Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-qxdb6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-28T05:01:31.096Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Bibliography

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  26 July 2018

Paul Dragos Aligica
Affiliation:
George Mason University, Virginia
Get access
Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2018

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alchian, A. A., and Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization. The American Economic Review, 62(5), 777795.Google Scholar
Aligica, P. D. (2003). Rethinking Institutional Analysis: Interviews with Vincent and Elinor Ostrom. (Interview), Mercatus Center at George Mason University.Google Scholar
Aligica, P. D. (2014). Institutional Diversity and Political Economy, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Aligica, P. D. (2016). Neither Market nor State Domain: Nonprofits from the Ostroms’ Theoretical Perspective. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 45(4_suppl), 43S60S.Google Scholar
Aligica, P. D., and Boettke, P. J. (2009). Challenging Institutional Analysis and Development: The Bloomington School, New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Aligica, P. D., & Tarko, V. (2013). Co-Production, Polycentricity, and Value Heterogeneity: The Ostroms’ Public Choice Institutionalism RevisitedAmerican Political Science Review107(4), 726-741.Google Scholar
Anheier, H. K. (2005). Nonprofit Organizations: Theory, Management, Policy, New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Anheier, H. K., and Ben-Ner, A. (Eds.). (2003). The Study of the Nonprofit Enterprise: Theories and Approaches, New York: Springer.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J. (1963). Social Choice and Individual Values. Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics at Yale University Monograph 12, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Audretsch, D. B., Grilo, I., and Thurik, A. R. (Eds.). (2007). Explaining Entrepreneurship and the Role of Policy: A Framework. In Handbook of Research on Entrepreneurship Policy, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, pp. 117.Google Scholar
Bakunin, M. A. (1990). Bakunin: Statism and Anarchy, edited by Shatz, M.. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barnett, R. E. (1998). The Structure of Liberty: Justice & the Rule of Law, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Barry, N. P. (1988). The Invisible Hand in Economics and Politics: A Study in the Two Conflicting Explanations of Society: End-States and Processes, London: Institute of Economic Affairs.Google Scholar
Baumol, W. J. (1990). Entrepreneurship: Productive, Unproductive, and Destructive. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), 893921.Google Scholar
Ben-Ner, A. (1986). Nonprofit Organizations: Why Do They Exist in Market Economies? In Rose-Ackerman, S., ed., The Economics of Nonprofit Institutions: Studies in Structure and Policy, New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 94113.Google Scholar
Ben-Ner, A., and Gui, B. (2003). The Theory of Nonprofit Organizations Revisited. In Anheier, H. K. and Ben-Ner, A., eds., The Study of the Nonprofit Enterprise: Theories and Approaches, Boston: Springer, pp. 326.Google Scholar
Bennett, S. E. (2006). Democratic Competence, Before Converse and After. Critical Review, 18(1–3), 105141.Google Scholar
Bergson, A. (1954). On the Concept of Social Welfare. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 68(2), 233252.Google Scholar
Boettke, P. (2010). Handbook on Contemporary Austrian Economics. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Boettke, P. J., and Coyne, C. J. (2008). The Political Economy of the Philanthropic Enterprise. In Shockley, G. E., Frank, P. M., and Stough, R., eds., Non-Market Entrepreneurship: Interdisciplinary Approaches, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, p. 7188.Google Scholar
Boettke, P., and Prychitko, D. (2004). Is an Independent Nonprofit Sector Prone to Failure? Toward an Austrian School Interpretation of Nonprofit and Voluntary Action. Conversations on Philanthropy, 1(1), 163.Google Scholar
Boulding, K. E. (1981). A Preface to Grants Economics: The Economy of Love and Fear, New York: Praeger.Google Scholar
Boyte, Harry (2011). Public Work and the Politics of the Commons. The Good Society, 20(1), 84102.Google Scholar
Brennan, G., Eriksson, L., Goodin, R. E., and Southwood, N. (2013). Explaining Norms, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Brennan, J. (2016a). Against Democracy, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Brennan, J. (2016b, June 24). Ethicist Jason Brennan: Brexit, Democracy, and Epistocracy. Princeton University Press Blog. Retrieved from http://blog.press.princeton.edu/2016/06/24/ethicist-jason-brennan-brexit-democracy-and-epistocracy/Google Scholar
Brennan, J. (2016c, August 28). Can Epistocracy, or Knowledge-Based Voting, Fix Democracy? Los Angeles Times. Retrieved from http://www.latimes.com/opinion/op-ed/la-oe-brennan-epistocracy-20160828-snap-story.htmlGoogle Scholar
Brennan, J. (2017). Against Democracy, new preface edition, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Breton, A. (1996). Competitive Governments, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (1964). What Should Economists Do? Southern Economic Journal, 30(3), 213222.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (1965). An Economic Theory of Clubs. Economica, 32(125), 114.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. ([1968] 1999). The Collected Works of James M. Buchanan Vol. 5: The Demand and Supply of Public Goods, Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (1975). The Limits of Liberty: Between Anarchy and Leviathan, University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (1979). What Should Economists Do? Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, Inc.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (1984). Politics Without Romance: A Sketch of Positive Public Choice Theory and Its Normative Implications. In Buchanan, J. M. and Tollison, R. D., eds., The Theory of Public Choice II, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, pp. 1122.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (1987). Justification of the Compound Republic: The Calculus in Retrospect. Cato Journal, 7(2), 305315.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (1990). The Domain of Constitutional Economics. Constitutional Political Economy, 1(1), 118.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (1991). The Foundations of Normative Individualism. In Buchanan, J. M., ed., The Economics and the Ethics of Constitutional Order, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press., pp. 221229.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (1999). The Collected Works of James M. Buchanan Vol. 1: The Logical Foundations of Constitutional Liberty, Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (2000). The Soul of Classical Liberalism. The Independent Review, 5(1), 111119.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (2006). Why I, Too, Am Not a Conservative: The Normative Vision of Classical Liberalism, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Caplan, B. (2001). Rational Irrationality and the Microfoundations of Political Failure. Public Choice, 107(3), 311331.Google Scholar
Caplan, B. (2008). The Myth of the Rational Voter: Why Democracies Choose Bad Policies, new edition with a new preface by the author, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Carson, K. (2013). Governance, Agency and Autonomy: Anarchist Themes in the Work of Elinor Ostrom. The Center for a Stateless Society Paper No. 16 (Second Half 2013).Google Scholar
Cartwright, N., and Hardie, J. (2012). Evidence-Based Policy: A Practical Guide to Doing It Better, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Cassirer, E. (1961). The Myth of the State, New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Chamlee-Wright, E. (2010). The Cultural and Political Economy of Recovery: Social Learning in a Post-Disaster Environment, New York: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, J. P. (2013). The Impossible Community: Realizing Communitarian Anarchism, New York: Bloomsbury Publishing USA.Google Scholar
Clemens, E. S. (2006). The Constitution of Citizens: Political Theories of Nonprofit Organizations. In Powell, W. W. and Steinberg, R., eds., The Nonprofit Sector: A Research Handbook, New Haven: Yale University Press, pp. 207220.Google Scholar
Converse, P. E. (1964). The Nature of Belief Systems in Mass Publics. Critical Review, 18(1–3), 174.Google Scholar
Converse, P. E. (1975). Public Opinion and Voting Behavior. In Greenstein, F. I. and Polsby, N. W., eds., Handbook of Political Science, Vol. 4, Boston: Addison-Wesley, pp. 75169.Google Scholar
Cooter, R. (1997). Normative Failure Theory of Law. Cornell Law Review, 82(5), 947979.Google Scholar
Cooter, R. (1998). Expressive Law and Economics. The Journal of Legal Studies, 27(S2), 585607.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coyne, C. (2013). Doing Bad by Doing Good: Why Humanitarian Action Fails, Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Crowder, G. (1992). Classical Anarchism : The Political Thought of Godwin, Proudhon, Bakunin, and Kropotkin, 1st edition, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Dahl, R. A. (1989). Democracy and Its Critics, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Dollery, B. E., and Wallis, J. (2003). The Political Economy of the Voluntary Sector: A Reappraisal of the Comparative Institutional Advantage of Voluntary Organisations, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Downs, A. (1957). An Economic Theory of Democracy, New York: Harper.Google Scholar
Durieux, H. (2011). Subsidiarity, Anarchism, and the Governance of Complexity. Koninklijke Vlaamse Academie van België voor Wetenschappen en Kunsten, Contactforum.Google Scholar
Easterly, W. (2008). Design and Reform of Institutions in LDCs and Transition Economies Institutions: Top Down or Bottom Up? American Economic Review, 98(2), 9599.Google Scholar
Elkin, S. and Soltan, K. (Eds.). (1999). Citizen Competence and Democratic Institutions, University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press.Google Scholar
Ellerman, D. P. (1986). The Employment Contract and Liberal Thought. Review of Social Economy, 44(1), 1339.Google Scholar
Ellerman, D. (1999). The Democratic Firm: An Argument Based on Ordinary Jurisprudence. Journal of Business Ethics, 21(2), 111124.Google Scholar
Elster, J. (1989). The Cement of Society: A Survey of Social Order, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Epstein, R. A. (2003). Skepticism and Freedom: A Modern Case for Classical Liberalism, University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Epstein, R. A. (2009). Simple Rules for a Complex World, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Ferguson, W. D. (2013). Collective Action and Exchange: A Game-Theoretic Approach to Contemporary Political Economy. Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Foss, N. (1994). The Theory of the Firm: The Austrians as Precursors and Critics of Contemporary Theory. Review of Austrian Economics, 7(1), 3165.Google Scholar
Foucault, M. (1977). Discipline and Punish: The Birth of the Prison, New York: Vintage Books.Google Scholar
Freeden, M. (2015). In Freeden, M., Sargent, L. T., and Stears, M., eds., The Oxford Handbook of Political Ideologies, Reprint edition, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, D. (1973). The Machinery of Freedom, Chicago: Open Court Publishing Company.Google Scholar
Friedman, J. (2006). Democratic Competence in Normative and Positive Theory: Neglected Implications of “The Nature of Belief Systems in Mass Publics.” Critical Review, 18(1–3), 143.Google Scholar
Galston, W. A. (1991). Liberal Purposes: Goods, Virtues, and Diversity in the Liberal State, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gaus, G. (2010). The Order of Public Reason: A Theory of Freedom and Morality in a Diverse and Bounded World, Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gaus, G. (2011). Between Discovery and Choice: The General Will in a Diverse Society. Contemporary Readings in Law and Social Justice, 3(2), 7095.Google Scholar
Gaus, G. (2013). The Evolution, Evaluation, and Reform of Social Morality: A Hayekian Analysis. In Peart, S. J. and Levy, D. M., eds., F. A. Hayek and the Modern Economy: Economic Organization and Activity, New York: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 5988.Google Scholar
Gaus, G. (2016). The Tyranny of the Ideal: Justice in a Diverse Society, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Gaus, G. (2017). Is Public Reason a Normalization Project? Deep Diversity and the Open Society. Social Philosophy Today, 33, 2752.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, G. (2000). Adaptive Thinking: Rationality in the Real World, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Goldman, A. I. (1999). Social Epistemology. Crítica: Revista Hispanoamericana de Filosofía, 31(93), 319.Google Scholar
Goldman, A. I., and Whitcomb, D. (Eds.). (2011). Social Epistemology: Essential Readings, 1st edition, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Goldman, E. (2012). Anarchism and Other Essays, Mineola, NY: Courier Corporation.Google Scholar
Goodin, R. E. and Tilly, C. (Eds.). (2008). The Oxford Handbook of Contextual Political Analysis, 1st edition, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Granovetter, M. (1978). Threshold Models of Collective Behavior. American Journal of Sociology 83(6), 14201443.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Green, D., and Shapiro, I. (1996). Pathologies of Rational Choice Theory: A Critique of Applications in Political Science, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Groenewegen, J. (2011). The Bloomington School and American Institutionalism. The Good Society, 20(1): 1536.Google Scholar
Grube, L., and Storr, V. H. (2013). The Capacity for Self-Governance and Post-Disaster Resiliency. Review of Austrian Economics, 27(3), 301324.Google Scholar
Gutmann, A. (1980). Liberal Equality, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hammack, D. C., and Young, D. R. (1993). Nonprofit Organizations in a Market Economy: Understanding New Roles, Issues, and Trends, San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass Publishers.Google Scholar
Hansmann, H. (2003). The Role of Trust in Nonprofit Enterprise. In Anheier, H. and Ben-Ner, A., eds., The Study of the Nonprofit Enterprise: Theories and Approaches, Boston: Springer, pp. 115122.Google Scholar
Hansmann, H., and Powell, W. W. (1987). Economic Theories of Nonprofit Organization. In Powell, W. W. and Steinberg, R., eds., The Nonprofit Sector: A Research Handbook, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, pp. 117139.Google Scholar
Harper, D. A., and Lewis, P. (2012). New Perspectives on Emergence in Economics. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 82(2–3), 329–37.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1945). The Use of Knowledge in Society. American Economic Review, 35(4), 519–30.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1948). Economics and Knowledge. Reprinted in Individualism and Economic Order, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 3356.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. ([1960] 1978). The Constitution of Liberty, University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1967). Notes on the Evolution of Systems of Rules of Conduct. In Studies in Philosophy, Politics and Economics, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 6681.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (]1973] 1998). Law, Legislation and Liberty, Volume 1: Rules and Order, unknown edition, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. ([1976] 1998). Law, Legislation and Liberty, Volume 2: The Mirage of Social Justice, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. ([1979] 1998). Law, Legislation and Liberty, Volume 3: The Political Order of a Free People, Volume 3 in series; softcover edition, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1992). Why I Am Not a Conservative. The Centre for Independent Studies, 41, 128.Google Scholar
Heckathorn, D. (1996). The Dynamics and Dilemmas of Collective Action. American Sociological Review, 61(2), 250277.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Helmke, G., and Levitsky, S. (2004). Informal Institutions and Comparative Politics: A Research Agenda. Perspectives on Politics, 2(4), 725740.Google Scholar
Hirschman, A. O. (1971). Introduction: Political Economics and Possibilism. In Bias for Hope: Essays on Development and Latin America, 1st edition, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, pp. 2637.Google Scholar
Hirschman, A. O. (1991). The Rhetoric of Reaction: Perversity, Futility, Jeopardy, 1st edition, Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huemer, M. (2012). The Problem of Political Authority: An Examination of the Right to Coerce and the Duty to Obey, Basingstoke, UK: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Iannaccone, L. (1998). Introduction to the Economics of Religion. Journal of Economic Literature. 36 (3), 14651495.Google Scholar
James, E., (Ed.). (1989). The Nonprofit Sector in International Perspective: Studies in Comparative Culture & Policy. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
James, E. (1990). Economic Theories of the Nonprofit Sector: A Comparative Perspective. In Anheier, H. K. and Seibel, W., eds., The Third Sector: Comparative Studies of Nonprofit Organizations, Berlin: Walter de Gruyter, pp. 2130.Google Scholar
Johnson, J., and Orr, S. (2017). Institutions, Capabilities, Citizens, paper presented at Fact/Values/Strategies, Tisch College of Civic Studies, Tufts University.Google Scholar
Johnson, S. (2006). Everything Bad is Good for You: How Today’s Popular Culture is Actually Making Us Smarter, 1st reprint edition, New York: Riverhead Books.Google Scholar
Jones, G. (2015). Hive Mind: How Your Nation’s IQ Matters So Much More Than Your Own, 1st edition, Stanford, CA: Stanford Economics and Finance.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keefer, P., and Knack, S. (2008). Social Capital, Social Norms and the New Institutional Economics. In Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. M., eds., Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Dordreccht, The Netherlands: Springer, pp. 701725.Google Scholar
Kirzner, I. (1973). Competition and Entrepreneurship, University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Kirzner, I. (1992). The Meaning of the Market Process: Essays in the Development of Modern Austrian Economics, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Kirzner, I. M. (1960). The Economic Point of View: An Essay in the History of Economic Thought, Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.Google Scholar
Kirzner, I. M. (1997). Entrepreneurial Discovery and the Competitive Market Process: An Austrian ApproachJournal of Economic Literature35(1), 6085.Google Scholar
Klein, P., Mahoney, J., McGahan, A., and Pitelis, C. (2010). Toward a Theory of Public Entrepreneurship. European Management Review, 7(1), 115.Google Scholar
Kliemt, H. (2011). Tayloring Game Theory the Ostrom Way. The Good Society, 20(1), 3750.Google Scholar
Knight, F. H. (1921). Risk, Uncertainty and Profit, Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Knight, J., and Johnson, J. (2011). The Priority of Democracy: Political Consequences of Pragmatism, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kogelmann, B. (2017). Justice, Diversity, and the Well-Ordered SocietyThe Philosophical Quarterly67(269), 663684.Google Scholar
Kropotkin, P. (1987). Anarchism and Anarchist Communism: Its Basis and Principles, (edited by Walter, N.), London: Freedom Press.Google Scholar
Kropotkin, P. (2012). Mutual Aid: A Factor of Evolution, Courier Corporation.Google Scholar
Kuhnert, S. (2001). An Evolutionary Theory of Collective Action: Schumpeterian Entrepreneurship for the Common Good. Constitutional Political Economy, 12(1), 1329.Google Scholar
Kukathas, C. (2003). The Liberal Archipelago, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Kuran, T. (1997). Private Truths, Public Lies: The Social Consequences of Preference Falsification. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Kuran, T., and Sunstein, C. R. (1999). Availability Cascades and Risk Regulation. Stanford Law Review, 51(4), 683768.Google Scholar
Lachmann, L. M. (1966). Sir John Hicks on Capital and Growth. South African Journal of Economics, 34(2), 113123.Google Scholar
Lachmann, L. M. (1971). The Legacy of Max Weber: Three Essays, Berkeley: The Glaendessary Press.Google Scholar
Lachmann, L. M. (1986). The Market as an Economic Process, Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Landemore, H. (2012a). Democratic Reason: The Mechanisms of Collective Intelligence in Politics. In Landemore, H. and Elster, J., eds., Collective Wisdom: Principles and Mechanisms, Cambridge University Press, pp. 251289.Google Scholar
Landemore, H. (2012b). Why the Many are Smarter Than the Few and Why it Matters. Journal of Public Deliberation, 8(1).Google Scholar
Landemore, H. (2013). Democratic Reason: Politics, Collective Intelligence, and the Rule of the Many, reprint edition, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Lau, R. R., and Redlawsk, D. P. (2001). Advantages and Disadvantages of Cognitive Heuristics in Political Decision Making. American Journal of Political Science, 45(4), 951971.Google Scholar
Lessig, L. (1995). The Regulation of Social Meaning. University of Chicago Law Review, 62(3), 9431045.Google Scholar
Levine, P. (2011). Seeing Like a Citizen: The Contributions of Elinor Ostrom to “Civic Studies.” The Good Society, 20(1), 315.Google Scholar
Levine, P. (2014). The Case for Civic Studies. In Levine, P. and Soltan, K., eds., Civic Studies: Approaches to the Emerging Field, American Association of Colleges & Universities, pp. 38.Google Scholar
Levine, P., and Soltan, K., (Eds.). (2014). Civic Studies: Approaches to the Emerging Field, American Association of Colleges & Universities.Google Scholar
Levy, J. T. (2015). Rationalism, Pluralism, and Freedom, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Lewis, P. A. (2011). Varieties of Emergence: Minds, Markets and Novelty. Studies in Emergent Order. 4, 170–92.Google Scholar
Link, A. (2007). Public Policy and Entrepreneurship. In Audretsch, D., Grilo, I., and Thurik, A. R., eds., Handbook of Research on Entrepreneurship Policy, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, pp. 130139.Google Scholar
Macedo, S. (1990). Liberal Virtues: Citizenship, Virtue, and Community in Liberal Constitutionalism, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Marwell, G., and Oliver, P. (1993). The Critical Mass in Collective Action, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Marwell, G., Oliver, P., and Prahl, R. (1988). Social Networks and Collective Action: A Theory of the Critical Mass. The American Journal of Sociology, 94(3), 502534.Google Scholar
McGinnis, M. D. (1999). Polycentricity and Local Public Economies: Readings from the Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
McGinnis, M. D. (2005). Self-Governance, Polycentrism, and Federalism: Recurring Themes in Vincent Ostrom’s Scholarly Oeuvre. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 57(2): 173188.Google Scholar
McGinnis, M. D., and Walker, J. M. (2010). Foundations of the Ostrom Workshop: Institutional Analysis, Polycentricity, and Self-Governance of the Commons. Public Choice, 143(3): 293301.Google Scholar
Merton, R. K. (1948). The Self-Fulfilling Prophecy. Antioch Review, 8, 193210.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. (1859). On Liberty, Ontario: Batoche Books Limited.Google Scholar
Miller, D. (1984). Anarchism, London: JM Dent.Google Scholar
Mises, L. (1920). Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth. In Hayek, F. A., ed., Collective Economic Planning, London: George Routledge & Sons, pp. 87130.Google Scholar
Mises, L. (1922). Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis, New York: Mcmillan Co.Google Scholar
Mises, L. (1998). Human Action, Auburn, AL: The Ludwig von Mises Institute.Google Scholar
Morris, C. (2002). An Essay on the Modern State, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Morris, C. (2008). State Legitimacy and Social Order. In Kühnelt, J., ed., Political Legitimization Without Morality? Springer Netherlands, pp. 1532.Google Scholar
Munger, M. (2010). Endless Forms Most Beautiful and Most Wonderful: Elinor Ostrom and the Diversity of Institutions. Public Choice, 143(3): 263268.Google Scholar
Murphy, R. P. (2002). Chaos Theory, Auburn, AL: The Ludwig Von Mises Institute.Google Scholar
Nisbet, R. A. (1953). The Quest for Community: A Study in the Ethics of Order and Freedom, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1993). Institutions and Credible Commitment. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics (JITE)/Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft, 149(1), 1123.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1997). Some Fundamental Puzzles in Economic History/Development. In Santa Fe Institute Studies in the Sciences of Complexity-Proceedings, Vol. 27, Addison-Wesley Publishing, pp. 223238.Google Scholar
O’Driscoll, G. P., and Rizzo, M. J. (1985). The Economics of Time and Ignorance, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Oliver, P. (1993). Formal Models of Collective Action. Annual Review of Sociology, 19, 271300.Google Scholar
Oliver, P., and Marwell, G. (1988). The Paradox of Group Size in Collective Action: A Theory of the Critical Mass. II. American Sociological Review, 53(1), 18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oliver, P., and Marwell, G. (2001). Whatever Happened to Critical Mass Theory? A Retrospective and Assessment. Sociological Theory, 19(3), 292311.Google Scholar
Oliver, P., Marwell, G., and Teixeira, R. (1985). A Theory of the Critical Mass. I. Interdependence, Group Heterogeneity, and the Production of Collective Action. American Journal of Sociology, 91(3), 522556.Google Scholar
Olson, M. (1971). The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Ortmann, A. (1996). Modem Economic Theory and the Study of Nonprofit Organizations: Why the Twain Shall Meet. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 25(4), 470484.Google Scholar
Osterfeld, D. (1989). Anarchism and the Public Goods Issue: Law, Courts, and the Police. The Journal of Libertarian Studies, 9(1), 4768.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (1965). Public Entrepreneurship: A Case Study in Ground Water Basin Management, Los Angeles, University of California. Retrieved from https://dlc.dlib.indiana.edu/dlc/handle/10535/3581Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (1972). Metropolitan Reform: Propositions Derived from Two Traditions. Social Science Quarterly, 53(3), 474493.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (Ed). (1982). Strategies of Political Inquiry, Beverly Hills: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (1986). An Agenda for the Study of Institutions. Public Choice 48(1): 325.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the Commons. The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (1991). Rational Choice Theory and Institutional Analysis: Towards Complementarity. American Political Science Review, 85(1), 237250.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (1994). Neither Market Nor State: Governance of Common-Pool Resources in the Twenty-First Century, Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (1996). Crossing the Great Divide: Coproduction, Synergy, and Development. World Development, 24(6), 10731087.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (1998). A Behavioural Approach to the Rational Choice Theory of Collective Action. American Political Science Review, 92(1), 122.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (2000). Collective Action and the Evolution of Social Norms. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(3), 137158.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (2005a). Understanding Institutional Diversity, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (2005b). Unlocking Public Entrepreneurship and Public Economies. Discussion Paper No. 2005/1, EGDI-WIDER Conference on Unlocking Human Potential – Linking the Informal and Formal Sectors, Helsinki, 17–18 Sept. Retrieved from https://www.wider.unu.edu/sites/default/files/dp2005-01.pdfGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, E. (2008). Developing a Method for Analyzing Institutional Change. In Batie, S. S. and Mercuro, N., eds., Alternative Institutional Structures: Evolution and Impact, New York: Routledge, pp. 4876.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (2011). Background on the Institutional Analysis and Development Framework. Policy Studies Journal, 39(1), 727.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (2014). Collective Action and the Evolution of Social Norms. Journal of Natural Resources Policy Research, 6(4), 235252.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (2016). The Comparative Study of Public Economies. American Economist, 61(1), 91107.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E., and Ahn, T. K. (2007). The Meaning of Social Capital and its Link to Collective Action. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1304823 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1304823Google Scholar
Ostrom, E., and Davis, G. (1993). Nonprofit Organizations as Alternatives and Complements in a Mixed Economy. In Hammack, D. C. and Young, D. R., eds., Nonprofit Organization in a Market Economy: Understanding New Roles, Issues, and Trends, San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass Publishers, pp. 2356.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E., and Ostrom, V. (2004). The Quest for Meaning in Public Choice. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 63(1), 105147.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E., and Parks, R. B. (1973). Neither Gargantua nor the Land of Lilliputs: Conjectures on Mixed Systems of Metropolitan Organization. In McGinnis, M. D., ed., Polycentricity and Local Public Economies: Readings from the Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, pp. 284305.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E., and Walker, J. (Eds.). (2003). Trust and Reciprocity: Interdisciplinary Lessons from Experimental Research, New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Ostrom, V. (1972). Polycentricity. Workshop Working Paper Series, Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis, Presented at Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, DC, Sept. 5–9.Google Scholar
Ostrom, V. (1979). A Conceptual-Computational Logic for Federal Systems of Governance. In Daniel, D. J., ed., Constitutional Design and Power-Sharing in the Post-Modern Epoch, Lanham, MD: University Press of America, pp. 222.Google Scholar
Ostrom, V. (1982). The Human Condition. In Indiana University Archives, Vol. 82, pp. 329.Google Scholar
Ostrom, V. (1984). The Meaning of Value Terms. American Behavioral Scientist, 28(2), 249262.Google Scholar
Ostrom, V. (1986). The Constitutional Level of Analysis: A Challenge. Bloomington: Workshop Working Paper Series, Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis, Indiana University.Google Scholar
Ostrom, V. (1987). The Political Theory of a Compound Republic: Designing the American Experiment, Lincoln, NE: University of Nebraska Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, V. (1990). Problems of Cognition as a Challenge to Policy Analysts and Democratic Societies. Journal of Theoretical Politics 2(3): 243262.Google Scholar
Ostrom, V. (1993). Opportunity, Diversity, and Complexity. In Ostrom, V., Feeny, D., and Picht, H., eds., Rethinking Institutional Analysis and Development: Issues, Alternatives, and Choices, San Francisco: ICS Press, Institute for Contemporary Studies, pp. 389407.Google Scholar
Ostrom, V. (1994). The Meaning of American Federalism: Constituting a Self-Governing Society, San Francisco, Calif: ICS Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, V. (1997). The Meaning of Democracy and the Vulnerability of Democracies: A Response to Tocqueville’s Challenge, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, V. (2006). Citizen-Sovereigns: The Source of Contestability, the Rule of Law, and the Conduct of Public Entrepreneurship. PS: Political Science & Politics, 39(1), 1317.Google Scholar
Ostrom, V. (2008 [1973]). The Intellectual Crisis in American Public Administration, 3rd edition [1st ed. 1973; rev. ed. 1974; 2nd ed. 1989], Tuscaloosa, AL: University of Alabama Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, V., and Allen, B. (2008). The Political Theory of a Compound Republic: Designing the American Experiment, 3rd revised edition, Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.Google Scholar
Ostrom, V., and Ostrom, E. (1965). A Behavioral Approach to the Study of Intergovernmental Relations. Readings from the Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis, 359(1), 135146.Google Scholar
Ostrom, V., and Ostrom, E. (1977). Public Goods and Public Choices. In McGinnis, M., translator, Readings from the Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis, Boulder, CO: Westview Press, pp. 75105.Google Scholar
Ostrom, V., Bish, R., and Ostrom, E. (1988). Local Government in the United States, San Francisco: ICS Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, V., Tiebout, C. M., and Warren, R. (1961). The Organization of Government in Metropolitan Areas: A Theoretical Inquiry. American Political Science Review, 55, 831842.Google Scholar
Ott, J. S. (Ed.). (2001). The Nature of the Nonprofit Sector, Boulder, CO: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Page, S. E. (2008) The Difference: How the Power of Diversity Creates Better Groups, Firms, Schools, and Societies, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Parks, R. B., Baker, P. C., Kiser, L., … Wilson, R. (1981). Consumers as Coproducers of Public Services: Some Economic and Institutional Considerations. Policy Studies Journal, 9(7), 10011011.Google Scholar
Pateman, C. (1970). Participation and Democratic Theory, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Pennington, M. (2011). Robust Political Economy: Classical Liberalism and the Future of Public Policy, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Platteau, J.-P. (1996). Traditional Sharing Norms as an Obstacle to Economic Growth in Tribal Societies. (Working Paper), Notre-Dame de la Paix, Sciences Economiques et Sociales. Retrieved from https://econpapers.repec.org/paper/fthnodapa/173.htmGoogle Scholar
Platteau, J.-P. (2000). Institutions, Social Norms and Economic Development, 1st edition, Amsterdam, The Netherlands: Routledge.Google Scholar
Platteau, J.-P. (2006). Solidarity Norms and Institutions in Village Societies: Static and Dynamic Considerations. In Kolm, S.-C. and Ythier, J. M., eds., Handbook of the Economics of Giving, Altruism and Reciprocity, Vol. 1, Oxford: Elsevier, pp. 819886.Google Scholar
Pocock, J. G. A. (2016). The Machiavellian Moment: Florentine Political Thought and the Atlantic Republican Tradition, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Pohl, R., (Ed.). (2004). Cognitive Illusions: A Handbook on Fallacies and Biases in Thinking, Judgement, and Memory, New York: Psychology Press.Google Scholar
Polanyi, M. (1951). The Logic of Liberty, University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Posner, E. A. (Ed.). (2007). Social Norms, Nonlegal Sanctions, and the Law, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Posner, R. A. (1998). Rational Choice, Behavioral Economics, and the Law. Stanford Law Review, 1551–1575.Google Scholar
Powell, W., and Steinberg, R. (2006). The Nonprofit Sector: A Research Handbook, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Pressman, J. L., and Wildavsky, A. B. (1973). Implementation: How Great Expectations in Washington Are Dashed in Oakland; Or, Why It’s Amazing that Federal Programs Work at All, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Pryor, F. L. (2005). Economic Systems of Foraging, Agricultural, and Industrial Societies, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Putnam, R. D., Leonardi, R., and Nanetti, R. Y. (1994). Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Radnitzky, G. (Ed.). (1992). Universal Economics: Assessing the Achievements of the Economic Approach, New York: Paragon House.Google Scholar
Radnitzky, G., and Bernholz, P. (1987). Economic Imperialism: The Economic Approach Applied Outside the Field of Economics, New York: Paragon House.Google Scholar
Raiser, M. (1997). Informal Institutions, Social Capital and Economic Transition: Reflections on a Neglected Dimension. European Bank for Reconstruction and Development. http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.194.8230&rep=rep1&type=pdfGoogle Scholar
Raiser, M. (2001). Informal Institutions, Social Capital, and Economic Transition: Reflections on a Neglected Dimension. In Cornia, G. A. and Popov, V., eds., Transition and Institutions: The Experience of Gradual and Late Reformers, Oxford University Press, pp. 218239.Google Scholar
Reksulak, M., Razzolini, L., and Shughart, W. F. (Eds.). (2013). The Elgar Companion to Public Choice, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, S. (Ed.). (1986). The Economics of Nonprofit Institutions: Studies in Structure and Policy, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1997). Altruism, Ideological Entrepreneurs and the Non-Profit Firm. VOLUNTAS: International Journal of Voluntary and Nonprofit Organizations, 8(2), 120134.Google Scholar
Rossi, P. H., Lipsey, M. W., & Freeman, H. E. (2004). Evaluation: A Systematic Approach. Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE Publication.Google Scholar
Rothbard, M. N. (1973). For a New Liberty: The Libertarian Manifesto, New York: Collier Books.Google Scholar
Rothbard, M. N., and Salerno, J. T. (2011). Man, Economy, and State with Power and Market, Scholar’s Edition, 2nd edition, Auburn, Alabama: Ludwig von Mises Institute.Google Scholar
Sabetti, F. (2011). Constitutional Artisanship and Institutional Diversity: Elinor Ostrom, Vincent Ostrom, and the Workshop. The Good Society, 20(1), 7383.Google Scholar
Sabetti, F. (2014). Artisans of the Common Life: Building a Public Science of Civics. In Levine, P. and Soltan, K., eds., Civic Studies: Approaches to the Emerging Field, Vol. 3, Washington, DC: Bringing Theory to Practice, pp. 2332.Google Scholar
Sabetti, F., Allen, B., and Sproule-Jones, M. (Eds.). (2009). The Practice of Constitutional Development: Vincent Ostrom’s Quest to Understand Human Affairs, New York: Lexington Books.Google Scholar
Salamon, L. M. (1987). Of Market Failure, Voluntary Failure, and Third-Party Government: Toward a Theory of Government–Nonprofit Relations in the Modern Welfare State. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 16(1–2), 2949.Google Scholar
Salamon, L. M. (1995). Partners in Public Service: Government–Nonprofit Relations in the Modern Welfare State, Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Salamon, L. M., and Anheier, H. K. (1998). Social Origins of Civil Society: Explaining the Nonprofit Sector Cross-Nationally. VOLUNTAS: International Journal of Voluntary and Nonprofit Organizations, 9(3), 213248.Google Scholar
Salamon, L. M., Sokołowski, C. W., and Anheier, H. K. (2000). Social Origins of Civil Society: An Overview, Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins Center for Civil Society Studies.Google Scholar
Schmidtz, D. (1995). Rational Choice and Moral Agency, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Schmidtz, D. (2006). The Elements of Justice, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Schmidtz, D., and Brennan, J. (2011). A Brief History of Liberty, Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. (1954). History of Economic Analysis, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. A. (1976). Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy, London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Scott, J. C. (1998). Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition Have Failed, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Selgin, G. (1988). Praxeology and Understanding: An Analysis of the Controversy in Austrian Economics. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.Google Scholar
Sen, A. (1970). The Impossibility of a Paretian Liberal. Journal of Political Economy, 78(1), 152157.Google Scholar
Shackle, G. L. S. (1973). Epistemics and Economics: A Critique of Economic Doctrines, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Shapiro, R. Y., and Bloch‐Elkon, Y. (2008). Do the Facts Speak for Themselves? Partisan Disagreement as a Challenge to Democratic Competence. Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society, 20(1–2), 115139.Google Scholar
Shockley, G. E. (Ed.). (2009). Non-Market Entrepreneurship, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Skinner, Q. (1998). Liberty Before Liberalism, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, S. R., and Grønbjerg, K. A. (2006). Scope and Theory of Government–Nonprofit Relations. In Powell, W. W. and Steinberg, R., eds., The Nonprofit Sector: A Research Handbook, 2nd edition, pp. 221–242.Google Scholar
Smith, V. L. (2003). Constructivist and Ecological Rationality in Economics. The American Economic Review, 93(3), 465508.Google Scholar
Smith, V. L. (2008). Rationality in Economics: Constructivist and Ecological Forms, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Soltan, K. (2011). A Civic Science. The Good Society, 20(1), 102119.Google Scholar
Sproule-Jones, M., Allen, B., and Sabetti, F. (Eds.). (2008). The Struggle to Constitute and Sustain Productive Orders, Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.Google Scholar
Steinberg, R. (2003). Economic Theories of Nonprofit Organizations. In Anheier, H. K. and Ben-Ner, A., eds., The Study of Nonprofit Enterprise, New York: Springer US, pp. 277309.Google Scholar
Steinberg, R., and Gray, B. H. (1993). The Role of Nonprofit Enterprise. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 22(4), 297316.Google Scholar
Steinberg, R., and Powell, W. W. (Eds.). (2006). The Nonprofit Sector: A Research Handbook, 2nd edition, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. J., and Becker, G. S. (1977). De Gustibus Non Est Disputandum. American Economic Review 67(2), 7690.Google Scholar
Storr, V. (2008). North’s Underdeveloped Ideological Entrepreneur, in Chamlee-Wright, E., ed., Annual Proceedings of the Wealth and Well-Being of Nations, Vol. 1, Beloit, WI: Beloit College Press, pp. 20082009.Google Scholar
Storr, V. H., Haeffele-Balch, S., and Grube, L. E. (2015). Community Revival in the Wake of Disaster: Lessons in Local Entrepreneurship, New York: Palgrave Macmillian.Google Scholar
Swedberg, R. (1990). Economics and Sociology: Redefining Their Boundaries: Conversations with Economists and Sociologists, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H., and Sunstein, C. R. (2003). Libertarian Paternalism. The American Economic Review, 93(2), 175179.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H., and Sunstein, C. R. (2008). Nudge: Improving Decisions About Health, Wealth, and Happiness, revised and expanded edition, New York: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Thompson, C. (2013). Smarter Than You Think: How Technology is Changing Our Minds for the Better, New York: Penguin.Google Scholar
Todd, P. M., and Gigerenzer, G. (2003). Bounding Rationality to the World. Journal of Economic Psychology, 24(2), 143165.Google Scholar
Tomasi, J. (2012). Free Market Fairness. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Toonen, T. (2010). Resilience in Public Administration: The Work of Elinor and Vincent Ostrom from a Public Administration Perspective. Public Administration Review, 70(2), 193202.Google Scholar
Tully, J. (2013). Two Ways of Realizing Justice and Democracy: Linking Amartya Sen and Elinor Ostrom. Critical Review of International Social and Political Philosophy, 16(2), 220232.Google Scholar
Valentinov, V., and Iliopoulos, C. (2013). Economic Theories of Nonprofits and Agricultural Cooperatives Compared: New Perspectives for Nonprofit Scholars. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 42(1), 109126.Google Scholar
van de Haar, E. (2009). Classical Liberalism and International Relations Theory: Hume, Smith, Mises, and Hayek, New York: Springer.Google Scholar
van de Haar, E. (2015). Degrees of Freedom: Liberal Political Philosophy and Ideology, New York: Transaction Publishers.Google Scholar
Vanberg, V. J. (2002). The Constitution of Markets: Essays in Political Economy, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Vanberg, V. J. (2005). Market and State: The Perspective of Constitutional Political Economy. Journal of Institutional Economics, 1(01), 2349.Google Scholar
Wagner, R. E. (1966). Pressure Groups and Political Entrepreneurs: A Review Article. Papers on Non- Market Decision Making, 1(12), 161170.Google Scholar
Wagner, R. E., (Ed.). (2016). Politics as a Peculiar Business: Insights from a Theory of Entangled Political Economy, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Walker, J. (2012, June 12). Elinor Ostrom, Scholar Who Argued for Decentralization, RIP. Hit & Run Blog at Reason.com, retrieved from http://reason.com/blog/2012/06/12/elinor-ostrom-scholar-who-maGoogle Scholar
Walzer, M. (1983). Spheres of Justice: A Defense of Pluralism and Equality, New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Weisbrod, B. A. (1975). Toward a Theory of the Voluntary Nonprofit Sector in a Three-Sector Economy. In Phelps, E. S., ed., Altruism, Morality, and Economic Theory, New York: Russell Sage Foundation, pp. 171196.Google Scholar
Weisbrod, B. A. (1977). The Voluntary Nonprofit Sector, Lexington, MA: D.C. Heath & Co.Google Scholar
Weisbrod, B. A. (1991). The Nonprofit Economy, Cambridge, MA.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Young, D. R. (2000). Alternative Models of Government–Nonprofit Sector Relations: Theoretical and International Perspectives. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 29(1), 149172.Google Scholar
Young, D. R. (2013). If Not for Profit, for What? A Behavioral Theory of the Nonprofit Sector Based on Entrepreneurship (1983 print edition), Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Bibliography
  • Paul Dragos Aligica, George Mason University, Virginia
  • Book: Public Entrepreneurship, Citizenship, and Self-Governance
  • Online publication: 26 July 2018
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316888728.011
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Bibliography
  • Paul Dragos Aligica, George Mason University, Virginia
  • Book: Public Entrepreneurship, Citizenship, and Self-Governance
  • Online publication: 26 July 2018
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316888728.011
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Bibliography
  • Paul Dragos Aligica, George Mason University, Virginia
  • Book: Public Entrepreneurship, Citizenship, and Self-Governance
  • Online publication: 26 July 2018
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316888728.011
Available formats
×