Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-skm99 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-26T14:42:27.029Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 October 2021

Ruben Mercado
Affiliation:
Latin American Faculty of Social Sciences
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Artificial Economics
Methods, Models, and Interdisciplinary Links
, pp. 165 - 173
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2021

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Albin, Peter (1992). Approximations of Cooperative Equilibria in Multi-Person Prisoner’s Dilemma Played by Cellular Automata. Mathematical Social Sciences, 24(2–3): pp. 293319.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Albin, Peter (1998). Barriers and Bounds to Rationality: Essays on Economic Complexity and Dynamics in Interactive Systems. Princeton University Press, New Jersey.Google Scholar
Alchian, Armen (1950). Uncertainty, Evolution and Economic Theory. Journal of Political Economy, 58(3): 211221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alpaydin, Ethem (2014). Introduction to Machine Learning. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Anderson, Phillip (1972). More Is Different. Science, 177(4047): 393396.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth and Hahn, Frank (1983). General Competitive Analysis. North-Holland, Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Arthur, W. Brian (2014). Complexity and the Economy. Oxford University Press, New York.Google Scholar
Axelrod, Robert (1997). The Complexity of Cooperation. Princeton University Press, New Jersey.Google Scholar
Axtell, Robert (2000). Why Agents? For the Varied Motivations for Agent Computing in the Social Sciences. Working Paper 17, Center on Social and Economic Dynamics, The Brookings Institution, Washington DC.Google Scholar
Bailey, Kenneth (2006). Systems Theory. In Turner, Jonathan (ed.), Handbook of Sociological Theory, pp. 379401. Springer.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary (1962). Irrational Behavior and Economic Theory. Journal of political Economy, 70(1): 113.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary (1993). The Economic Way of Looking at Life. Working Paper 12, Coase-Sandor Institute for Law & Economics, Chicago.Google Scholar
Bermúdez, José (2014). Cognitive Science: An Introduction to the Science of Mind. Cambridge University Press, New York.Google Scholar
Blaug, Mark (1992). The Methodology of Economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boccara (2004). Modeling Complex Systems. Springer Verlag, New York.Google Scholar
Boero, Ricardo, Morini, Mateo, Sonessa, Michele and Terna, Pietro (2015). Agent-Based Models of the Economy: From Theory to Applications. Palgrave MacMillan, Basingstoke, UK.Google Scholar
Borrill, Joseph and Tesfatsion, Leigh (2010). Agent-Based Modeling: The Right Mathematics for the Social Sciences? Working Paper 10023, Department of Economics, Iowa State University, Iowa, USA.Google Scholar
Bourdieu, Pierre (1977). Outline of a Theory of Practice. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Boyd, Robert and Richerson, Peter (1985). Culture and the Evolutionary Process. University of Chicago Press, Chicago.Google Scholar
Bowles, Samuel (2003). Microeconomics: Behavior, Institutions and Evolution. Part III. Princeton University Press, New Jersey.Google Scholar
Brandstätter, Christian, Dietrich, Dietmar, Doblhammer, Klaus et al. (2015). Natural Scientific, Psychoanalytical Model of the Psyche for Simulation and Emulation. Scientific Report III, Institute of Computer Technology, Vienna University of Technology, Vienna.Google Scholar
Brenner, Thomas (2006). Agent Learning Representation: Advice on Modelling Economic Learning. In Leigh, Tesfatsion and Judd, Kenneth (eds.), Handbook of Computational Economics, Vol. 2: Agent-Based Computational Economics, pp. 894947. North-Holland, Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Bridges, Douglas and Palmgren, Erik (2018). Constructive Mathematics. In Zalta, Edward N. (ed.), The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Summer 2018 ed.), https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/sum2018/entries/mathematics-constructive.Google Scholar
Bridges, Douglas and Reeves, Steve (1997). Constructive Mathematics in Theory and Programming Practice, CDMTCS-068, Centre For Discrete Mathematics and Theoretical Computer Science, University of Waikato, Auckland, NZ.Google Scholar
Brock, William and Colander, David (2000). Complexity and Policy. In Colander, David (ed.), The Complexity Vision and the Teaching of Economics, pp. 7396. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK.Google Scholar
Bucci, Wilma (1997). Psychoanalysis & Cognitive Science: A Multiple Code Theory. Guilford Press, New York.Google Scholar
Calvo, Paco and Gomila, Toni (eds.) (2008). Handbook of Cognitive Science: An Embodied Approach. Elsevier Science & Technology, Oxford.Google Scholar
Camerer, Colin (2008). The Case for Mindful Economics. In Caplin, Andrew and Schotter, Andrew (eds.), Foundations of Positive and Normative Economics: A Handbook, pp. 4369. Oxford University Press, New York.Google Scholar
Carley, Kathleen (2006). Computational Approaches to Sociological Theorizing. In Turner, Jonathan (ed.), Handbook of Sociological Theory, pp. 6983. Springer.Google Scholar
Cavalli-Sforza, Luigi Luca and Feldman, Marcus (1981). Cultural Transmission and Evolution: A Quantitative Approach. Princeton University Press, New Jersey.Google Scholar
Chen, Shu-Heng (2012). Varieties of Agents in Agent-Based Computational Economics: A Historical and Interdisciplinary Perspective. Journal of Economics Dynamics and Control, 36(1): 125.Google Scholar
Chen, Shu-Heng (2016). Agent-Based Computational Economics: How the Idea Originated and Where It Is Going. Routledge, London.Google Scholar
Chenery, Hollis (1975). The Structuralist Approach to Development Policy. American Economic Review, 65(2): 310316.Google Scholar
Chomsky, Noam (1959). A Review of B. F. Skinner’s Verbal Behavior. Language, 35(1): 2658.Google Scholar
Colander, David and Kupers, Roland (2014). Complexity and the Art of Public Policy: Solving Society’s Problems from the Bottom Up. Princeton University Press, New Jersey.Google Scholar
Cole, David (2020). The Chinese Room Argument. In Zalta, Edward N. (ed.), The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Spring 2020 ed.), https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/spr2020/entries/chinese-room/.Google Scholar
Crutchfield, James (1994). The Calculi of Emergence: Computation, Dynamics and Induction. Physica D, 75: 1154.Google Scholar
Damaceanu, Romulus-Catalin (2013). Agent-Based Computational Economics Using NetLogo. Bentham Science Publishers, Sharjah, UAE.Google Scholar
Damasio, Antonio (2005). Descartes’s Error. Penguin Books, New York.Google Scholar
Damasio, Antonio (2009). Neuroscience and the Emergence of Neuroeconomics. In Glimcher, Paul (ed.), Neuroeconomics: Decisionmaking and The Brain, pp. 209214. Elsevier Science Publishing, San Diego.Google Scholar
Dawid, Herbert and Pyka, Andreas (2018). Special Issue on Evolutionary Dynamics and Agent-Based Modeling. Computational Economics, 52(3).Google Scholar
Dawkins, Richard (2006). The Selfish Gene. 30th anniversary ed. Oxford University Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
Debreu, Gerard (1972). Theory of Value: An Axiomatic Analysis of Economic Equilibrium. Yale University Press, New Haven.Google Scholar
Delli Gatti, Domenico, Fagiolo, Georgio, Gallegati, Mauro, Riciardi, Matteo and Russo, Alberto (eds.) (2018). Agent-Based Models in Economics: A Toolkit. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Dennett, Daniel (1996). Darwin’s Dangerous Idea: Evolution and the Meanings of Life. Penguin Books, London.Google Scholar
Dietrich, Dietmar, Fodor, Georg, Zucker, Gerhard and Bruckner, Dietmar (eds.) (2009). Simulating the Mind: A Technical Neuropsychoanalytical Approach. Springer-Verlag, Vienna.Google Scholar
Dietrich, Franz and List, Christian (2016). Mentalism versus Behaviorism in Economics: A Philosophy of Science Perspective. Economics & Philosophy, (32)2: 249281.Google Scholar
Dreyfus, Hubert (1972). What Computers Can’t Do: A Critique of Artificial Reason. Harper & Row, New York.Google Scholar
Dreyfus, Hubert (1992). What Computer’s Still Can’t Do. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Durlauf, Steven (2012). Complexity, Economics and Public Policy. Politics, Philosophy & Economics, 11(1): 4575.Google Scholar
Ehrentreich, Norman (2008). Agent-Based Modeling: The Santa Fe Institute Artificial Stock Market Revisited, Part II. Springer-Verlag, Berlin.Google Scholar
Elsenbroich, Corinna and Gilbert, Nigel (2013). Modelling Norms. Springer, Dordrecht.Google Scholar
Epstein, Joshua (2006). Generative Social Science: Studies in Agent-Based Computational Modeling. Princeton University Press, New Jersey.Google Scholar
Epstein, Joshua (2013). Agent_Zero: Toward Neurocognitive Foundations for Generative Social Science. Princeton University Press, New Jersey.Google Scholar
Epstein, Joshua and Axtell, Robert (1996). Growing Artificial Societies: Social Science from the Bottom Up. The MIT Press, Cambridge MA.Google Scholar
Fine, Ben and Milonakys, Dimitri (2009). From Economics Imperialism to Freakonomics. Routledge, London.Google Scholar
Flache, Andreas and Hegselmann, Rainer (1998). Understanding Complex Social Dynamics: A Plea for Cellular Automata Based Modelling. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 1(3).Google Scholar
Frankish, Keith and Ramsey, William (eds.) (2012). The Cambridge Handbook of Cognitive Science. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Franks, David (2019). Neurosociology: Fundamentals and Current Findings. Springer, Dordrecht.Google Scholar
Franks, David and Turner, Jonathan (2013). Handbook of Neurosociology. Springer, Dordrecht.Google Scholar
Friedenberg, Jay and Silverman, Gordon (2011). Cognitive Science: and introduction to the study of mind. SAGE Publications, Inc.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton (1966). The Methodology of Positive Economics. In Friedman, Milton (ed.), Essays in Positive Economics, pp. 316 and pp. 3043. University of Chicago Press, Chicago.Google Scholar
Fudenberg, Drew and Tirole, Jean (1991). Game Theory. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Gelbard, Friedrich (2017). Psychoanalytic Defense Mechanisms in Cognitive Multi-Agent Systems. Routledge, London.Google Scholar
Gershenson, Carlos and Fernández, Nelson (2012). Complexity and Information: Measuring Emergence, Self-Organization and Homeostasis at Multiple Scales. Complexity, 18(2): 2944.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giddens, Anthony (1986). The Constitution of Society: Outline of the Theory of Structuration. Polity Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
Gilbert, Nigel (2019). Agent-Based Models. SAGE Publications, Thousand Oaks, CA.Google Scholar
Gintis, Herbert (2009). Game Theory Evolving. Princeton University Press, New Jersey.Google Scholar
Glimcher, Paul (2003). Decisions, Uncertainty and the Brain: The Science of Neuroeconomics. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Glimcher, Paul and Fehr, Ernst (2014). Neuroeconomics: Decision Making and the Brain. 2nd ed. Elsevier Science Publishing, San Diego.Google Scholar
Gode, Dhananjay and Sunder, Shyam (1993). Allocative Efficiency of Markets with Zero-Intelligence Traders: Market as a Partial Substitute for Individual Rationality. Journal of Political Economy, 101(1): 119137.Google Scholar
Goodfellow, Ian, Bengio, Yoshua and Courville, Aaron (2016). Deep Learning. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Gul, Faruk and Pesendorfer, Wolfang (2008). The Case for Mindless Economics. In Caplin, Andrew and Schotter, Andrew (eds.), Foundations of Positive and Normative Economics: A Handbook, pp. 339. Oxford University Press, New York.Google Scholar
Hadeler, Karl-Peter and Müller, Johannes (2017). Cellular Automata: Analysis and Applications. Springer International Publishing, Cham, Switzerland.Google Scholar
Hamill, Lynne and Gilbert, Nigel (2016). Agent-Based Modelling in Economics. Wiley, West Sussex, UK.Google Scholar
Hansen, Lars and Sargent, Thomas (2007). Robustness. Princeton University Press, New Jersey.Google Scholar
Harari, Yuval (2017). Homo Deus: A Brief History of Tomorrow. Vintage, London.Google Scholar
Hausman, Daniel (1992). The Inexact and Separate Science of Economics. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich (1937). Economics and Knowledge. Economica, 4(13): 3354.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich (1945). The Use of Knowledge in Society. The American Economic Review, 35(4): 519530.Google Scholar
Haykin, Simon (2009). Neural Networks and Learning Machines. Pearson, New Jersey.Google Scholar
Heidegger, Martin (2008). Being and Time. HarperCollins, New York.Google Scholar
Hicks, John and Allen, R. G. D. (1934). A Reconsideration of the Theory of Value. Economica, Part I 1(1): 5276 and Part II 1(1): 196219.Google Scholar
Him, Xuewei, Wu, Jinpei and Li, Xueyan (2018). Theory of Practical Cellular Automaton. Beijing Jiaotong University Press and Springer Nature, Singapore.Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey (2004). Thorstein Veblen and Darwinism. International Review of Sociology, 14(3): 343361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hollander, Christopher and Annie, Wu (2011). The Current State of Normative Agent-Based Systems. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 14(2): 6.Google Scholar
Holt, , Richard, J., Rosser, Barkley Jr. and Colander, David (2010). The Complexity Era in Economics. Middlebury College Economics Discussion Paper, 10–01, Middlebury, VT.Google Scholar
Hommes, Cars and LeBaron, Blake (eds.) (2018). Handbook of Computational Economics Vol. 4: Heterogeneous Agent Modeling. North-Holland, Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Horgan, John (1995). From Complexity to Perplexity. Scientific American, 272(6): 104120.Google Scholar
Horgan, John (2015). The End of Science: Facing the Limits of Knowledge in the Twilight of the Scientific Age, pp. 195232. Basic Books, New York.Google Scholar
Huys, Quentin, Maia, Tiago and Frank, Michael (2016). Computational Psychiatry as a Bridge from Neuroscience to Clinical Applications. Nature Neuroscience, 19(3): 404413.Google Scholar
Izquierdo, Luis, Izquierdo, Segismundo, Galan, Joseph and Santos, José (2013). Combining Mathematical and Simulation Approaches to Understand the Dynamics of Computer Models. In Edmonds, Bruce and Meyer, Ruth (eds.), Simulating Social Complexity, pp. 293330. Springer-Verlag, Berlin.Google Scholar
Kandel, Eric (2005). Psychiatry, Psychoanalysis and the New Biology of Mind. American Psychiatry Association Publishing, Virginia, USA.Google Scholar
Keenan, Donald and O’Brien, Mike (1993). Competition, Collusion and Chaos. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 17(3): 327353.Google Scholar
Kendrick, David A. (1981). Stochastic Control for Economic Models. McGraw-Hill, New York.Google Scholar
Kendrick, David A. (2005). Stochastic Control for Economic Models: Past, Present and Paths Ahead. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 29(1–2): 330.Google Scholar
Kendrick, David A., Amman, Hans and Tucci, Marco (2014). Learning About Learning. In Schmedderss, Karl and Judd, Kenneth (eds.), Handbook of Computational Economics, Vol. III, pp. 135. North-Holland, Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Kendrick, David A., Mercado, Ruben and Amman, Hans (2006). Computational Economics. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.Google Scholar
Kirk, Robert (2019). Zombies. In Zalta, Edward N. (ed.), The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Spring 2019 ed.), https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/spr2019/entries/zombies/.Google Scholar
Lange, Oskar (1965). Whole and Parts: A General Theory of Systems Behavior. Pergamon Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
Laver, Michael (2020). Agent-Based Models of Social Life: Fundamentals. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
LeBaron, Blake (2002). Building the Santa Fe Artificial Stock Market. Working Paper, Brandeis University, Waltham MA, June.Google Scholar
Lefevre, Henry (2009). Dialectical Materialism, Part II. University of Minnesota Press, Minneapolis.Google Scholar
Leontief, Wassily (1941). The Structure of American Economy 1919–1929. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Li, Xuewei, Jinpei, Wu and Xueyan, Li (2018). Theory of Practical Cellular Automaton. Springer Verlag, Singapore.Google Scholar
Lowe, Edward Jonathan (2000). An Introduction to the Philosophy of Mind. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Martin-Löf, Per (1984). Constructive Mathematics and Computer Programming. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society of London, A312: 501518.Google Scholar
Massey, Douglass (2002). A Brief History of Human Society: The Origin and Role of Emotion in Social Life. American Sociological Review, 67(1): 129.Google Scholar
Maynard Smith, John (1982). Evolution and the Theory of Games. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Mercado, Ruben and Kendrick, David A. (2006). Parameter Uncertainty and Policy Intensity: Some Extensions and Suggestions for Further Work. Computational Economics, 27: 483496.Google Scholar
Miller, John and Page, Scott (2007). Complex Adaptive Systems: An Introduction to Computational Models of Social Life. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Melanie (1996). An Introduction to Genetic Algorithms. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Melanie (2009). Complexity: A Guided Tour. Oxford University Press, New York.Google Scholar
Newmann, Martin (2008). Homo Socionicus: A Case Study of Simulation Models of Norms. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 11(4).Google Scholar
Norman, Greg, Hawkley, Louise, Luhmann, Maike, Cacioppo, John and Berntson, Gary (2013). Social Neuroscience and the Modern Synthesis of Social and Biological Levels of Analysis. In Franks, Davis and Turner, Jonathan (eds.), Handbook of Neurosociology, pp. 6781. Springer, Dordrecht.Google Scholar
Nowak, Martin and May, Robert (1992). Evolutionary Games and Spatial Chaos. Nature, 359: 826829.Google Scholar
Nowak, Martin and May, Robert (1993). The Spatial Dilemmas of Evolution. International Journal of Bifurcation and Chaos, 3(1): 3578.Google Scholar
O’Sullivan, David and Haklay, Mordechai (2000). Agent-Based Models and Individualism: Is the World Agent-Based? Environment and Planning A, 32(8): 14091425.Google Scholar
Packard, Norman (1989). Intrinsic Adaptation in a Simple Model for Evolution. In Langton, Christopher (ed.), Artificial Life, pp. 141155. Addison-Wesley, Redwood City, CA.Google Scholar
Pigliucci, Massimo (2004). Between Holism and Reductionism: A Philosophical Primer on Emergence. Biological Journal of the Linnean Society, 112(2): 261267.Google Scholar
Pinker, Steven (2002). The Blank Slate: The Modern Denial of Human Nature. Penguin Books, London.Google Scholar
Poole, David and Mackworth, Alan (2017). Artificial Intelligence: Foundations of Computational Agents. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Prawitz, Dag (1990). Tacit Knowledge: An Impediment for AI? In Goranson, Bo and Florin, Magnus (eds.), Artificial Intelligence, Culture and Language: On Education and Work, pp. 5760. Springer-Verlag, London.Google Scholar
Railsback, Steven and Grimm, Volker (2019). Agent-Based and Individual-Based Modeling: A Practical Introduction. 2nd ed. Princeton University Press, New Jersey.Google Scholar
Rangel, Antonio, Camerer, Colin and Read Montague, P. (2008). A Framework for Studying the Neurobiology of Value-Based Decision Making. Nature Reviews Neuroscience, 9(7): 4556.Google Scholar
Ranish, Robert and Sorgner, Stefan (2014). Post and Transhumanism: An Introduction. Peter Lang, Bern.Google Scholar
Rodado, Juan and Rendon, Mario (1996). Can Psychoanalysis be of Help to Artificial Intelligence … or … Vice Versa? The American Journal of Psychoanalysis, 56: 395413.Google Scholar
Rosser, J. Barkley Jr. (1999). On the Complexities of Complex Economic Dynamics. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 13(4): 169192.Google Scholar
Rosser, J. Barkley Jr. (2015). Complexity and the Austrians. In Coyne, Christopher and Boettke, Peter (eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Austrian Economics, pp. 594611. Oxford University Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
Roughgarden, Tim (2010). Computing Equilibria: A Computational Complexity Perspective. Economic Theory, 42: 193236.Google Scholar
Russell, Stuart and Norvig, Peter (2018). Artificial Intelligence: A Modern Approach. Pearson, Harlow UK.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul (1938). A Note on the Pure Theory of Consumers’ Behaviour. Economica, 5(17): 6171.Google Scholar
Sanderson, Stephen (2006). Evolutionary Theorizing. In Turner, Jonathan (ed.), Handbook of Sociological Theory, pp. 435455. Springer, New York.Google Scholar
Sandler, Joseph, Holder, Alex, Dare, Christopher and Dreher, Anna (1997). Freud’s Models of the Mind: An Introduction. Routledge, London.Google Scholar
Saygin, Ayse, Cicekli, Ilyas and Akman, Varol (2000). Turing Test: 50 Years Later. Minds and Machines, 10: 463518.Google Scholar
Schatzki, Theodore (1996). Social Practices: A Wittgensteinian Approach to Human Activity and the Social. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Schatzki, Theodore (2002). The Site of the Social: A Philosophical Account of the Constitution of Social Life and Change. Penn State University Press, University Park, PA.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph (1983). The Theory of Economic Development. Taylor & Francis, Somerset, UK.Google Scholar
Sengupta, Jati and Fanchon, Phillipe (1997). Control Theory Methods in Economics. Springer-Verlag, New York.Google Scholar
Skinner, Burrhus F. (1957). Verbal Behavior. Appleton-Century-Crofts, New York.Google Scholar
Solms, Mark and Turnbull, Oliver (2011). What Is Neuropsychoanalysis? Neuropsychoanalysis, 13(2): 133145.Google Scholar
Squazzoni, Flaminio (2012). Agent-Based Computational Sociology. John Wiley & Sons, West Sussex, UK.Google Scholar
Sraffa, Piero (1960). Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities: Prelude to a Critique of Economic Theory. Cambridge University Press, London.Google Scholar
Standish, Russell (2008). Concept and Definition of Complexity. In Yang, Ang and Shan, Yin (eds.), Intelligent Complex Adaptive Systems, pp. 105124. IGI Publishing, Hershey, PA.Google Scholar
Stets, Jan and Turner, Jonathan (eds.) (2006). Handbook of the Sociology of Emotions. Springer-Verlag, New York.Google Scholar
Stigler, George (1984). Economics: The Imperial Science? Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 86(3): 301313.Google Scholar
Sun, Ron (ed.) (2008). The Cambridge Handbook of Computational Psychology. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Sutton, Richard and Barto, Andrew (2018). Reinforcement Learning: An Introduction. 2nd ed. The MIT Press, Cambridge MA.Google Scholar
Taylor, Charles (1995). Philosophical Arguments, pp. 6178. Harvard University Press, Cambridge MA.Google Scholar
Tesfatsion, Leigh and Judd, Kenneth (eds.) (2006). Handbook of Computational Economics. Vol. 2: Agent-Based Computational Economics, North-Holland, Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Thagard, Paul (2005). Mind: Introduction to Cognitive Science. The MIT Press, Cambridge MA.Google Scholar
Thagard, Paul (2012). Cognitive Architectures. In Frankish, Keith and Ramsey, William (eds.), The Cambridge Handbook of Cognitive Science, pp. 5070. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Tomasello, Michael (2014). A Natural History of Human Thinking. Harvard University Press, Cambridge MA.Google Scholar
Tsitsiklis, John (2010). Commentary: Perspectives on Stochastic Optimization Over Time. INFORMS Journal on Computing, 22(1): 1819.Google Scholar
Turing, Alan (1937). On Computable Numbers, with an Application to the Entscheidungsproblem. Proceedings of the London Mathematical Society, s2-42 (1): 230265.Google Scholar
Turing, Alan (1950). Computing Machinery and Intelligence. Mind, 59(236): 433460.Google Scholar
Turkle, Sherry (1988). Artificial Intelligence and Psychoanalysis: A New Alliance. Daedalus, (117)1: 241268.Google Scholar
Turner, Jonathan (1986). The Theory of Structuration. American Journal of Sociology, 91(4): 969977.Google Scholar
Turner, Jonathan and Maryanski, Alexandra (2013). The Evolution of the Neurological Basis of Human Sociality. In Franks, David and Turner, Jonathan (eds.), Handbook of Neurosociology, pp. 289309. Springer, Dordrecht.Google Scholar
Turner, Stephen (1994). The Social Theory of Practices: Tradition, Tacit Knowledge, and Presuppositions. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago.Google Scholar
Turner, Stephen (2015). Understanding the Tacit. Routledge, London.Google Scholar
Tye, Michael (2018). Qualia. In Zalta, Edward N. (ed.), The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Summer 2018 ed.), https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/sum2018/entries/qualia/.Google Scholar
van Nuys, David (2010). An Interview with Wilma Bucci on Psychoanalysis and Cognitive Science, Gulf Bend Center, Victoria, TX. Accessed November 10, 2020, www.gulfbend.org/poc/view_doc.php?type=doc&id=38296.Google Scholar
van Veen, Fjodor (2017). The Neural Network Zoo. The Asimov Institute, Utrecht. Accessed November 10, 2020, www.asimovinstitute.org/neural-network-zoo/.Google Scholar
Velupillai, K. Vela (2005). The Impossibility of an Effective Theory of Policy in a Complex Economy. Universita degli Study di Trento, Dipartimento di Economia, Discussion Paper 14.Google Scholar
Velupillai, K. Vela, Zambelli, Stefano and Kinsella, Stephen (eds.) (2012). Computable Economics. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, UK.Google Scholar
Villatoro, Daniel, Andrighetto, Giulia, Conte, Rosaria and Sabater-Mir, Jordi (2015). Self-Policing Through Norm Internalization: A Cognitive Solution to the Tragedy of the Digital Commons in Social Networks. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 18(2)2.Google Scholar
von Bertalannfy, Ludwig (2015). General Systems Theory: Foundations, Development, Applications. George Braziller, New York.Google Scholar
von Neumann, John (1951). The General and Logical Theory of Automata. In Jeffress, Lloyd (ed.). Cerebral Mechanisms in Behavior: The Hixon Symposium, pp. 131. John Wiley & Sons, New York.Google Scholar
von Neumann, John (1958). The Computer and the Brain. Yale University Press, New Haven.Google Scholar
von Neumann, John and Morgenstern, Oskar (2007). Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton University Press, New Jersey.Google Scholar
Walsh, Anthony (2014). Biosociology: Bridging the Biology-Sociology Divide, Routledge, London.Google Scholar
Weinberg, Stephen (1993). Dreams of a Final Theory: The Search for the Fundamental Laws of Nature, pp. 5164. Vintage, New York.Google Scholar
Wilensky, Uri and Rand, William (2015). Introduction to Agent-Based Modeling: Modeling Natural, Social and Engineered Complex Systems with NetLogo. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Wilson, Edward (1975). Sociobiology: The New Synthesis. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Wilson, Edward (1978). On Human Nature. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Wilson, Robert and Keil, Frank (eds.) (2001). The MIT Encyclopedia of the Cognitive Sciences. The MIT Press, Cambridge MA.Google Scholar
Wittgenstein, Ludwig (2016). Philosophical Investigations. Wiley-Blackwell, Chichester, UK.Google Scholar
Wolfram, Stephen (2002). A New Kind of Science. Wolfram Media, Champaign, USA.Google Scholar
Zambelli, Stefano (2012). Computable Economics: Reconstructing the Nonconstructive. New Mathematics and Natural Computation, 8(1): 113122.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Ruben Mercado
  • Book: Artificial Economics
  • Online publication: 28 October 2021
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009036719.012
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Ruben Mercado
  • Book: Artificial Economics
  • Online publication: 28 October 2021
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009036719.012
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Ruben Mercado
  • Book: Artificial Economics
  • Online publication: 28 October 2021
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009036719.012
Available formats
×