S., and Sheehan, Dennis P., 2000, “The Rise in Managerial Stock Ownership,” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 13(3): 105–115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holderness, Clifford, and Sheehan, Dennis, 1988, “The Role of Majority Shareholders in Publicly Held Corporations,” Journal of Financial Economics, 20: 317–346.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holmstrom, B., and Milgrom, P., 1991a, “Multi-task Principal–Agent Analyses: Incentive Contracts, Asset Ownership, and Job Design,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 7: 24–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holmstrom, Bengt, 1982a, “Moral Hazard in Teams,” Bell Journal of Economics, 13: 324–340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holmstrom, Bengt, 1982b, “Managerial Incentives – A Dynamic Perspective,” in Essays in Economics and Management in Honor of Lars Wahlbeck. Helsinki: Swedish School of Economics.Google Scholar
Holmstrom, Bengt, 1996, “The Firm as a Subeconomy,” draft, Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
Holmstrom, Bengt, and Milgrom, Paul, 1987, “Aggregation and Linearity in the Provision of Intertemporal Incentives,” Econometrica, 55: 303–328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holmstrom, Bengt, and Milgrom, Paul, 1990, “Regulating Trade Among Agents,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 146: 85–105.Google Scholar
Holmstrom, Bengt, and Milgrom, Paul, 1991b, “Measurement Cost and Organization Theory,” Working Paper, Stanford University.
Holmstrom, Bengt, and Milgrom, Paul, 1994, “The Firm as an Incentive System,” American Economic Review, 84: 972–991.
Holmstrom, Bengt, and Ricart i Costa, Joan, 1986, “Managerial Incentives and Capital Management,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101: 835–860.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holmstrom, Bengt, and Roberts, John, 1998, “The Boundaries of the Firm Revisited,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12(4): 73–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holmstrom, Bengt, and Tirole, Jean, 1989, “The Theory of the Firm,” in Schmalensee, R. and Willig, R. (eds.), The Handbook of Industrial Organization. Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Hubbard, Glenn R., and Weiner, Robert J., 1986, “Regulation and Long-Term Contracting in U.S. Natural Gas Markets,” Journal of Industrial Economics, 35: 71–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hubbard, Glenn R., and Weiner, Robert J., 1991, “Long-Term Contracting and Multiple-Price Systems,” NBER Working Paper 3782, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. (Published in 1992 as “Long-Term Contracting and Multiple-Price Systems,” Journal of Business, 65: 177–198.)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ichniowski, Casey, Levine, David I., Olson, Craig, and Strauss, George, 2000, The American Workplace: Skills, Compensation, and Employee Involvement. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ichniowski, Casey, Shaw, Kathryn, L., and Prennushi, Giovanna, 1997, “The Effects of Human Resource Management Practices on Productivity: A Study of Steel Finishing Lines,” American Economic Review, 87(3): 291–313.Google Scholar
Itoh, Hideshi, 1989, “Coalitions, Incentives, and Risk Sharing,” mimeograph, Kyoto University, Japan.
Itoh, Hideshi, 1991, “Incentives to Help in Multi-Agent Situations,” Econometrica, 59: 611–637.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jarrell, Gregg A., Brickley, James, and Netter, Jeffrey M., 1988, “The Market for Corporate Control: The Empirical Evidence Since 1980,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2: 49–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, M. C., and Meckling, W. H., 1977, “On the Labor-Managed Firm and the Co-determination Movement,” unpublished manuscript.
Jensen, M. C., and Meckling, W. H., 1979, “Rights and Production Functions: An Application to Labor-Managed Firms and Co-determination,” Journal of Business, 52: 469–506.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, Michael C., 1972, “Capital Markets: Theory and Evidence,” Bell Journal of Economics, 3: 357–398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, Michael, 1983, “Organization Theory and Methodology,” Accounting Review, 58: 319–339.Google Scholar
Jensen, Michael, 1986, “Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers,” American Economic Review, 76: 323–329.Google Scholar
Jensen, Michael, 1989, “Eclipse of the public corporation,” Harvard Business Review, 67: 61–74.Google Scholar
Jensen, Michael, 1993, “The modern industrial revolution, exit and the failure of internal control systems,” Journal of Finance, 48: 831–880.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, Michael C., and Meckling, William H., 1976a, “Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure,” Journal of Financial Economics, 3: 305–360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, Michael C., and Meckling, William H., 1976b, “Can the Corporation Survive,” Center for Research in Government Policy and Business Working Paper No. PPS 76–4. Rochester, New York: University of Rochester. (Published in 1978 as “Can the Corporation Survive,” Financial Analysts Journal, 31(1): 31–37.)Google Scholar
Jensen, Michael C., and Meckling, William H., 1988, “The Distribution of Power Among Corporate Managers, Shareholders, and Directors,” Journal of Financial Economics, 20: 3–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, Michael, and Murphy, Kevin, 1990, “Performance Pay and Top Management Incentives,” Journal of Political Economy, 98: 225–263.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, Michael C., and Warner, Jerold B., 1988, “The Distribution of Power Among Corporate Managers, Shareholders, and Directors,” Journal of Financial Economics, 20: 3–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, Harry G., 1963, “The ‘Higher Criticism’ of the Modern Corporation,” Columbia Law Review, 63: 399–432.Google Scholar
Johnson, Marilyn F., Porter, Susan, and Shackell, Margaret B., 1997, “Stakeholder Pressure and the Structure of Executive Compensation,” Working Paper, Michigan State University, University of Massachusetts at Amherst, Notre Dame.
Jones, Eliot, 1927, The Trust Problem. New York: MacMillan.Google Scholar
Joskow, Paul L., 1977, “Commercial Impossibility, the Uranium Market, and the Westinghouse Case,” Journal of Legal Studies, 6: 119–176.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joskow, Paul L., 1985, “Vertical Integration and Long-Term Contracts: The Case of Coal-Burning Electric Generating Plants,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 1: 33–80.Google Scholar
Joskow, Paul L., 1987, “Contract Duration and Relationship-Specific Investments: Empirical Evidence,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 77: 168–185.Google Scholar
Joskow, Paul L., 1988a, “Asset Specificity and the Structure of Vertical Relationships: Empirical Evidence,” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 4: 95–117.Google Scholar
Joskow, Paul L., 1988b, “Price Adjustment in Long-Term Contracts: The Case of Coal,” Journal of Law and Economics, 31: 47–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Juster, R, 1985, “Preferences for Work and Leisure,” Chapter 13 in Thomas, F. Juster and Frank Stafford, P. (eds.), Time, Goods, and Well-Being. Ann Arbor: Institute for Social Research, University of Michigan.Google Scholar
Kahn, C., and Huberman, G., 1988, “Default, Foreclosure, and Strategic Renegotiation,” presented at the Conference on Economics of Contract Law, Duke University.
Kaldor, Nicholas, 1934a, “A Classificatory Note of the Determinateness of Equilibrium,” The Review of Economic Studies, 1: 122–136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaldor, Nicholas, 1934b, “The Equilibrium of the Firm,” Economic Journal, 44: 60–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kandel, Eugene, and Lazear, Edward, 1992, “Peer Pressure and Partnerships,” Journal of Political Economy, 100: 801–817.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplan, Steven N., 1989, “The Effects of Management Buyouts on Operating Performance and Value,” Journal of Financial Economics, 24: 581–618.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kenney, R. W., and Klein, B., 1983, “The Economics of Block Booking,” Journal of Law and Economics, 26: 497–540.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kerr, C., 1954, “The Balkanization of Labor Markets,” in E. Wight Bakke et al., Labor Mobility and Economic Opportunity. Cambridge, MA: Technology Press of MIT.Google Scholar
Kessler, Friedrich, and Stern, Richard H., 1959, “Competition, Contract, and Vertical Integration,” Yale Law Journal, 69: 1–129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard, 1933, Essays in Biography. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Khalil, Elias L., 1994, “Can Transaction-Cost, Competence-Bundle, and Process Theories of the Firms Sustain the Market/Form Dichotomy Thesis?” Working Paper, Ohio State University, Mansfield Campus.
Kihlstrom, Richard, and Laffont, Jean-Jacques, 1979, “A General Equilibrium Entrepreneurial Theory of Firm Formation Based on Risk Aversion,” Journal of Political Economy, 87: 719–747.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kihlstrom, Richard E., and Matthews, Steven A., 1990, “Managerial Incentives in an Entrepreneurial Stock Market Model,” Discussion Papers 876, Northwestern University, Center for Mathematical Studies in Economics and Management, Science.
Kirzner, I., 1973, Competition and Entrepreneurship. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Kirzner, Israel M., 1979, Perception, Opportunity, Profit: Studies in the Theory of Entrepreneurship. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Klein, Benjamin, 1974, “The Competitive Supply of Money,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 6: 423–453.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, Benjamin, 1983, “Contracting Costs and Residual Claims: The Separation of Ownership and Control,” Journal of Law and Economics, 26: 367–374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, Benjamin, 1988, “Vertical Integration as Organized Ownership: The Fisher Body-General Motors Relationship Revisited,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 4: 199–213.Google Scholar
Klein, Benjamin, Crawford, Robert G., and Alchian, Armen, 1978, “Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents and the Competitive Contracting Process,” Journal of Law and Economics, 21: 297–326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, Benjamin, and Leffler, Keith, 1979, “The Role of Market Forces in Assuring Contractual Performance,” Journal of Political Economy, 89: 615–641.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, Benjamin, and McLaughlin, Andrew, 1978, “Resale Price Maintenance, Exclusive Territories, and Franchise Termination: The Coors Case,” unpublished manuscript.
Klein, Peter G., and Shelanski, Howard A., 1994, “Empirical Research in Transaction Cost Economics: A Survey and Assessment,” Business and Public Policy Working Paper BPP-60, Haas School of Business, University of California, Berkeley. (Published in 1995 as “Empirical Research in Transaction Cost Economics: A Review and Assessment,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 11: 335–361.)Google Scholar
Klein, W. A., 1976, “Legal and Economic Perspectives on the Firm,” unpublished manuscript, University of California, Los Angeles.
Knight, Frank, 1921, Risk, Uncertainty and Profit. London: The London School of Economics and Political Science.Google Scholar
Knight, Frank, 1933, Risk, Uncertainty and Profit, preface to the re-issue. London: London School of Economics Series of Reprints, No. 16.Google Scholar
Knight, Frank H., 1965, Risk, Uncertainty and Profit. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Kole, Stacey, and Lehn, Kenneth, 1999, “Deregulation and the Adaptation of Governance Structure: The Case of the U.S. Airline Industry,” Journal of Financial Economics, 52(1): 79–118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kronman, A. T., 1985, “Contract Law and the State of Nature,” Journal of Law, Economies and Organizations, 1: 4–32.Google Scholar
Kroszner, Randall, and Rajan, Raghuram, 1997, “Organization Structure and Credibility: Evidence from Commercial Bank Securities Activities before the Glass-Steagall Act,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper. (Published in 1997 as “Organization Structure and Credibility: Evidence from Commercial Bank Securities Activities before the Glass-Steagall Act,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 39: 475–516.)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krueger, Alan, 1991, “Ownership, Agency, and Wages: An Examination of Franchising in the Fast Food Industry,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106: 75–101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kruse, Douglas, 1993, Profit Sharing: Does It Make a Difference?Kalamazoo, MI: Upjohn Institute for Employment Research.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laffont, Jean-Jacques, and Tirole, Jean, 1989, “Provision of Quality and Power of Incentive Schemes in Regulated Industries,” in Barnett, W., Cornet, B., d'Aspremont, C., Gabsewicz, J., and Mas-Colell, A. (eds.), Equilibrium Theory and Applications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
LaFontaine, Francine, and Slade, Margaret, 1997, “Retail Contracting: Theory and Practice,” Journal of Industrial Economics, 45: 1–25.CrossRef
Langlois, Richard, 2003, “The Vanishing Hand: The Changing Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism,” Industrial and Corporate Change, 12(2): 351–385.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Porta, Rafael, Lopez-de-Silanes, Florencio, and Shleifer, Andrei, 1999, “Corporate Ownership around the World,” Journal of Finance, 54: 471–517.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lawler, Edward, 1971, Pay and Organizational Effectiveness. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Lazear, Edward, 1989, “Pay Equality and Industrial Politics,” Journal of Political Economy, 97: 561–580.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lazear, Edward, and Rosen, Sherwin, 1981, “Rank-Order Tournaments as Optimum Labor Contracts,” Journal of Political Economy, 89: 841–864.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leff, Nathaniel H., 1978, “Industrial Organization and Entrepreneurship in the Developing Countries: The Economic Groups,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, 26: 661–676.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leffler, Keith B., and Rucker, Randal, 1991, “Transaction Costs and the Efficient Organization of Production: A Study of Timber-Harvesting Contracts,” Journal of Political Economy, 99: 1060–1087.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leibenstein, H., 1966, “Allocative Efficiency vs. X-Efficiency,” American Economic Review, 56: 392–415.Google Scholar
Leibenstein, Harvey, 1979, “A Branch of Economics Is Missing: Micro-Micro Theory,” Journal of Economic Literature, 17(2): 477–502.Google Scholar
Leibenstein, Harvey, 1982, “The Prisoners' Dilemma in the Invisible Hand: An Analysis of Intrafirm Productivity,” American Economic Review, 72: 92–97.Google Scholar
Lerner, Abba, 1972, “The Economics and Politics of Consumer Sovereignty,” American Economic Review, 62: 259.Google Scholar
Levi, Margaret, 1988, Of Rule and Revenue. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Levinsohn, Alan, 2001, “A Garden of Stock Options Helps Harvest Talent,” Strategic Finance, 82: 81–82.Google Scholar
Llewellyn, Karl N., 1931, “What Price Contract? An Essay in Perspective,” Yale Law Journal, 40: 704–751.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loasby, Brian J., 1986, “Competition and Imperfect Knowledge: The Contribution of G. B. Richardson,” Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 33: 145–158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lowry, S,1976, “Bargain and Contract Theory in Law and Economics,” Journal of Economic Issues, 10: 1–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lutz, Nancy, 1995, “Ownership Rights and Incentives in Franchising,” Journal of Corporate Finance, 2: 103–131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Macaulay, Stewart, 1963, “Non-Contractual Relations in Business: A Preliminary Study,” American Sociological Review, 28: 55–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacDonald, Glenn, 1984, “New Directions in the Economic Theory of Agency,” Canadian Journal of Economics, 17: 415–440.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Macgregor, David H., 1906, Industrial Combination. London: George Bell and Sons.Google Scholar
Machlup, F., 1967, “Theories of the Firm: Marginalist, Behavioral, Managerial,” American Economic Review, 57: 1–33.Google Scholar
Machlup, F., and Taber, Martha, 1960, “Bilateral Monopoly, Successive Monopoly, and Vertical Integration,” Economica, 27: 101–119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Machlup, Fritz, 1961, International Trade and the National Income Multiplier. New York: A. M. Kelley.Google Scholar
MacLeod, Bentley, 1987, “Behavior and the Organization of the Firm,” Journal of Comparative Economics, 11: 207–220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacLeod, W,1988, “Equity, Efficiency, and Incentives in Cooperative Teams,” in Jones, Derek and Svejar, Jan (eds.), Advances in the Economic Analysis of Participatory and Labor-Managed Firms, Vol. 3. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.Google Scholar
Macneil, I. R., 1974, “The Many Futures of Contracts,” Southern California Law Review, 47: 691–816.Google Scholar
Macneil, I. R., 1978, “Contracts: Adjustment of Long-Term Economic Relations under Classical, Neoclassical, and Relational Contract Law,” Northwestern University Law Review, 72: 854–906.Google Scholar
Malcomson, James, 1984, “Work Incentives, Hierarchy, and Internal Labor Markets,” Journal of Political Economy, 92: 486–507.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malmgren, H., 1961, “Information, Expectations, and the Theory of the Firm,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 75: 399–421.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maness, Robert, 1996, “Incomplete Contracts and the Choice between Vertical Integration and Franchising,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 32: 101–115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Manne, Henry G., 1962, “The ‘Higher Criticism’ of the Modern Corporation,” Columbia Law Review, 53: 259–285.Google Scholar
Manne, Henry, 1965, “Mergers and the Market for Corporate Control,” Journal of Political Economy, 73: 110–120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Manne, Henry G., 1967, “Our Two Corporate Systems: Laws and Economics,” Virginia Law Review, 53: 259–285.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
March, J. G., and Simon, H. A., 1958, Organizations. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Marglin, Stephen, 1974, “What Do Bosses Do? The Origins and Functions of Hierarchy in Capitalist Production,” Review of Radical Political Economics, 6: 60–112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marris, R., 1964, The Economic Theory of Managerial Capitalism. Glencoe, IL: The Free Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marx, Karl, 1967, Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, Volume I. The Process of Capitalist Production. Edited by Engels, Frederick, translated from the Third German Edition by Moore, Samuel and Aveling, Edward. New York: International Publishers.Google Scholar
Masten, Scott, 1988, “A Legal Basis for the Firm,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 4: 191–198.Google Scholar
Masten, Scott E., 1984, “The Organization of Production: Evidence from the Aerospace Industry,” Journal of Law & Economics, 27(2): 403–417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Masten, Scott E., and Crocker, Keith J., 1988, “Efficient Adaptation in Long-Term Contracts: Take-or-Pay Provisions for Natural Gas,” American Economic Review, 75: 1083–1093.Google Scholar
McAfee, R, and McMillan, John, 1991, “Organizational Diseconomies of Scale,” mimeo, University of California, San Diego.
McConnell, John J., and Servaes, Henri, 1990, “Additional evidence on equity ownership and corporate value,” Journal of Financial Economics, 27(2): 595–612.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McManus, J. C., 1975, “The Costs of Alternative Economic Organizations,” Canadian Journal of Economics, 8: 334–350.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meade, J., 1971, The Controlled Economy, London: G. Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Meade, James, 1972, “The Theory of Labor-Managed Firms and of Profit-Sharing,” Economic Journal, 82: 401–428.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meckling, W. H., 1976, “Values and the Choice Model of the Individual in the Social Sciences,” Zeitschrift fur Volkswirtschaft und Statistik, 112: 545–560.Google Scholar
Merton, Robert, 1995, “Financial Innovation and the Management and Regulation of Financial Institutions,” Journal of Banking and Finance, 19: 461–481.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, P., and Roberts, J., 1986, “Relying on the Information of Interested Parties,” Rand Journal of Economics, 17: 18–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, Paul, 1988, “Employment Contracts, Influence Activities and Efficient Organization Design,” Journal of Political Economy, 96: 42–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, Paul, and Roberts, John, 1988a, “An Economic Approach to Influence Activities and Organizational Responses,” American Journal of Sociology, 93: S154–S179.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, Paul, and Roberts, John, 1988b, “Economic Theories of the Firm: Past, Present, and Future,” Canadian Journal of Economics, 21: 444.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, Paul A., and Roberts, John, 1990a, “Bargaining Costs, Influence Costs, and the Organization of Economic Activity,” in Alt, James E. and Shepsle, Kenneth A. (eds.), Perspectives on Positive Political Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Milgrom, Paul, and Roberts, John, 1990b, “The Economics of Modern Manufacturing: Technology, Strategy, and Organization,” American Economic Review, 80: 511–528.Google Scholar
Milgrom, Paul, and Roberts, John, 1992, Economics, Organization, and Management. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Milgrom, Paul, and Roberts, John, 1993, “Johnson Controls, Inc.: Automotive Systems Group: The Georgetown Kentucky Plant,” Stanford Graduate School of Business, Case S-BE-9.
Minahan, John, 1988, “Managerial Incentive Schemes and the Divisional Structure of Firms,” mimeograph, University of Massachusetts.
Mitchell, Daniel E. B., and Kimbell, Larry J., 1982, “Labor Market Contracts and Inflation,” in Baily, Martin Neil (ed.), Workers, Jobs, and Inflation. Washington, DC: The Brookings, Institution.Google Scholar
Monsen, R. J., and Downs, A., 1965, “A Theory of Large Managerial Firms,” Journal of Political Economy, 73: 221–236.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Monteverde, Kirk, and Teece, David, 1982, “Supplier Switching Costs and Vertical Integration in the Automobile Industry,” Bell Journal of Economics, 13: 206–213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Montias, J, 1970, “The Price Mechanism in Socialist Countries – Discussion,” American Economic Review, 60: 321–323.Google Scholar
Montias, John M., 1976, The Structure of Economic Systems. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Morck, Randall, Shleifer, Andrei, and Vishny, Robert W., 1988, “Management Ownership and Market Valuation: An Empirical Analysis,” Journal of Financial Economics, 20: 293–315.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morris, Charles, 1980, The Cost of Good Intentions, New York: W.W. Norton.Google Scholar
Mulherin, J, 1986, “Complexity in Long-Term Contracts: An Analysis of Natural Gas Contractual Provisions,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 2: 105–117.Google Scholar
Murphy, Kevin J., 1999, “Executive Compensation,” in Handbook of Labor Economics. Ashenfelter, Orley and Card, David (eds.), North Holland, 2485–2563.Google Scholar
Murphy, Kevin J., 2002, “Explaining Executive Compensation: Managerial Power vs. the Perceived Cost of Stock Options,” University of Chicago Law Review, 69: 847–869.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Muth, John F., 1960, “Optimal Properties of Exponentially Weighted Forecasts,” Journal of the American Statistical Association, 55: 299–306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myerson, R., 1979. “Incentive Compatibility and the Bargaining Problem,” Econometrica, 47: 61–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nalbantian, Haig R. (ed.), 1987, Incentives, Cooperation, and Risk Sharing: Economic and Psychological Perspectives on Employment Contracts. Totowa, NJ: Rowman and Littlefield.
National Association of Corporate Directors, 1995, Report of the NACD Blue Ribbon Commission on Director Compensation. NACD, Washington, D.C.
Nelson, Charles R., 1973, Applied Time Series Forecast for Managerial Forecasting. San Francisco: Holden-Day.Google Scholar
Nelson, R., 1959, Merger Movements in American Industry, 1895–1956. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Nelson, Richard R., and Winter, Sidney G., 1982, An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Neuberger, Egon, and James, Estelle, 1973, “The Yugoslav Self-Managed Enterprise: A Systemic Approach,” 245–284 in Bornstein, Morris (ed.), Plan and Market: Economic Reform in Eastern Europe. New Haven, CT:Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Newman, Andrew, 1995, “Employment Contracts, Finance, and the Distribution of Wealth,” in Roemer, J. E. (ed.), Property Relations, Incentives and Welfare. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Nilsson, Eric, 1989, “International Trade and the Social Relations of Production,” Ph.D. dissertation, University of Massachusetts.
North, Douglas, 1981, Structure and Change in Economic History. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Novaes, W., and Zingales, L., 1995, “Capital Structure Choice When Managers Are in Control: Entrenchment versus Efficiency,” NBER Working Paper No. 5384, available at gsblgz.uchicago.edu.
Nove, Alec, 1958, “The Problem of Success Indicators in Soviet Industry,” Economica, 25: 1–13.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nutter, Warren, 1951, The Extent of Enterprise Monopoly in the United States 1899–1939. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Ofek, Eli, and Yermack, David, 2000, “Taking Stock: Equity-Based Compensation and the Evolution of Managerial Ownership,” Journal of Finance, 55(3): 1367–1384.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ortiz, Fernando, 1963, Contraputo del Tabaco y el Azucar. Barcelona: Editorial Ariel.Google Scholar
Ortuno-Ortin, Ignacio, Roemer, John E., and Silvestre, Joaquim, 1993, “Investment Planning and Market Socialism,” in Bowles, S., Gintis, H., and Gustafsson, B. (eds.), The Microfoundations of Political Economy: Problems of Participation, Democracy, and Efficiency. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Pagano, Ugo, 1985, Work and Welfare in Economic Theory. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Pagano, Ugo, 1988, “Determinazione Endogena dei Diritti di Proprieta in un Economia di Mercato,” Working Paper, University of Siena.
Palay, Thomas M., 1984. “Comparative Institutional Economics: The Governance of Rail Freight Contracting,” Journal of Legal Studies, 13: 265–287.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pearl, Meyers & Partners, 2002, Executive Pay Trends: Looking Forward and Looking Back.
Pejovich, S., 1969, “The Firm, Monetary Policy and Property Rights in a Planned Economy,” Economic Inquiry, 7(3): 193–200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pencavel, John, 2001, Worker Participation: Lessons from the Worker Co-Ops of the Pacific Northwest. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Penrose, E., 1958, The Theory of the Growth of the Firm. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Perrow, Charles, 1983, Normal Accidents: Living with High-Risk Technologies. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Plant, Arnold, 1932, “Trends in Business Administration,” Economica, 12: 45–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powell, Walter, 1996, “Inter-Organizational Collaboration in the Biotechnology Industry,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 152(1): 197–215.Google Scholar
Preston, L. E., 1975, “Corporation and Society: The Search for a Paradigm,” Journal of Economic Literature, 13: 434–453.Google Scholar
Publishers' Association v. Newspaper and Mail Delivery Union, 1952, 114 N.Y.S. 2d401.
Putterman, Louis, 1984, “On Some Recent Explanations of Why Capital Hires Labor,” Economic Inquiry, 22: 171–187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Putterman, Louis, 1988, “The Firm as Association versus the Firm as Commodity: Efficiency, Rights, and Ownership,” Economics and Philosophy, 4: 243–266.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Putterman, Louis, 1993a, “Ownership and the Nature of the Firm,” Journal of Comparative Economics, 17: 243–263.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Putterman, Louis, 1993b, “Exit, Voice, and Portfolio Choice: Agency and Public Ownership,” Economics and Politics, 5: 205–218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Putterman, Louis, 1993c, “Incentive Problems Favoring Noncentralized Investment Fund Ownership,” pp. 156–168 in Bardhan, P. and Roemer, J. E. (eds.), Market Socialism: The Current Debate. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Putterman, Louis, 1995, “Markets, Hierarchies, and Information: On a Paradox in the Economics of Organization,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 26: 373–390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Putterman, Louis, and Dietrich, Rueschemeyer (eds.), 1992, States and Markets in Development: Synergy or Rivalry?Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.Google Scholar
Putterman, Louis, and Skillman, Gilbert, 1992, “The Role of Exist in the Theory of Cooperative\Teams,” Journal of Comparative Economics, 16: 596–618.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Radner, R., 1970, “Problems in the Theory of Markets under Uncertainty,” The American Economic Review, 60: 454–460.Google Scholar
Rajan, Raghuram G., and Zingales, Luigi, 1997, “The Firm as a Dedicated Hierarchy,” University of Chicago Working Paper, available at gsblgz.uchicago.edu.
Rajan, Raghuram G., and Zingales, Luigi, 1998, “Power in a Theory of the Firm,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(2): 387–432.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rajan, Raghuram G., and Zingales, Luigi, 2001, “The Firm as a Dedicated Hierarchy: A Theory of the Origins and Growth of Firms,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(3): 805–851.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rappaport, Alfred, 1999, “New Thinking on How to Link Executive Pay with Performance,” Harvard Business Review, 77(2): 91–101.Google ScholarPubMed
Richardson, G. B., 1972, “The Organization of Industry,” Economic Journal, 82: 883–896.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Richardson, G. B., 1990, Information and Investment: A Study in the Working of the Competitive Economy, with a New Foreword by David Teece. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Riordan, Michael, 1990, “Vertical Integration and the Strategic Management of the Enterprise,” in Aoki, M., Gustafsson, B., and Williamson, O. (eds.), The Firm as a Nexus of Treaties. London: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Robbins, L., 1932, An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Robertson, D. H., 1930, Control of Industry. London: Nisbet and Co.Google Scholar
Robinson, E. A. G., 1931, The Structure of Competitive Industry. London: Nisbet; and Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Robinson, E. A. G., 1934, “The Problem of Management and the Size of the Firm,” The Economic Journal, 44: 242–257.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, Joan, 1932, Economics Is a Serious Subject: The Apologia of an Economist to the Mathematician, the Scientist and the Plain Man. Cambridge: W. Heffer and Sons.Google Scholar
Roe, Mark, 1994, Strong Managers, Weak Owners: The Political Roots of American Corporate Finance, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Roemer, John, 1994, A Future for Socialism. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ross, S. A., 1973, “The Economic Theory of Agency: The Principal's Problem,” American Economic Review, 62: 134–139.Google Scholar
Ross, S. A., 1974, “The Economic Theory of Agency and the Principal's Similarity,” in Balch, Michael, McFadden, Daniel, and Wu, Shih-yen (eds.), Essays on Economic Behavior under Uncertainty. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Ryan, Alan, 1987, “Property,” in John Eatwell, Murray, and Newman, Peter (eds.), The New Palgrave: Dictionary of Economics. New York: Stockton Press.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul, 1957, “Wages and Interest: A Modern Dissection of Marxian Economics,” American Economic Review, 47: 884–912.Google Scholar
Schelling, T., 1971, “On the Ecology of Micromotives,” The Public Interest, 25: 61–98.Google Scholar
Scherer, R., and Ross, David, 1990, Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance, Boston: Houghton Mifflin Company.Google Scholar
Schmidt, Peter, and Strauss, Robert P., 1976, “The Effect of Unions on Earnings and Earnings on Unions: A Mixed Logit Approach,” International Economic Review, 17: 204–212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schor, Juliet B., and Bowles, Samuel, 1987, “Employment Rents and the Incidence of Strikes,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 64(4): 584–591.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scott, Richard, 1981, Organizations. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Segal, Ilya, and Whinston, Michael, 1997, “On the Transaction Cost Determinants of Vertical Integration,” draft, Department of Economics, Northwestern University.
Selznick, Philip, 1948, “Foundations of the Theory of Organization,” American Sociological Review, 13: 25–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selznick, Philip, 1949, TVA and the Grass Roots: A Study in the Sociology of Formal Organization. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Seyhun, H, 1998, Investment Intelligence from Insider Trading. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Shapiro, Carl, and Stiglitz, Joseph, 1984, “Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device,” American Economic Review, 74: 433–444.Google Scholar
Shepard, Andrea, 1993, “Contractual Form, Retail Price, and Asset Characteristics,” Rand Journal of Economics, 24: 58–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shove, G. F., 1933, “The Imperfection of the Market: A Further Note,” The Economic Journal, 43: 113–124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shubik, M., 1970, “A Curmudgeon's Guide to Microeconomics,” Journal of Economic Literature, 8: 405–434.Google Scholar
Shleifer, Andrei, and Vishny, Robert W., 1986, “Large Shareholders and Corporate Control,” Journal of Political Economy, 94(3): 461–488.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Silver, M., and Auster, R., 1969, “Entrepreneurship, Profit and Limits on Firm Size,” Journal of Business, 42: 277–281.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, H., 1959, “Theories of Decision Making in Economics and Behavioral Science,” American Economic Review, 49: 253–283.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A., 1955, “A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 69: 99–118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, H. A., 1957, Models of Man. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert, 1951, “A Formal Theory of the Employment Relation,” Econometrica, 19: 293–305. Reprinted in Models of Man, 1957, New York: Wiley.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, Herbert, 1991, “Organizations and Markets,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5: 25–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slade, Margaret, 1996, “Multitask Agency and Contract Choice: An Empirical Assessment,” International Economic Review, 37: 465–486.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Adam, 1937, The Wealth of Nations, Cannan edition. New York: Modern Library. Originally published in 1776.Google Scholar
Smith, Clifford, and Watts, Ross, 1992, “The investment opportunity set and corporate financing, dividend, and compensation policies,” Journal of Financial Economics, 32: 263–292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sonnenschein, Hugo, 1987, “Oligopoly and Game Theory,” John Eatwell, Murray, and Newman, Peter (eds.), in The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Spence, Michael, and Zeckhauser, Richard, 1971, “Insurance, Information, and Individual Action,” American Economic Review, 61: 380–387.Google Scholar
Steinherr, Alfred, and Thisse, J-F, 1979, “Are Labor-Managers Really Perverse?Economics Letters, 2: 137–142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, George, and Friedland, Claire, 1983, “The Literature of Economics: The Case of Berle and Means,” Journal of Law and Economics, 26: 237–268.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph, 1975, “Incentives, Risk, and Information: Notes toward a Theory of Hierarchy,” Bell Journal of Economics, 6: 552–579.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E., 1977, “The Theory of Local Public Goods,” in The Economics of Public Services, Martin Feldstein, S. and Robert Inman, P. (eds.), London: Macmillan, for International Economic Association.Google Scholar
Stinchcombe, Arthur L., 1983, “Contracts as Hierarchical Documents,” unpublished manuscript, Stanford Graduate School of Business.
Stuckey, John, 1983, Vertical Integration and Joint Ventures in the Aluminum Industry. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Stulz, Rene, 1988, “Managerial Control of Voting Rights: Financing Policies and the Market tor Corporate Control,” Journal of Financial Economics, 20: 24–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stulz, Rene, 1996, “Rethinking Risk Management,” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 9: 8–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Summers, C., 1969, “Collective Agreements and the Law of Contracts,” Yale Law Journal, 78: 527–575.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tajfel, Henri, 1970, “Experiments in Intergroup Discrimination,” Scientific American, 223: 96–102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, Curtis, and Wiggins, Steven, 1997, “Competition or Compensation: Supplier Incentives Under the American and Japanese Subcontracting Systems,” American Economic Review, 87(4): 598–618.Google Scholar
Teece, David J., 1976, Vertical Integration and Vertical Divestiture in the U.S. Petroleum Industry. Stanford, CA: Stanford University.Google Scholar
Teece, David J., 1980, “Economics of Scope and the Scope of Enterprise,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 1: 223–247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Teece, David J., 1982, “Towards an Economic Theory of the Multiproduct Firm,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 3: 39–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Teece, David, Rumelt, Richard, Dosi, Giovanni, and Winter, Sidney, 1994, “Understanding Corporate Coherence, Theory and Evidence,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 23: 1–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomas, Randall S., and Martin, Kenneth J., 1999, “The Effect of Shareholder Proposals on Executive Compensation,” University of Cincinnati Law Review, 67: 1021–1081.Google Scholar
Thompson, E. A., 1970, “Nonpecuniary Rewards and the Aggregate Production Function,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 52: 395–404.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tiebout, Charles M., 1956, “A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures,” Journal of Political Economy, 64(5): 416–424.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tirole, Jean, 1986, “Hierarchies and Bureaucracies: On the Role of Collusion in Organizations,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 2: 181–214.Google Scholar
Trivers, R. L., 1971, “The Evolution of Reciprocal Altruism,” Quarterly Review of Biology, 46: 35–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tufano, Peter, 1996, “Who Manages Risk? An Empirical Examination of Risk Management Practices in the Gold Mining Industry,” Journal of Finance, 51: 1097–1138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Turner, John C., 1987, Rediscovering the Social Group: A Self-Categorization Theory. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Urquhart, David, 1856, Familiar Words as Affecting England and the English. London: Trubner & Co.Google Scholar
Usher, Abbott P., 1921, Introduction to the Industrial History of England. London: G. C. Harrap and Co., Ltd.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein, 1964, Absentee Ownership and Business Enterprise in Recent Times: The Case of America. New York: B. W. Huebsch, reprinted by Augustus M. Kelly.Google Scholar
Stackelberg, H., 1934, Marktform and Gleichgewicht. Vienna: Springer-Verlag.Google Scholar
Wade, James B., Porac, Joseph, and Pollock, Timothy, 1997, “Worth, Words, and the Justification of Executive Pay,” Journal of Organizational Behavior, 18: 641–664.3.0.CO;2-M>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walton, Mary, 1997, Car: A Drama of the American Workplace. New York: W.W. Norton.Google Scholar
Watts, Ross L., and Zimmerman, Jerod, 1978, “Auditors and the Determination of Accounting Standards, an Analysis of the Lack of Independence,” Working Paper GPB 7806, University of Rochester, Graduate School of Management.
Weisbach, Michael, 1988, “Outside Directors and CEO Turnover,” Journal of Financial Economics, 20: 431–460.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weitzman, Martin L., and Kruse, Douglas, 1990, “Profit Sharing and Productivity,” in Blinder, Alan S. (ed.), Paying for Productivity: A Look at the Evidence. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
White, Harrison, 1981. “Where Do Markets Come From?American Journal of Sociology, 87: 517–547.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
White, Horace, J, 1936, “Monopolistic and Perfect Competition,” American Economic Review, 26: 645.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E., 1964a, “The Economics of Antitrust: Transaction Cost Considerations,” University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 122: 1439–1496.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, O. E., 1964b, The Economics of Discretionary Behavior: Managerial Objectives in a Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E., 1970, Corporate Control and Business Behavior. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E., 1975, Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Anti-Trust Implications. New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E., 1967a, “Hierarchical Control and Optimum Firm Size,” Journal of Political Economy, 75: 123–138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E., 1967b, “The Economics of Defense Contracting: Incentives and Performance,” in Issues in Defense Economics. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E., 1971, “The Vertical Integration of Production: Market Failure and Considerations,” American Economic Review, 61: 112–123.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver, 1979, “Transaction-Cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Relations,” Journal of Law and Economics, 22: 233–261.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver, E., 1985, The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, and Relational Contracting. New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver, 1988, “The Logic of Economic Organizations,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 4: 65.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver, 1994, “Evaluating Coase,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8: 201–204.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver, Wachter, Michael, and Harris, Jeffery, 1975, “Understanding the Employment Relation,” Bell Journal of Economics, 6: 250–278.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E., and Winter, Sidney G. (eds.), 1991, The Nature of the Firm: Origins, Evolution, and Development. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Wilson, R., 1968, “On the Theory of Syndicates,” Econometrica, 36: 119–132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, R., 1969, La Decision: Aggregation et Dynamique des Orders de Preference, Extrait. Paris: Editions du Centre National de la Recherche, Scientifique.Google Scholar
Wolfson, Mark A., 1983, “Empirical Evidence of Incentive Problems and Their Mitigation in Oil and Gas Tax Shelter Programs,” unpublished manuscript, Stanford University.
,World Bank, 1991, World Development Report 1991. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Yermack, David, 1996, “Higher Market Valuation of Companies with a Small Board of Directors,” Journal of Financial Economics, 40: 185–213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yermack, David, 1997, “Good Timing: CEO Stock Option Awards and Company News Announcements,” Journal of Finance, 52: 449–476.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yunker, James A., 1992, Socialism Revised and Modernized: The Case for Pragmatic Market Socialism. New York: Praeger.Google Scholar
Zingales, Luigi, 1998, “Corporate Governance,” in The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law, Newman, P. (ed.). New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Edited by Randall S. Kroszner, Louis Putterman, Brown University, Rhode Island
  • Book: The Economic Nature of the Firm
  • Online publication: 05 June 2014
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511817410.029
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Edited by Randall S. Kroszner, Louis Putterman, Brown University, Rhode Island
  • Book: The Economic Nature of the Firm
  • Online publication: 05 June 2014
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511817410.029
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Edited by Randall S. Kroszner, Louis Putterman, Brown University, Rhode Island
  • Book: The Economic Nature of the Firm
  • Online publication: 05 June 2014
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511817410.029
Available formats
×