Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-ttngx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-01T11:46:38.881Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

6 - Conceptions of poverty and poor-relief in Turin in the second half of the eighteenth century

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 July 2010

Stuart Woolf
Affiliation:
University of Essex
Get access

Summary

Introduction

The idea that poverty is a relative rather than an absolute concept appears to be widely accepted. Historians recognize that different societies define need and the necessity of relief in different ways. It has even been proposed that the term ‘poverty’ be replaced by ‘deprivation’, in that this automatically suggests greater flexibility and points to the dependency of the threshold of need on culturally determined variables.

The relative nature of the concept of ‘poverty’ is usually attributed to two considerations. First, to a series of conventions about what is regarded as a necessity which define acceptable standards of living. Then, there are boundaries, which are also liable to change, that distinguish between the deserving and the undeserving poor, according to various sets of values and ideological frameworks.

Even though they underline the importance of a relativist approach, historians, it seems, hold on to an element of objectivity in the shape of a hierarchy of need, albeit based on the notion of convention. This is seen as the key criterion through which different social and cultural milieux were accustomed to identify and measure poverty and to model their systems of welfare. Such assumptions, in my view, have deeply influenced studies in the field, imposing two major methodological orientations. On the one hand, such studies have considered that the population in receipt of welfare could be taken as revealing the structure if not the dimensions of poverty.

Type
Chapter
Information
Domestic Strategies
Work and Family in France and Italy, 1600–1800
, pp. 148 - 199
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 1991

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×