Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-42gr6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-16T03:56:25.930Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The (South) American Dream: Mobility and Economic Outcomes of First- and Second-Generation Immigrants in Nineteenth-Century Argentina

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  24 November 2017

Santiago Pérez*
Affiliation:
Santiago Pérez is Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, University of California, Davis, 1118 Social Sciences and Humanities, Davis, CA 95616. E-mail: seperez@ucdavis.edu.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

I study the mobility and economic outcomes of European immigrants and their children in nineteenth-century Argentina, the second largest destination country during the Age of Mass Migration. I use new data linking males across censuses and passenger lists of arrivals to Buenos Aires. First-generation immigrants experienced faster occupational upgrading than natives. Occupational mobility was substantial relative to Europe; immigrants holding unskilled occupations upon arrival experienced high rates of occupational upgrading. Second-generation immigrants outperformed the sons of natives in terms of literacy, occupational status and access to property, and experienced higher rates of intergenerational mobility out of unskilled occupations.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The Economic History Association 2017 

During the Age of Mass Migration (1850–1913), 55 million Europeans left their countries of origin and moved to the New World. After the United States, Argentina was the second largest destination country in the period, receiving 6.2 million immigrants. By 1914, 30 percent of Argentina's population was foreign-born.

The conventional view on this migration episode is that Argentina constituted a “land of opportunity,” offering European immigrants a good chance to experience upward economic mobility.Footnote 1 Although this view has been pervasive in the historical literature,Footnote 2 there is little quantitative evidence to support it. Moreover, the quantitative evidence that does exist is based on the published tabulations of the census. While these tabulations provide useful information on the economic performance of immigrants at one point in time, they offer little insight into how immigrants progressed as they spent time in the country. In addition, the published census data contain no information on parental place of birth, which prevents a systematic study of second-generation immigrants’ economic performance.

I study the mobility and economic outcomes of European immigrants and their children in nineteenth-century Argentina. To do so, I use newly collected data linking males across the 1869 and 1895 national censuses of population and passenger ship lists of immigrant arrivals to the city of Buenos Aires (Pérez Reference Pérez2017). These data enable me to follow a large group of immigrants and their children and to track their progress while in the country. To the best of my knowledge, this article is the first to use longitudinal data following individuals over time and across places to provide evidence on the economic performance of immigrants in late nineteenth-century Argentina.

The first part of my analysis looks at the occupational mobility of first-generation immigrants. I ask whether immigrants started in lower paying occupations than natives but converged to them as they spent time in the country. I find that, upon arrival, European immigrants held on average slightly lower paying occupations than natives. Yet, consistent with assimilation into the labor market of Argentina, my findings suggest that immigrants from most of the major sending countries outpaced natives in terms of occupational upgrading. These results contrast with recent evidence on the Age of Mass Migration in the United States (Abramitzky, Boustan, and Eriksson Reference Abramitzky, Leah and Eriksson2014), where immigrants appear to have experienced similar rates of occupational upgrading as natives.

Once I have characterized the occupational progress of immigrants after their arrival to Argentina, I study the extent to which immigrants who stayed in Argentina experienced progress relative to their pre-migration occupations. I find that immigrants were very likely to upgrade their occupations: About 75 percent of those who declared an unskilled occupation upon arrival experienced occupational upgrading in less than 15 years. Moreover, relatively skilled immigrants experienced little occupational downgrading. Comparing my results to evidence from similarly constructed data for the United States (Ferrie Reference Ferrie1997), my findings suggest that European immigrants in Argentina were better able to exploit their pre-migration human capital than those migrating to the United States.

My data only enable me to characterize the occupational trajectories of immigrants who migrated permanently to Argentina. These immigrants are of special interest from a historical point of view, since they participated in the labor market of Argentina for many years and were also likely to raise children in the country. However, in interpreting the results described earlier, it is useful to bear in mind that the experience of the average immigrant might have been different from the experience of those who settled permanently.

The second part of my analysis focuses on the children of European immigrants: the “second generation.” I find that the sons of European immigrants experienced substantially better economic outcomes than the sons of natives: They were more likely to be literate, held higher paying occupations and were more likely to own property as adults. The relative advantage of the second generation was not confined to any single sending country. Rather, the sons of immigrants from every major sending country outperformed the sons of natives. In explaining these results, I provide suggestive evidence that the higher “ethnic capital” (Borjas Reference Borjas1992) of the children of European immigrants might have contributed to their advantages in adulthood.

Finally, I contrast the intergenerational mobility of second-generation immigrants to that of the children of natives. I find a relatively similar persistence of occupational status among second-generation immigrants compared to children of natives. On the one hand, the children of unskilled European immigrants were more likely to exit those occupations than the children of unskilled natives. However, the sons of white-collar immigrants were more likely to work in white-collar occupations in adulthood than the sons of white-collar natives. As a result, occupational persistence was on average similar across the two groups.

A number of features make Argentina in the Age of Mass Migration an interesting case study of the economic performance of international immigrants. First, the magnitude of the migration flow relative to the native population was substantial by both historical and contemporary standards. Second, in contrast to immigrants entering the United States during this time period and to many immigrants today, immigrants entering Argentina exhibited higher levels of human capital than natives and came from countries that resembled Argentina in terms of average living standards.Footnote 3 Hence, this migration episode can shed light on what immigrant assimilation might look like in a setting where immigrants had high human capital and were a fairly numerous group relative to natives. Finally, the opportunity to construct longitudinal data that follow a large number of immigrants and their children enables me to deal with some of the methodological challenges faced by researchers studying immigrant assimilation (Borjas Reference Borjas1985; Abramitzky, Boustan, and Eriksson Reference Abramitzky, Leah and Eriksson2014).

HISTORICAL CONTEXT AND RELATED LITERATURE: ARGENTINA IN THE AGE OF MASS MIGRATION

The 1853 Constitution made it a national priority to attract European immigrants to help populate the vast and sparsely populated Argentine territory. In the mind of the elites governing the country, immigrants from Europe—especially those from the north of the continent—were needed to provide a “civilizing influence” that would enable Argentina to grow as a prosperous and free nation (Alberdi Reference Alberdi1852).Footnote 4

From 1857 to 1930, Argentina received 6.2 million immigrants from Europe, becoming the second largest receiving country in the period (after the United States) and the largest in per-capita terms (Germani Reference Germani1966). Figure 1 shows the number of yearly arrivals of overseas immigrants to Argentina. Until 1862, the number of yearly arrivals was below 10,000, but started to increase rapidly thereafter. This increase coincided with the unification of the different provincial governments into a single national authority following the Battle of Pavón in 1861. By 1914, the year of the third national census, Argentina's population had grown from less than two million in 1869 to more than eight million, of which 30 percent were foreign born.

Source: Argentina, Anuario de la Dirección General de Estadística (1908).

Figure 1 NUMBER OF NEW IMMIGRANT ARRIVALS, 1857–1900

Despite the Argentine elites' desire to attract immigrants from the north of Europe, nearly half of the immigrants were of Italian origin. In 1895, Italian immigrants accounted for 11 percent of the population of Argentina. Spain was the second most numerous sending country, representing around a third of the total immigration. Although immigrants from France were not as numerous overall, they accounted for a relatively large fraction of the early-arriving immigrants that are the main focus of this article.

Conventional accounts of the period describe Argentina as a country where “hard working” immigrants had an easy path to upward economic mobility (Alsina Reference Alsina1898). Although this view is also popular among early scholars (Diaz-Alejandro Reference Diaz-Alejandro1970; Conde Reference Conde1979; Baily Reference Baily1983), there is little quantitative evidence supporting it. In a series of widely debated studies, Gino Germani (Reference Germani1966) uses the published census tabulations to study the extent of occupational mobility in nineteenth-century Argentina. His study finds that immigrants moved up the occupational ladder at a faster pace than natives. However, a concern with inferring mobility from aggregate data is that the pool of immigrants changes from census to census, either because new immigrants arrive to the country or because some return to their countries of origin. Hence, it is not possible to disentangle changes in the social standing of immigrants from changes in the composition of the immigrant pool. In the case of Argentina, an added difficulty is the lack of information on year of arrival to the country in the nineteenth-century censuses.

A more recent study by María Liliana Da Orden (Reference Da Orden2005) also offers some support for the optimistic view of immigrant social mobility. The author studies the occupational mobility of Spanish immigrants in Mar del Plata, a coastal city in the Province of Buenos Aires. By linking birth and marriage records of the children of immigrants, she is able to observe immigrants’ occupation at two different points in time. She documents that, after an average of 26 years, 51 percent of the immigrants in her sample had moved up in the occupational ladder.

Other studies present a more negative outlook on the possibilities for social progress in nineteenth-century Argentina. Mark Szuchman (Reference Szuchman1981) links census records from 1869 to 1895 for immigrants and natives residing in the city of Córdoba. He finds that upward mobility was rare among immigrants, although the author is only able to follow individuals who had stayed in the city of Córdoba until 1895. Eugene F. Sofer (Reference Sofer1982) examines the occupational mobility of Eastern European Jewish immigrants in the city of Buenos Aires at the late nineteenth-century. The author links individuals from the 1895 census to the records of the Chevrah Kedyscha Ashkenazi, the main Jewish association in Buenos Aires. He documents little upward mobility, with most immigrants remaining trapped in unskilled jobs or even experiencing downward mobility.

Existing studies that use individual level data to assess the economic mobility of immigrants suffer from two main limitations.Footnote 5 First, these studies focus on either specific immigrant groups or on immigrants living in specific places within Argentina. Second, because economic and geographical mobility are probably associated, limiting the analysis to immigrants who did not change their place of residence is likely to underestimate the economic mobility experienced by the typical immigrant. Later, I show that failing to track internal migrants indeed results in lower estimated rates of occupational mobility among first-generation immigrants.

From a methodological point of view, this article is closely related to Joseph P. Ferrie (Reference Ferrie1997) and Ran Abramitzky, Leah Platt Boustan, and Katherine Eriksson (Reference Abramitzky, Leah and Eriksson2014). Ferrie (Reference Ferrie1997) links records of ship arrivals of immigrants to U.S. censuses in the Antebellum period to look at the occupational mobility of immigrants relative to Europe. The author finds that immigrants, in particular those from Britain and Germany, experienced relatively high rates of upward occupational mobility during this time period. Abramitzky, Boustan, and Eriksson (Reference Abramitzky, Leah and Eriksson2014) use linked census data to study the labor market assimilation of immigrants in the United States at the early twentieth-century. The authors find that immigrants exhibited similar rates of occupational upgrading as natives.

This article is also related to a growing body of literature in economic history that uses linked data to study historical migration episodes. In addition to the two articles described earlier, some other examples include Abramitzky, Boustan, and Eriksson (Reference Abramitzky, Leah and Eriksson2012, Reference Abramitzky, Leah and Eriksson2013), Boustan, Matthew E. Kahn, and Paul W. Rhode (Reference Abramitzky, Leah and Eriksson2012); William J. Collins and Marianne H. Wanamaker (Reference Collins and Wanamaker2014, Reference Collins and Wanamaker2015); Jason Long and Ferrie (Reference Long and Ferrie2013), Long (Reference Long2005), Edward Kosack and Zachary Ward (Reference Kosack and Ward2014), and Laura Salisbury (Reference Salisbury2014). In contrast to this article, the focus of this literature has been to study either internal migrations within the United States or the United Kingdom or international migrations to the United States.

DATA

Linking the 1869 and 1895 Censuses

I constructed a new sample following natives and immigrants across Argentina's national censuses of 1869 and 1895. To do so, I took advantage of the fact that both censuses' handwritten manuscripts are indexed and can be searched through the genealogy website FamilySearch.org.Footnote 6 The sample includes males—natives and immigrants—who were of working-age in both census years and males—sons of natives and native-born sons of immigrants—who were observed in their childhood household in 1869 and as adults in 1895.

To construct this sample, I identified two groups of individuals in the 1869 census full count: (1) males 18 to 35 years old, born in either Argentina or one of the six largest European sending countries (England, France, Germany, Italy, Spain, and Switzerland), and (2) males 0 to 17 years old, born in Argentina, with father present in the household and father born in Argentina or one of the European countries listed earlier. These six European countries were the only sending countries with more than 1,000 residents in the relevant age cohort in 1869 Argentina, accounting for more than 95 percent of all European immigrants at that time.Footnote 7 These two groups included a total of 448,201 individuals, of which 58,755 were born in one of the European sending countries included in the analysis and 22,932 were native-born sons of immigrants from these countries.

I then searched the 1895 census full count for a set of potential matches for each of these individuals. Based on the similarity in reported names and (estimated) years of birth, I calculated a linking score ranging from 0 to 1 for each pair of potential matches: Higher scores represented pairs of records that were more similar to each other. Full details on the procedure used to compute the linking scores are provided in the Online Appendix.

I used these linking scores to inform my decision rule on which records to incorporate into the analysis. To be considered a unique match for an individual in the 1869 census, a record in the 1895 census had to satisfy three conditions: (1) be the record with the highest linking score among all the potential matches for that individual, (2) have a linking score earlier a minimum threshold , and (3) have a linking score sufficiently higher than the second-best linking score .Footnote 8

Because the linking is based on potentially noisy information, there is a trade-off in choosing the cutoff values p_ and l. On the one hand, higher values of p_ and l imply that a larger fraction of true matches will be discarded from the analysis. In addition, individuals who report their identifying information with high accuracy and have more uncommon names—within their place and year of birth—are more likely to be uniquely matched under a more stringent rule. On the other hand, lower values of p_ and l will lead to a larger sample but to a higher share of incorrect matches. With this trade-off in mind, my baseline results are based on a sample created using a relatively conservative choice of the parameters p_ and l. As a result, my matching rates are lower than those typically found in recent economic history papers using U.S. census data.

The matching rate was 11.6 percent for sons of natives and 13.6 percent for sons of immigrants. I was able to uniquely link approximately 9.5 percent of working-age natives and 10 percent of working-age immigrants. Table A.1 in the Online Appendix shows the matching rates that resulted from this linking process, disaggregated by country of origin and by age group. I provide a detailed discussion on matching rates and additional sources of match failure in Online Appendix Table A.2.Footnote 9 Once I had completed the linking procedure, I manually digitized the economic outcomes variables using the handwritten census manuscripts available online at FamilySearch.org. In the case of working-age immigrants, children of immigrants and children of natives, I digitized the economic outcome variables for every individual in the linked sample. In the case of working-age natives, I digitized the economic outcomes only for a random sample of the linked individuals. The final sample includes about 6,000 working-age natives, 5,000 working-age immigrants, 18,000 sons of natives and 2,500 native-born sons of immigrants.

Linking Passenger Lists to the 1895 Census

To assess the extent to which immigrants experienced occupational progress relative to Europe, I complement the earlier data with a sample linking male immigrants arriving to the city of Buenos Aires to the 1895 census. To construct this sample, I started with a sample of 54,036 working-ageFootnote 10 immigrants who appeared in ship arrival records between 1882 and 1894.Footnote 11 These records were originally collected by the National Migration Office and have been digitized by CEMLA (Centro de Estudios Migratorios Latinoamericanos), a research center in Buenos Aires. Each record contains the name, occupation, date of arrival, port of origin and entry, civil status, and age of each passenger on the ship. In this time period, about 75 percent of immigrants entered Argentina through the port of Buenos Aires (Dirección General de Inmigración 1925).

I then linked these immigrants to the 1895 census using a method analogous to the one described earlier. I was able to link 3,157 immigrants, which represents approximately a 6 percent matching rate. Linking these data is more challenging than linking the censuses because immigrants typically declared their original first name upon arrival but adopted a Spanish version of it while in Argentina.Footnote 12 Table A.3 in the Online Appendix shows the number of individuals and linked individuals in this sample, by country of birth.

Comparing the Linked Samples to the Population

Given the absence of numerical identifiers in the data, names provide the most important source of information in the linking procedure. The dependence on names could lead to a biased sample if having a name that is both uncommon and accurately recorded is correlated with social and economic characteristics. In this subsection, I compare individuals in the linked samples to individuals in the cross-sectional data. I provide further details on this comparison in the Online Appendix.

The Online Appendix Tables A.4 to A.7 show the results of these comparisons. In these tables, I compare natives and immigrants in the linked sample to natives and immigrants in the 1869 and 1895 census cross-sections, based on the nationally representative census samples compiled by Jorge L. Somoza (Reference Somoza1967). Overall, the evidence suggests some degree of positive selection of individuals into the linked census sample. First, the white-collar occupational category tends to be overrepresented in the linked sample, with the fraction of white-collar workers being 2 percentage points higher than in the cross-section among native-born working-age individuals in the 1895 census. Second, individuals in the linked sample were 10 percentage points more likely to own property and 9 percentage points more likely be literate.

In Table A.8 in the Online Appendix, I compare immigrants in the passenger lists who were matched to an observation in the 1895 census to immigrants who were not, as well as immigrants in the linked sample in 1895 to immigrants in the 1895 cross-section. The main difference between the linked sample and the cross-section is that immigrants from Spain are overrepresented in the linked sample. For instance, while only 20 percent of immigrants in the passenger lists were from Spain, 35 percent of immigrants in the linked sample were from this country. This overrepresentation likely reflects the fact that immigrants from Spain did not change their names upon arrival to Argentina, making it easier to find them in the 1895 census.

Occupations and Earnings Data

Similar to U.S. national censuses of the period, nineteenth-century Argentine censuses lack information on individual-level earnings or income. I dealt with this feature of the data using two standard approaches in the literature. First, following Abramitzky, Boustan, and Eriksson (Reference Abramitzky, Leah and Eriksson2012, Reference Abramitzky, Leah and Eriksson2014) and Collins and Wanamaker (Reference Collins and Wanamaker2014), I constructed a measure of typical earnings by occupation.Footnote 13 Second, I classified the occupational titles into occupational categories.

To create the occupational earnings measure, I employed information from a variety of historical sources. First, I used information on daily wages in blue-collar occupations in the city of Buenos Aires from William I. Buchanan (Reference Buchanan1998). Second, I used the published census volumes to construct estimates of earnings in the commercial and industrial sectors. Third, I used the congressional reports of Antonio M. Correa and Emilio Lahitte (Reference Correa and Lahitte1898) to estimate earnings in the farming sector. Table A.9 in the Online Appendix shows the sources of income data used in the analysis. Further details on the construction of this earnings measure, including more information on the sources and assumptions are provided in the Online Appendix.

It is worth emphasizing that constructing a measure of typical earnings is challenging, especially for self-employed individuals. As a result, I conducted a number of sensitivity checks to assess the robustness of the results that rely on the occupational score. In particular, I paid special attention to the issue of assigning earnings to farmers.

I also classified the more than 100 occupational titles in my sample into broad occupational categories.Footnote 14 To do so, I first assigned each occupation a code from the Historical International Classification of Occupations (HISCO). This classification is based on the International Standard Classification of Occupations (ISCO) and has been adapted to deal with historical data. I then mapped each HISCO code to an occupational category using the Historical International Social Class Scheme (HISCLASS), developed by Ineke Maas, Andrew Miles and Marco H.D. Van Leeuwen (Reference Maas, Miles and Van Leeuwen2002). Finally, I collapsed the HISCLASS scheme into four broad categories following Long and Ferrie (Reference Long and Ferrie2013): white-collar (HISCLASS 1–5), farmer (HISCLASS 8), skilled/semi-skilled (HISCLASS 6–7, 9) and unskilled (HISCLASS 10–12). Table 1 shows the ten most common occupations for working-age individuals in 1895 and their corresponding occupational category, reported separately for natives and immigrants in the linked census sample.

Table 1 FREQUENT OCCUPATIONS, 1895 CENSUS

Notes: This table shows the ten most frequent occupations in 1895 among working-age natives and immigrants in the sample linking the 1869 and 1895 national censuses.

Sources: Linked sample created by following working-age individuals through the 1869 and 1895 population censuses of Argentina. The text and Online Appendix described sample construction in detail.

There are three limitations associated with using occupations rather than earnings to measure labor market assimilation. First, I am not able to capture changes in an individual's social standing that stem from changes in their economic status within a given occupation. Second, the occupational earnings measure explicitly fixes the ranking of occupations in its 1895 level. As a result, the measure is unable to capture changes in economic status that occur due to changes in the distribution of income across occupations over time.Footnote 15 Third, because the censuses lack a question on employment status, I cannot distinguish employed from unemployed individuals.

THE FIRST GENERATION

Occupational Mobility of Natives and Immigrants

Panel (a) in Table 2 shows a transition matrix for natives, while Panel (b) shows this same matrix for immigrants. Each element of these matrices represents the fraction (number) of individuals working in occupational category i in 1869 that worked in occupational category j in 1895. The last row in both matrices shows the distribution of individuals across occupational categories in 1895.

Table 2 OCCUPATIONAL MOBILITY OF NATIVES AND IMMIGRANTS, 1869 (ROWS) AND 1895 (COLUMNS)

Notes: Panel (a) presents an occupational transition matrix for native-born males. Each cell in this matrix shows the percentage and number (between brackets) of individuals in the linked sample in each occupational category in 1869 (rows) and 1895 (columns). Panel (b) presents the same matrix for foreign-born individuals. Occupations were classified based on the HISCLASS scheme. White-collar (HISCLASS 1–5), farmer (HISCLASS 8), skilled/semi-skilled (HISCLASS 6–7, 9) and unskilled (HISCLASS 10–12). Panel (c) reports summary measures of mobility. M (Column 1) corresponds to the fraction of individuals o↩ the main diagonal of the matrix. d(P, J) and d(Q, J) (Columns 2 and 3) correspond to the distance between matrices P and Q and a matrix representing full independence, respectively. d(P, Q) (Column 4) represents the distance between matrices P and Q and d(P, Q)i (Column 5) represents this same distance after excluding the elements of the main diagonal from each matrix. For each of these distances, I performed a test of the hypothesis that d(i, j) = 0. Significance levels are indicated by ∗∗∗p < 0.01, ∗∗p < 0.05, ∗p < 0.1.

Sources: Data are from the sample of linked census records, as described in the text and Online Appendix.

The first noticeable difference is that immigrants and natives were concentrated in different occupational groups. Farming was considerably more prevalent among natives than among immigrants, both in 1869 and in 1895. This difference is consistent with the different propensities of natives and immigrants to locate in urban areas. In 1869, 63 percent of the foreign-born resided in urban locations, whereas this proportion was only 28 percent among natives.

In Panel (c) of Table 2, I present a number of summary measures of mobility based on the transition matrices. The simplest measure of mobility is the fraction of individuals who switched occupational categories across years; that is the fraction of individuals off the main diagonal of the matrix. This statistic suggests that there was more occupational mobility among immigrants than among natives, with 59 percent of immigrants and 51 percent of natives switching occupational categories from 1869 to 1895.

Immigrants also appear to exhibit more mobility out of the unskilled category: 72 percent of those initially in unskilled occupations had moved out of this category by 1895, compared to 64 percent among natives. The typical path out of the unskilled category was different for the two groups. Natives usually left the unskilled category by switching into farming, whereas immigrants moved into more urban occupations such as white-collar and skilled/semi-skilled jobs. While only 8 percent of natives in unskilled occupations in 1869 worked in white-collar jobs by 1895, this fraction is considerably higher (23 percent) among immigrants.

As discussed in Long and Ferrie (Reference Long and Ferrie2013), a key shortcoming of using this simple measure to compare mobility across two matrices is that the measure does not distinguish whether differences in mobility are due to: (1) differences in the distribution of occupations across the two matrices or (2) differences in the strength of the association of the rows and columns in each of the two matrices. This distinction is important in this setting because, as discussed earlier, the distribution of occupations among natives differed markedly from the distribution among immigrants.

To establish whether the row-column association was stronger (i.e., there was less occupational mobility) among natives or among immigrants, I followed Long and Ferrie (Reference Long and Ferrie2013) in completing the following steps. First, I computed the Altham (Reference Altham1970) statistic d(P,Q), which measures the difference in the strength of the row-column association in matrices P—the mobility matrix of natives and Q—the mobility matrix of immigrants.Footnote 16 Higher values of d(P,Q) imply greater differences in this association, but are not informative regarding which of the two matrices exhibit more mobility. Next, I calculated d(P,J) and d(Q,J), which measure this same difference but relative to a matrix J representing full independence (a matrix of ones). Higher values of d(P,J) or d(Q,J) imply greater departures from independence, or less mobility.

Panel (c) of Table 2 shows that d(P,Q) is significantly different from zero, suggesting that the strength of the row-column association is different in the two matrices. In addition, the departure from independence is larger for natives than for immigrants, d(P,J) > d(Q,J). Taken together, these results suggest that there was higher occupational mobility among immigrants than among natives.Footnote 17

One key limitation of the existing studies of immigrant mobility in Argentina is the inability to track internal migrants. Table B.1 in the Online Appendix shows that this inability leads to lower rates of estimated occupational mobility among immigrants. In this table, I divide the sample of immigrants into “movers” and “stayers.” Individuals are classified as “movers” if by 1895 they lived outside of their 1869 department of residence. Panels (a) and (b) show an occupational mobility matrix computed separately for stayers and movers, respectively. Panel (c) of this table shows that stayers were less likely to switch occupational categories than movers (48 percent versus 65 percent). Similarly, the Altham statistic described earlier indicates that the mobility matrix for stayers exhibits a greater departure from independence that the mobility matrix for movers.

Occupational Earnings Regressions

Next, I use the occupational earnings data to compare the rates at which natives and immigrants moved into higher paying occupations. In particular, I estimate the following model of occupational earnings:

(1)

where Occupational Earnings it is the daily occupational earnings of individual i in year t, Immigrant i is an indicator variable of whether the individual was foreign-born, Year1895 t is an indicator of whether the observation belongs to the 1895 census X it and is a vector of individual-level characteristics. In the baseline specification, X it is limited to a quartic in age. I restrict the sample to working-age individuals, defined as those being at least 18 years old and at most 35 years old in 1869, and to those with a reported occupation in both census years. Because matching rates are not constant across sending countries, in the baseline specification each observation is weighted to reflect the country of birth distribution in 1895 Argentina.

There are two main coefficients of interest in equation (1): b 1, which captures baseline differences in the occupational earnings of natives and immigrants, and b 3, which captures differences in their occupational earnings growth.

This specification differs from the standard in the immigrant assimilation literature, which uses years since migration as the independent variable of interest (Abramitzky, Boustan, and Eriksson Reference Abramitzky, Leah and Eriksson2014; Borjas Reference Borjas1985; Chiswick Reference Chiswick1978; Lubotsky Reference Lubotsky2007). It is not possible to estimate the standard specification in this context because the censuses lack information on year of arrival to Argentina. This lack of information also prevents me from following cohorts of immigrants over time, as in George J. Borjas (Reference Borjas1985) and Chris Minns (Reference Minns2000). Note, however, that estimating this regression on the panel data enables me to keep the composition of the sample constant across census years. In doing so, I am able to disentangle changes in the social standing of immigrants from changes in the composition of the immigrant pool.Footnote 18

The first column of Table 3 presents the results of the baseline specification. This specification suggests that natives had relatively higher occupational earnings in 1869, but that immigrants upgraded their occupations faster. In particular, the growth in occupational earnings among immigrants was 6 percent faster than among natives. This evidence is consistent with the finding of immigrants’ higher rates of movements out of the unskilled category documented in the previous subsection.

Table 3 OCCUPATIONAL EARNINGS REGRESSIONS

Notes: ∗∗∗p < 0.01, ∗∗p < 0.05, ∗p < 0.1. Robust standard errors in parentheses. All the regressions control for a fourth order polynomial on age and are weighted by the country of birth distribution in 1895. See the Online Appendix for details on how the income measure was computed. Column 1 reports the baseline specification. In Column 2, I restrict the sample to individuals residing in the provinces of Buenos Aires (including the city of Buenos Aires), Entre R´íos and Santa Fe in 1869. In Column 3, I include department of residence fixed effects and the interaction between these fixed effects and a 1895 census year indicator. In Column 4, I control for literacy and an interaction between literacy and a 1895 census year indicator. In Column 5, I control both for department fixed effects and their interaction with the 1895 indicator, and for literacy and its interaction with the 1895 indicator.

Sources: Data are from the sample of linked census records, as described in the text and Online Appendix.

Explaining the Differences Between Immigrants and Natives

I explore two main alternative hypotheses; other than labor market assimilation, that could explain the faster growth in occupational earnings among immigrants. First, I test whether this finding could be attributed to the greater propensity of immigrants to locate in areas of Argentina that were experiencing faster progress, particularly urban areas. Second, I test whether the finding is driven by an overall increase in returns to skill that disproportionately benefited immigrants, who had on average higher human capital levels than natives.

To explore the first possibility, I perform two different exercises. First, in Column 2 of Table 3, I restrict the sample to individuals who in 1869 resided in the provinces of Buenos Aires (including the city of Buenos Aires), Entre Ríos and Santa Fe. These three provinces hosted more than 95 percent of the European immigrants in 1869. When restricted to this set of provinces, I find that European immigrants performed worse than natives in the baseline year, but still exhibited higher relative occupational earnings growth. Second, in Column 3, I include department of residence fixed effects and an interaction between department of residence fixed effects and a 1895 census year indicator. That is, I compare immigrants residing in the same departments and allow the department of residence effects to differ based on the census year. The results are similar to the ones that I obtain in the previous specification.Footnote 19 Finally, the results (not reported) are similar if I restrict the sample to: (1) individuals residing in urban locations in 1869 or (2) individuals residing in urban locations both in 1869 and in 1895. Hence, the evidence suggests that immigrants experienced faster growth in occupational earnings also within urban areas.

As noted in the introduction, European immigrants had higher human capital levels than natives, as captured by literacy rates. Accordingly, the higher growth in occupational earnings among immigrants might reflect a general increase in the returns to skill from 1869 to 1895 rather than assimilation. To test this possibility, in Column 4 of Table 3 I estimate a version of equation (1) in which I include two additional controls: a literacy indicator and an interaction between a literacy indicator and a 1895 census year indicator. Again, I find faster occupational earnings growth among immigrants than among natives.

In the last column of Table 3, I test whether the earlier explanations combined could account for immigrants' relatively faster growth in occupational earnings. To do so, I include both the interaction between literacy and the 1895 census year indicator and the department of residence fixed effects interacted with the 1895 census indicator, as well as the main effects of both groups of variables. The evidence still suggests faster occupational upgrading among immigrants than among natives.

Heterogeneity by Sending Country

Immigrants from different sending countries differed both in terms of their human capital levels and in terms of their cultural and linguistic similarity to natives. Hence, the assimilation experience of the average immigrant might mask differences across sending countries. To explore this possibility, I estimate a version of equation (1) in which I include an indicator variable for each of the sending countries included in my sample, as well as an interaction of each of these country indicators with an 1895 census indicator. This specification captures differences both in country-specific baseline occupational earnings and in country-specific occupational earnings growth.

In Figure 2, I plot the coefficients corresponding to each of the countries around a 95 percent confidence interval. Upon arrival, immigrants from every major sending country (with the exception of Italy) appear to do better than natives, although the difference with respect to natives is not statistically significant for French immigrants. The evidence is broadly consistent with immigrants from countries with higher levels of average human capital doing better upon arrival. In particular, the ranking of countries based on average occupational earnings mostly matches the ranking of countries based on the average literacy of immigrants in Argentina. In addition, the evidence suggests that immigrants from every major sending country (with the exception of Switzerland) experienced faster occupational upgrading than natives. Note, however, that the interaction between the country of origin indicator and the 1895 census indicator is not statistically significant for the English or the German immigrants.

Notes: I estimate a version of equation (1) in which I replace the Immigrant indicator with separate indicators for each of the countries included in my sample, as well as an interaction of each of these country indicators with an 1895 census indicator. This figure shows the estimated coefficient around a 95 percent confidence interval corresponding to each country of origin indicator and the coefficient corresponding to the interaction between the country of origin indicator and the 1895 census indicator. Omitted category are natives. Sources: Data are from the sample of linked census records, as described in the text and Online Appendix.

Figure 2 OCCUPATIONAL EARNINGS REGRESSION, BY COUNTRY OF ORIGIN

Alternative Specifications and Robustness

In this subsection, I show that the finding of immigrants' higher occupational earnings growth relative to natives is robust to: (1) how earnings are assigned to farmers, (2) using an alternative measure of occupational status based on access to property as the dependent variable, and (3) the procedure used to create the linked sample.

Assigning an earnings measure to farmers is challenging for a variety of reasons. First, it is hard to distinguish in the census between owners and operators of farms and farm employees. Although the 1895 census contains a question on whether the person holds real estate property, which could be useful for distinguishing the two, this question is not available in the 1869 census. In addition, the farming sector encompasses a wide range of economic realities, ranging from small farms to large-scale production. Hence, relying on typical earnings is more challenging than in other occupations where within-occupation earnings dispersion is likely to be less prominent. While my baseline measure of occupational earnings introduces a distinction based on the reported occupational title between small (who I estimate to be close to the median in terms of occupational earnings) and large farmers (who are at the top of the income distribution) and also incorporates farm laborers as a separate category, this distinction is most likely not sufficiently rich to capture the different realities within the farming sector.

In Column 1 of Table 4, I exclude individuals who were employed as farmers in either 1869 or 1895 from the sample. The table shows that the finding of higher occupational upgrading for immigrants remains unchanged in this case. However, I now find that immigrants outperform natives even upon arrival. Despite the challenges in measuring occupational earnings for farmers, excluding them could introduce biases if immigrants and natives exhibit differential rates of movement into and out of farming. In the context of Argentina, immigrants’ occupational upgrading relative to natives is exaggerated once farmers are excluded, as moving into farming was a more frequent avenue for upward mobility for natives than for immigrants, as shown earlier.

Table 4 OCCUPATIONAL EARNINGS REGRESSIONS, ROBUSTNESS

Notes: ∗∗∗p < 0.01, ∗∗p < 0.05, ∗p < 0.1. Robust standard errors in parentheses. All the regressions control for a fourth order polynomial on age and are weighted by the country of birth distribution in 1895 (with exception of Columns 3 and 4). In Column 1, I exclude individuals employed as farmers in either 1869 or 1895 from the sample. In Column 2, I report the results of estimating the baseline equation using an alternative dependent variable based on access to property. In Column 3, I reweight the sample to account for differences in observable characteristics between the linked sample and the population. In Column 4, I report the results without reweighting the sample by the country of birth distribution in 1895. In column 5, I exclude immigrants with common first names (frequency higher than median within country of birth) from the sample. In Column 6, I drop all the immigrants from the sample who are not perfect matches.

Sources: Data are from the sample of linked census records, as described in the text and Online Appendix.

Another concern with the finding of faster occupational earnings growth among immigrants is that it might be sensitive to how the earnings measure was constructed. If my measure systematically overestimated earnings in occupations to which immigrants were more likely to transition, I would find that immigrants exhibited faster occupational upgrading than natives. As an alternative approach, I computed a measure of occupational status based on access to property. The 1895 census includes the question “¿Posee propiedad raíz?” (“Do you own real estate property?).”Footnote 20 I used this information to compute an alternative measure of occupational status: the fraction of individuals within a given occupation that owned real estate property in 1895. For instance, this measure takes a value of 0.2 for jornaleros (day laborers) and a value of 0.7 for comerciantes (storekeepers), which means that 20 percent of jornaleros and 70 percent of comerciantes in my sample held real estate property in 1895.Footnote 21 Column 2 in Table 4 shows that the finding of faster occupational upgrading among immigrants is robust to using the log of this measure as the dependent variable.

Finally, I assess the robustness of the results to the linking procedure used to create the sample. There are two main concerns related to the linking procedure. First, the linked samples are not fully representative of the population. Second, the fraction of false positives might be higher among immigrants than among natives.

To alleviate the first concern, in Column 3 of Table 4 I show that my results are similar when I reweight the sample to account for differences in observable characteristics (in addition to country of birth) with respect to the census cross-section.Footnote 22 This evidence suggests that selection into the linked sample, at least based on observable characteristics, is unlikely to drive the results. In addition, Column 4 shows that the results are also similar when I do not reweight the sample to account for differences in matching rates across sending countries.

The second concern is that the fraction of false positives in the linked sample might be higher among immigrants than among natives. If that were the case, relying on a linked sample would mechanically overestimate the extent of mobility among immigrants; although not necessarily the extent of upward mobility. While this possibility cannot be fully ruled out, I can replicate my analysis in a sample where this issue is likely to be less prevalent: immigrants with infrequent names. In particular, I re-estimate equation 1using immigrants with whose names fall later the median in the first name frequency distribution within their country of birth, while keeping the full sample of natives. Column 5 shows that the finding of faster occupational upgrading is robust to excluding this group of immigrants from the sample.

Finally, in Column 6 I replicate the analysis but focusing on the sample of immigrants whose identifying information matches perfectly, while again keeping the full sample of natives.Footnote 23 Overall, this evidence suggests that the result of faster occupational upgrading is unlikely to be driven by features of the linking procedure.Footnote 24 Note, however, that restricting the sample to immigrants with uncommon names (which likely exacerbates positive selection of immigrants into the linked sample) causes immigrants to perform better than natives in the baseline year.

Occupational Mobility from Arrival to 1895

In the previous subsection, I documented the extent to which immigrants moved up in the occupational ladder as they spent time in Argentina. Yet, another question is whether immigrants were able to progress relative to their pre-migration occupations. To answer this question, I use the sample following immigrants from their arrival to the city of Buenos Aires to the 1895 census. In this sample, I observe an individual's occupation in Europe as declared upon arrival and his occupation in 1895.Footnote 25

Table 5 shows a transition matrix in which rows represent occupations in Europe and columns represent occupations in the 1895 census. Overall, about 80 percent of immigrants who entered Argentina from 1882 to 1894 switched their occupational category by 1895. Yet, the data strongly reject independence between an occupation upon arrival and an occupation in 1895 (p-value< 0.01).

Table 5 OCCUPATIONAL MOBILITY OF IMMIGRANTS, DECLARED UPON ARRIVAL (ROWS) AND IN 1895 CENSUS (COLUMNS)

Notes: Each cell in the table shows the percentage and the number (between brackets) of individuals in the linked sample in each occupational category upon arrival to Argentina (rows) and in 1895 (columns). Occupations were classified based on the HISCLASS scheme. White-collar (HISCLASS 1–5), farmer (HISCLASS 8), skilled/semi-skilled (HISCLASS 6–7, 9) and unskilled (HISCLASS10–12).

Sources: Data are from the sample of linked census records, as described in the text and Online Appendix.

Given the absence of a comparable full ranking of occupations in Argentina and each of the sending countries, it is not possible to assess the fraction of immigrants that downgraded or upgraded their occupations relative to Europe. However, under the assumption that the unskilled category is the least desirable, the data show that occupational upgrading occurred for a large fraction of those who had held unskilled occupations in Europe; less than 25 percent of those who entered the country as unskilled workers were still in those occupations by 1895. The fraction of immigrants moving out of unskilled occupations is substantially higher than documented by Ferrie (Reference Ferrie1997) in the Antebellum United States. Ferrie (Reference Ferrie1997) finds that about half of the immigrants arriving to the United States in the 1840–1850 period were still working as unskilled workers by 1860. Indeed, even when excluding Irish immigrants, who had the worst outcomes among all immigrant groups, from the U.S. data, the evidence suggests higher rates of upward occupational mobility in Argentina.Footnote 26

Another contrast relative to the findings of Ferrie (Reference Ferrie1997) is that immigrants who declared skilled/semi-skilled occupations were quite unlikely to experience occupational downgrading; only 14 percent of those initially in the skilled/semi-skilled category were working in unskilled occupations in 1895. In the U.S. case, the fraction experiencing downgrading was considerably higher; as high as 30 percent among skilled workers. Overall, this evidence suggests that immigrants entering Argentina benefited from relatively better opportunities for occupational upgrading than those entering the United States.Footnote 27

Similar to Ferrie (Reference Ferrie1997) and consistent with historical accounts of the period (Germani Reference Germani1966), I find that those who declared farming occupations upon arrival were fairly unlikely to work as farmers in Argentina, at least in the short run. Indeed, about 66 percent of these immigrants resided in urban locations by 1895 (35 percent in the city of Buenos Aires) compared to 72 percent and 40 percent among all immigrants in the sample. This finding confirms that, for many European immigrants, the Transatlantic move was accompanied by a shift from rural to urban occupations (Sánchez-Alonso Reference Sánchez-Alonso2007).

THE SECOND GENERATION

Intergenerational Occupational Mobility

In this section, I compare the intergenerational occupational mobility of the native-born sons of immigrants—the “second generation”—and the sons of natives. Panels (a) and (b) of Table 6 show an intergenerational mobility matrix for sons of natives and for sons of immigrants, respectively. Rows in each of these matrices represent a father's occupation in 1869 and columns show the occupation of his son in 1895. Each element of these matrices represents the fraction (number) of fathers in occupational category i in 1869 whose sons worked in occupational category j in 1895.

Table 6 INTERGENERATIONAL MOBILITY OF CHILDREN OF NATIVES AND IMMIGRANTS, FATHERS IN 1869 (ROWS) AND SONS IN 1895 (COLUMNS)

Notes: Panel (a) presents a transition matrix for sons of natives. Each cell in this matrix shows the percentage and the number (between brackets) of fathers in occupation i in 1869 with sons in occupation j in 1895. Panel (b) presents the same matrix for native-born sons of immigrants. Panel (c) presents the counterfactual occupational distribution for sons of natives had they been exposed to the transition matrix of sons of immigrants. Occupations were classified based on the HISCLASS scheme. White-collar (HISCLASS 1–5), farmer (HISCLASS 8), skilled/semi-skilled (HISCLASS 6–7, 9) and unskilled (HISCLASS 10–12). Panel (d) reports summary measures of mobility. M (Column 1) corresponds to the fraction of individuals o↩ the main diagonal of the matrix. d(P, J) and d(Q, J) (Columns 2 and 3) correspond to the distance between matrices P and Q and a matrix representing full independence, respectively. d(P,Q) (Column 4) represents the distance between matrices P and Q and d(P, Q)i (Column 5) represents this same distance after excluding the elements of the main diagonal from each matrix. For each of these distances, I performed a test of the hypothesis that d(i, j) = 0. Significance levels are indicated by ∗∗∗p < 0.01, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗p < 0.1.

Sources: Data are from the sample of linked census records, as described in the text and Online Appendix.

The first noticeable difference between the two groups is that movements out of unskilled occupations were considerably more frequent among the children of immigrants. About half of the sons of natives whose father worked in unskilled occupations themselves worked in these occupations, compared to only 25 percent among the children of immigrants. The opposite pattern occurs in the white-collar category, where persistence was much prominent among sons of immigrants than among sons of natives.

In Panel (c) of Table 6, I follow Collins and Wanamaker (Reference Collins and Wanamaker2017) in reporting a counterfactual exercise simulating the distribution of sons of natives across occupational categories had they been exposed to the transition matrix of the sons of immigrants. This exercise reveals two main findings. First, the fraction of sons of natives in unskilled occupations would have been substantially lower under this counterfactual: 17 percent versus 28 percent. Second, the fraction in white-collar occupations would have been almost twice as high: 33 percent versus 17 percent.Footnote 28 Taken together, these results suggest that the children of European immigrants faced better prospects for mobility out of unskilled jobs than the children of natives.Footnote 29

Panel (d) of Table 6 provides summary measures of mobility analogous to the ones presented earlier. The table shows that the fraction of sons switching occupational categories is almost identical in both groups: About 55 percent of sons are in a different occupational category relative to their father. Yet, using the Altham measure of mobility reveals slightly higher mobility among sons of natives than among sons of immigrants.

The Economic Performance of the Second Generation

Next, I compare the economic outcomes of the native-born sons of immigrants and the sons of natives. I begin by estimating the following model:

(2)

where Son Outcome i is an economic outcome of the son in father-son pair i, Second Generation i is an indicator variable that takes a value of one for native-born individuals whose father was an immigrant, X i is a vector of household characteristics (limited to a quartic in son's and father's age in the baseline specification), and e i is an error term, clustered at the level of the father to account for the presence of siblings in the data.

The key difficulty in estimating the earlier equation is that the censuses do not include a question on parental place of birth. I therefore infer this information by linking males from the 1895 census to their childhood household in 1869, where they were observed living with their parents. The sample is restricted to native-born males 26 to 44 years old in the 1895 census, that is, those who had already been born and that were young enough to still be living in their childhood household in 1869.

I first compare the literacy rate of second-generation immigrants to that of the children of natives. A son is defined as being literate if in 1895 he answered affirmatively to the question: “Do you know how to read and write?” The question does not specify whether the individual was literate in Spanish or in another language. In Column 1 of Table 7, X i includes only a quartic in father's and son's age. This specification shows that the sons of immigrants were substantially more likely to be literate as adults than the sons of natives, an advantage above 35 percentage points relative to a mean literacy rate of about 50 percent among natives.

Table 7 ECONOMIC OUTCOMES OF THE SECOND GENERATION

Notes: ∗∗∗p < 0.01, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗p < 0.1. Robust standard errors clustered at the level of the father in parentheses. This table shows the estimated coefficients in a regression comparing the children of immigrants and the children of natives in the 1895 census. The dependent variable is an indicator for literacy in Columns 1 to 3, log occupational earnings in Columns 4 to 6 and an indicator of access to property in Columns 7 to 9. Parental place of birth is inferred by linking individuals from the 1895 census to their childhood households in 1869. All regressions control for a quartic in son's and father's age. Household characteristics include the literacy of the father and a full set of dummies corresponding to occupational classes of the father. Enumeration district fixed effects are based on a family place of residence in 1869.

Sources: Data are from the sample of linked census records, as described in the text and Online Appendix.

As first-generation immigrants themselves were more likely to be literate than natives, one simple explanation for the earlier finding is the transmission of human capital from parents to their children. I test this hypothesis in Column 2, where I control for parental literacy and also include indicators corresponding to the occupational category of the father in 1869.Footnote 30 The point estimate goes down by about a third, suggesting that differences in parental background—beyond place of birth—play a role in explaining the advantage of the second generation. However, the difference remains large (about 23 percentage points) and statistically significant.

An alternative explanation for the observed difference in literacy rates is that, as discussed earlier, immigrants were more likely to reside in urban locations than natives. If, for instance, urban locations were better served by schools, then the children of immigrants would have been more likely to acquire formal education and thus be literate as adults. Moreover, the children of immigrants were disproportionately located in the relatively more prosperous areas of Argentina, the Littoral region. To explore this possibility, I estimate equation (2) adding a full set of enumeration district fixed effects, based on the family place of residence in 1869. In addition to controlling for the urban/rural status of the family's place of residence, these fixed effects control for other observable and unobservable factors that vary at the enumeration district level and that might have influenced literacy rates in adulthood.Footnote 31 The results in Column 3 again show that second-generation immigrants did better in terms of literacy, an advantage of about 15 percentage points, even when compared to sons of natives who grew up in similar locations.

Columns 4 to 6 in Table 7 repeat the earlier analysis using the log of occupational earnings as the outcome variable. The evidence also suggests a substantial advantage of the children of immigrants relative to the sons of natives. This difference is robust to controlling for father's literacy and occupational status in 1869 (in Column 5), as well as for observable and unobservable enumeration district characteristics (in Column 6).

In Columns 7 to 9, the dependent variable is an indicator that takes a value of one if the individual held real estate property in 1895. Interestingly, I do not observe an advantage of the sons of immigrants in terms of access to property as adults in the baseline specification (Column 7) or when controlling for father's literacy and occupational category (Column 8). However, second-generation immigrants also do better in terms of access to property, an advantage of 3.2 percentage points relative to a mean of 33 percent among sons of natives, when I include enumeration district fixed effects (Column 9). This pattern is consistent with the fact that property was more difficult to access in the relatively more urban and prosperous locations where European immigrant families resided in Argentina.

I next explore how the children of immigrants from different sending countries fared as adults. Figure 3 shows the results of estimating equation (2), now using separate country of origin indicators instead of a single second-generation indicator. In each of the figures, I plot the coefficient corresponding to each of the countries around a 95 percent confidence interval. Panel (a) shows the results for literacy, Panel (b) for log occupational earnings, and Panel (c) for access to property. In the three cases, I control for father's literacy and occupational category in 1869, as well as for enumeration district fixed effects as determined by the family place of residence in 1869. The figures show that the children of immigrants from every major sending country fared on average better as adults than the children of natives. The differences relative to the sons of natives are especially prominent with respect to literacy and occupational earnings. Overall, these results suggest that the advantage of second-generation immigrants was not confined to any particular sending country.

Notes: I estimate a version of equation (2) in the main text in which I replace the Second Generation indicator with separate indicator variables for each of the countries included my sample. The figure shows the estimated coefficient around a 95 percent confidence interval corresponding to each country of origin indicator. The dependent variable in Panel (a) is a literacy indicator, Panel (b) is the log of occupational earnings, and Panel (c) is an indicator of access to real estate property. Omitted category are sons of natives. Sources: Data are from the sample of linked census records, as described in the text and Online Appendix.

Figure 3 ECONOMIC OUTCOMES OF THE SECOND GENERATION, BY FATHER'S COUNTRY OF ORIGIN

How can we account for the advantages of second-generation immigrants? One possible interpretation is that the children of immigrants benefited from higher “ethnic capital” than the children of natives (Borjas Reference Borjas1992). According to the “ethnic capital” hypothesis, the human capital of a child is influenced not only by the human capital of her own parents, but also by the average human capital of the ethnic group to which the child belongs. As immigrants had on average higher human capital than natives, their children might have been able to take advantage of the higher human capital within their ethnic network. In Table B.4 in the Online Appendix, I formally test this possibility by re-estimating equation (2) including the average literacy rate of a child's father's country of birth, as measured among immigrants from that country in Argentina in 1869—as an additional variable. The table shows that, conditional on father's background characteristics, there is a positive association between the average literacy of the ethnic group in the father's generation and literacy rates and occupational earnings of the second-generation. Note that this evidence should be interpreted as only suggestive because of the well-known “reflection problem” (Manski Reference Manski1993) in measuring social interactions.

CONCLUSIONS

I provided evidence on the mobility and economic outcomes of European immigrants and their children in nineteenth-century Argentina. To do so, I constructed longitudinal data linking males across the two national censuses of population of the period and passenger ship lists of immigrant arrivals to the city of Buenos Aires.

I first looked at the labor market assimilation of first-generation immigrants. I found that immigrants exhibited faster occupational upgrading than natives. This finding does not seem to be driven by immigrants from any particular origin. Rather, I documented that immigrants from most of the main European sending countries outpaced natives in terms of occupational upgrading. Immigrants also appear to have in many cases upgraded their pre-migration occupations: Most of those entering the country as unskilled workers upgraded their occupation after a relatively short period of time. A comparison with similarly constructed U.S. data suggests that European immigrants in Argentina experienced relatively higher rates of upward occupational mobility.

Focusing on second-generation immigrants, I documented that the sons of European immigrants from every major sending country outperformed the sons of natives along a number of important economic outcomes. In addition, the majority of the sons of unskilled immigrant workers were able to upgrade their occupations, in many cases to white-collar jobs.

Overall, my findings give further support to an optimistic view of the economic performance of European immigrants in nineteenth-century Argentina. Furthermore, I showed that this optimism also largely extends to the second generation. These findings provide an economic rationale of why some Europeans chose to migrate to Argentina instead of to the United States. While real wages were likely lower in Argentina (Williamson Reference Williamson1995), the prospects for upward economic mobility might have been better.

In comparing the experiences of Italians in Argentina and in the United States, Herbert S. Klein (Reference Klein1983) argues that “The sharp differences in the Italian immigrant experience within Argentina and the United States were fully perceived by both the immigrants themselves and virtually all contemporary observers.” But why did these differences exist? My article cannot offer a definite answer to this question. One plausible interpretation points to differences in the social structure of the two countries at the onset of Mass Migration. When the Age of Mass Migration started, Argentina had a relatively small population and no significant skilled working class. In contrast, the United States featured a larger and more skilled workforce (Baily Reference Baily1983). Hence, immigrants moving to Argentina were in a better position to become a dominant force of the economy than those going to the United States.

Footnotes

I have benefited from comments from Ran Abramitzky, Carolina Biernat, Arun Chandrasekhar, Melanie Morten, Gavin Wright, and two anonymous referees, as well as several participants in the Stanford Economic History seminar. I am also grateful to Enrique Pérez, Mercedes Pérez, Fernanda Righi, Mariana Righi, Lisandro Vaccaro, and María Fabiana Vaccaro for helping me with data collection and to Fiona Stewart for proofreading. This article benefited from funding from the Stanford University Economics Department; the Economic History Association through the Exploratory Data and Travel Grant and the Dissertation Fellowship; the Graduate Student Fellowships in International Development through a grant from the Stanford Center for International Development; and the Leonard W. Ely and Shirley R. Ely Graduate Student Fund Fellowship.

1 For instance, Szuchman (Reference Szuchman1981) argues that “Argentines never rejected the belief that their society represented an open system of economic opportunities proven by the upwardly mobile population.”

2 See, for example, Baily (Reference Baily1983), Conde (Reference Conde1979), Diaz-Alejandro (Reference Diaz-Alejandro1970), and Klein (Reference Klein1983) among others.

3 In 1869, the literacy rate among males over 18 years old was 26 percent for natives and 61 percent for immigrants. I estimated that the typical sending country had a per capita GDP that ranged from 80 to 120 percent that of Argentina in the 1875–1890 period and about 60 percent in the 1890–1914 period. In the United States, this figure ranged from 40 to 60 percent in 1875–1890 and 40 to 50 percent in 1890–1914. Own elaboration based on Dirección General de Inmigración (1925), Ferenczi (Reference Ferenczi1929), and Maddison (Reference Maddison2007).

4 See Devoto and Benencia (Reference Devoto and Benencia2003) for an overview of the history of immigration to Argentina. See Taylor (Reference Taylor, Hatton and Williamson1994) for a comparison between mass migration to Argentina and Australia.

5 Other studies on specific immigrant communities include Míguez' (Reference Manski1993) on the Province of Buenos Aires, Otero's (Reference Otero1994) study on French immigrants in the city of Tandil, and Tolcachier's (Reference Tolcachier1995) study on Israeli immigrants.

6 These are the only two national censuses of Argentina for which individual records with names are available. The next national census took place in 1914. Unfortunately, the individual records of this census were lost, so it is not possible to extend the sample ahead in time.

7 Because the 1869 census lacks information on relationship to head of household, I used a procedure similar to the one used by IPUMS to identify fathers and sons. See the Online Appendix for further details.

8 This decision rule is analogous to the one used by Mill and Stein (Reference Mill and Stein2012), Parman (Reference Parman2015), and Feigenbaum (Reference Feigenbaum2016, Reference Feigenbaum2017).

9 While immigrants are expected to have a lower matching rate because of return migration, they also resided in areas of Argentina with relatively lower mortality levels. For instance, natives born in Buenos Aires and aged 18 to 35 years old exhibited a 25 percent mortality rate from 1869 to 1895, whereas the average native exhibited a mortality rate above 40 percent during the same time period. In addition, European immigrants had substantially higher literacy levels, implying that their identifying information is likely to be reported with less error.

10 To be included in the sample, an individual had to be: (1) aged 18 to 60 years old upon arrival and (2) 60 years old or less by 1895.

11 Passenger lists started to be systematically collected following the 1876 Immigration Law, but all the individual records prior to 1881 have been lost. Then, unlike Ferrie (Reference Ferrie1997), I am unfortunately unable to observe an immigrant both in the 1869 and 1895 censuses and in the passenger lists.

12 Because some of the name changes are predictable—for instance, Italian immigrants named Giuseppe adopted the name José—I am able to partially address this issue by performing the linking based on a Spanish version of the first name. Further details are provided in the Online Data Appendix.

13 Abramitzky, Boustan, and Eriksson (Reference Abramitzky, Leah and Eriksson2014) use median wages by occupation constructed from the 1950 U.S. census and mean wages from the Cost of Living Survey of 1901 to construct occupational earnings in the 1900, 1910, and 1920 censuses. Collins and Wanamaker (Reference Collins and Wanamaker2014) construct occupational earnings by adjusting industry wages by demographic characteristics and location.

14 This approach is followed by Ferrie (Reference Ferrie1997, 1999), Long and Ferrie (Reference Long and Ferrie2013), Abramitzky, Boustan, and Eriksson (Reference Abramitzky, Leah and Eriksson2014), among other researchers.

15 Butcher and DiNardo (Reference Butcher and DiNardo2002) argue that, because immigrants and natives might exhibit different skill levels, changes in the returns to skills will result in changes in immigrants' relative economic standing, even in the absence of “true” assimilation.

16 The Altham (Reference Altham1970) statistic is based on the relative odds of individuals in different occupations in 1869 find a given a job in 1895. Under conditions of perfect mobility, the relative odds are one: an occupation does not provide any relative advantage in obtaining a given occupation. More generally, given two matrices P and Q, the Altham statistic d(P,Q) measures the difference in the strength of their row-column association. Importantly, it is possible to perform a likelihood-ratio test to assess whether this difference is significantly different from zero.

17 I also computed d(P,Q) i , which measures the row-column association in matrices P and Q while excluding the elements in the main diagonal of the matrix. Using this alternative measure, I also find higher mobility among immigrants than among natives, although the difference is now less stark.

18 Since it is not possible to follow cohorts of immigrants over time, the composition bias in this context also differs from the one that would arise when using U.S. data. In particular, a comparison of my results with those estimated in the repeated cross-section would not be informative about the selection of return migrants, but rather about the net change in the composition of the immigrant pool from 1869 to 1895.

19 The results in this specification should be interpreted with caution, as place of residence is an endogenous choice. Indeed, geographic mobility might be a strategy for occupational upgrading. I note, however, that the results (not reported) are also similar if I instead interact the department of residence fixed effects based on place of residence in 1869 with the 1895-year indicator.

20 As the 1869 census lacks a question on access to property, I cannot directly use the property variable as the outcome.

21 The correlation between this measure and my measure of occupational earnings is of about 0.7 in the data.

22 To compute the sample weights, I pool the 1895 census cross-section and the linked sample and estimate a probit model of the probability of being an observation in the linked sample. I then reweight my sample by the inverse of this linkage probability.

23 I define a perfect match as one in which both the first name and the last name agree perfectly, but I allow the year of birth to differ by at most one year. Because the two censuses took place in different times of the year, the difference in estimated year of birth could be one even if an individual accurately reported his age in both censuses.

24 The results are also similar if I (1) keep only natives with infrequent names and keep all the immigrants, (2) keep only natives who are perfect matches and keep all the immigrants, (3) drop both immigrants and natives with common names, and (4) drop both immigrants and natives who are not exact matches (results not reported).

25 A limitation of these data is that the accuracy of the occupation declared upon arrival has been questioned. The main issue is that immigrants might have answered their intended occupation in Argentina rather than their last occupation in Europe. According to Devoto and Benencia (Reference Devoto and Benencia2003), the most likely bias is that immigrants declared occupations that they deemed would be perceived as desirable by the Argentine authorities. If immigrants indeed exaggerated the quality of their occupations in Europe upon arrival, then the rates of upward occupational mobility that I document would likely be a lower bound.

26 For instance, the fraction of British and German immigrants moving out of unskilled occupations was about 60 percent in the United States (Ferrie Reference Ferrie1997).

27 In Table B.2 in the Online Appendix, I show that this pattern was similar for Italian and Spanish immigrants, the two largest sending countries. The sample size does not allow me to perform a similar comparison for the other sending countries.

28 I observe a similar pattern when I restrict the sample to individuals initially residing in the Provinces of Buenos Aires, Entre Ríos, and Santa Fe, where most European immigrants and their children resided. See Table B.3 in the Online Appendix.

29 Feigenbaum (forthcoming) documents a similar pattern of higher mobility of the grandchildren of immigrants relative to the grandchildren of natives in early twentieth-century Iowa.

30 The results are similar if instead of occupational category indicators I include occupational earnings as a control variable.

31 There were 3,045 different enumerators in the 1869 census, each covering about 600 individuals.

References

REFERENCES

Abramitzky, Ran, Leah, Platt Boustan, and Eriksson, Katherine. “Europe's Tired, Poor, Huddled Masses: Self-Selection and Economic Outcomes in the Age of Mass Migration.” American Economic Review 102, no. 5 (2012): 1832–56.Google Scholar
Abramitzky, Ran, Leah, Platt Boustan, and Eriksson, Katherine. “Have the Poor Always Been Less Likely to Migrate? Evidence from Inheritance Practices During the Age of Mass Migration.” Journal of Development Economics 102 (2013): 214.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Abramitzky, Ran, Leah, Platt Boustan, and Eriksson, Katherine. “A Nation of Immigrants: Assimilation and Economic Outcomes in the Age of Mass Migration.” Journal of Political Economy 122, no. 3 (2014): 467506.Google Scholar
Alberdi, Juan Bautista. Bases Y Puntos de Partida Para La Organización Política de La República Argentina, 1852.Google Scholar
Alsina, Juan A. “La Inmigración Europea En La República Argentina” Imprenta Calle México, 1898.Google Scholar
Altham, Patricia M.E.The Measurement of Association of Rows and Columns for an r x s Contingency Table.” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series B (Methodological) 32, no. 1 (1970): 6373.Google Scholar
Argentina. Dirección General de Estadística. Anuario de la Dirección General de Estadística. Compañía sud-americana de billetes de banco, 1908.Google Scholar
Álvarez, Beatriz, and Alberto Nicolini, Esteban. “Income Inequality in the North-West of Argentina During the First Globalization. Methodology and Preliminary Results.” Ponencia Presentada En II Encuentro Anual de La Asociación Española de Historia Económica. Madrid 8, (2010).Google Scholar
Baily, Samuel L.The Adjustment of Italian Immigrants in Buenos Aires and New York, 1870–1914.” American Historical Review 88, no. 2 (1983): 281305.Google Scholar
Borjas, George J.Assimilation, Changes in Cohort Quality, and the Earnings of Immigrants.” Journal of Labor Economics 3, no. 4 (1985): 463–89.Google Scholar
Borjas, George J.Ethnic Capital and Intergenerational Mobility.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 107, no. 1 (1992): 123–50.Google Scholar
Boustan, Leah Platt, Kahn, Matthew E., and Rhode, Paul W.. “Moving to Higher Ground: Migration Response to Natural Disasters in the Early Twentieth Century.” American Economic Review 102, no. 3 (2012): 238–44.Google Scholar
Buchanan, William I.La Moneda Y La Vida En La República Argentina.” Cuadernos Del CISH 3, no. 4 (1998): 239256.Google Scholar
Butcher, Kristin F., and DiNardo, John. “The Immigrant and Native-Born Wage Distributions: Evidence from United States Censuses.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 56, no. 1 (2002): 97121.Google Scholar
Chiswick, Barry R.The Effect of Americanization on the Earnings of Foreign-Born Men.” Journal of Political Economy 86, no. 5 (1978): 897921.Google Scholar
Collins, William J., and Wanamaker, Marianne H.. “Selection and Economic Gains in the Great Migration of African Americans: New Evidence from Linked Census Data.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 6, no. 1 (2014): 220–52.Google Scholar
Collins, William J., and Wanamaker, Marianne H.. “The Great Migration in Black and White: New Evidence on the Selection and Sorting of Southern Migrants.” Journal of Economic History 75, no. 4 (2015): 947–92.Google Scholar
Collins, William J., and Wanamaker, Marianne H.. “Up from Slavery? Intergenerational Mobility in the Shadow of Jim Crow.” NBER Working Paper No. w23395, Cambridge, MA, 2017.Google Scholar
Conde, Roberto Cortés. El Progreso Argentino: 1880–1914. Buenos Aires: Editorial Sudamericana, 1979.Google Scholar
Correa, Antonio M., and Lahitte, Emilio. “Investigación Parlamentaria Sobre Agricultura, Ganadería, Industrias Derivadas Y Colonización.” Anexo B, Buenos Aires. (1898).Google Scholar
Da Orden, María Liliana. Inmigración Española, Familia Y Movilidad Social En La Argentina Moderna: Una Mirada Desde Mar Del Plata (1890–1930). Colección La Argentina Plural. Buenos Aires: Biblos, 2005.Google Scholar
Devoto, Fernando, and Benencia, Roberto. Historia de La Inmigración En La Argentina. Buenos Aires: Sudamericana, 2003.Google Scholar
Diaz-Alejandro, Carlos F. Essays on the Economic History of the Argentine Republic. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1970.Google Scholar
Dirección General de Inmigración. Resumen Estadístico Del Movimiento Migratorio En La República Argentina: Años 1857–1924. Talleres Gráficos del Ministerio de Agricultura de la Nación, 1925.Google Scholar
Feigenbaum, James J.Multiple Measures of Historical Intergenerational Mobility: Iowa 1915 to 1940.” Economic Journal, forthcoming.Google Scholar
Feigenbaum, James J.Intergenerational Mobility during the Great Depression.” Mimeo, 2016.Google Scholar
Feigenbaum, James J.Automated Census Record Linking: A Machine Learning Approach.” Mimeo, 2017.Google Scholar
Ferenczi, Imre. “International Migration Statistics.” In International Migrations, Volume I: Statistics, 4776. Cambridge, MA: NBER, 1929.Google Scholar
Ferrie, Joseph P.The Entry into the U.S Labor Market of Antebellum European Immigrants, 1840–1860.” Explorations in Economic History 34, no. 3 (1997): 295330.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferrie, Joseph P. Yankeys Now: Immigrants in the Antebellum United States 1840–1860. New York: Oxford University Press, 1999.Google Scholar
Fuente, Diego Gregorio de la. Segundo Censo de La República Argentina, Mayo 10 de 1895. Vol. 3. Taller tip. de la Penitenciaria nacional, 1898.Google Scholar
Germani, Gino. “Mass Immigration and Modernization in Argentina.” Studies in Comparative International Development (SCID) 2, no. 11 (1966): 165–82.Google Scholar
Klein, Herbert S. 1983. “The Integration of Italian Immigrants into the United States and Argentina: A Comparative Analysis.” The American Historical Review 88, no. 2 (1983): 306–29.Google Scholar
Kosack, Edward, and Ward, Zachary. “Who Crossed the Border? Self-Selection of Mexican Migrants in the Early Twentieth Century.” Journal of Economic History 74, no. 4 (2014): 1015–44.Google Scholar
Long, Jason. “Rural-Urban Migration and Socioeconomic Mobility in Victorian Britain.” Journal of Economic History 65, no. 1 (2005): 135.Google Scholar
Long, Jason, and Ferrie, Joseph. “Intergenerational Occupational Mobility in Great Britain and the United States Since 1850.” American Economic Review 103, no. 4 (2013): 1109–37.Google Scholar
Lubotsky, Darren. “Chutes or Ladders? A Longitudinal Analysis of Immigrant Earnings.” Journal of Political Economy 115, no. 5 (2007): 820–67.Google Scholar
Maas, Ineke, Miles, Andrew, and Van Leeuwen, Marco H.D.. HISCO: Historical International Standard Classification of Occupations. Leuven, Belgium: Leuven University Press, 2002.Google Scholar
Maddison, Angus. The World Economy Volume 1: A Millennial Perspective, Volume 2: Historical Statistics. New Delhi: Academic Foundation, 2007.Google Scholar
Manski, Charles F.Identification of Endogenous Social Effects: The Reflection Problem.” Review of Economic Studies 60, no. 3 (1993): 531–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mill, Roy, and Stein, Luke CD. “Race, Skin Color, and Economic Outcomes in Early Twentieth-Century America.” Working Paper, Stanford University, Stanford, CA, 30 December 2012.Google Scholar
Minns, Chris. “Income, Cohort Effects, and Occupational Mobility: A New Look at Immigration to the United States at the Turn of the 20th Century.” Explorations in Economic History 37, no. 4 (2000): 326–50.Google Scholar
Míguez, Eduardo José. 1993. “La Movilidad Social de Nativos E Inmigrantes En La Frontera Bonaerense En El Siglo Xix: Datos, Problemas, Perspectivas.” Estudios Migratorios Latinoamericanos 8, no. 24 (1993): 139–70.Google Scholar
Otero, Hernán. “Redes Sociales Primarias, Movilidad Espacial E Inserción Social de Los Inmigrantes En La Argentina. Los Franceses de Tandil, 1850–1914.” Estudios Migratorios Latinoamericanos 9, no. 28 (1994): 521–48.Google Scholar
Parman, John. “Childhood Health and Sibling Outcomes: Nurture Reinforcing Nature during the 1918 Influenza Pandemic.” Explorations in Economic History 58, issue C (2015): 2243.Google Scholar
Pérez, Santiago. “The (South) American Dream: Mobility and Economic Outcomes of First- and Second-Generation Immigrants in 19th-Century Argentina.” Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research [distributor], 2017. Available at http://doi.org/10.3886/E100880V2.Google Scholar
Salisbury, Laura. “Selective Migration, Wages, and Occupational Mobility in Nineteenth Century America.” Explorations in Economic History 53, issue C (2014): 4063.Google Scholar
Sánchez-Alonso, Blanca. “The Other Europeans: Immigration into Latin America and the International Labour Market (1870–1930).” Revista de Historia Económica/Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History (Second Series) 25, no. 3 (2007): 395426.Google Scholar
Sofer, Eugene F. From Pale to Pampa: A Social History of the Jews of Buenos Aires. New York: Holmes and Meier, 1982.Google Scholar
Somoza, Jorge L. Muestras de Los Dos Primeros Censos Nacionales de Población, 1869 Y 1895. 46. Buenos Aries: Instituto Torcuato Di Tella, Centro de Investigaciones Sociales, 1967.Google Scholar
Szuchman, Mark. Mobility and Integration in Urban Argentina: Córdoba in the Liberal Era. Austin, TX: University of Texas Press, 1981.Google Scholar
Taylor, Alan M.Mass Migration to Distant Southern Shores.” In Migration and the International Labor Market, 1850–1939, edited by Hatton, Tim and Williamson, Jeffrey, 91115. London, UK: Psychology Press, 1994.Google Scholar
Tolcachier, Fabiana Sabina. “Movilidad Socio-Ocupacional de Los Israelitas En El Partido de Villarino, 1905–1950.” Estudios Migratorios Latinoamericanos 10, no. 31 (1995): 633–72.Google Scholar
Williamson, Jeffrey G.The Evolution of Global Labor Markets Since 1830: Background Evidence and Hypotheses.” Explorations in Economic History 32, no. 2 (1995): 141–96.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1 NUMBER OF NEW IMMIGRANT ARRIVALS, 1857–1900

Source: Argentina, Anuario de la Dirección General de Estadística (1908).
Figure 1

Table 1 FREQUENT OCCUPATIONS, 1895 CENSUS

Figure 2

Table 2 OCCUPATIONAL MOBILITY OF NATIVES AND IMMIGRANTS, 1869 (ROWS) AND 1895 (COLUMNS)

Figure 3

Table 3 OCCUPATIONAL EARNINGS REGRESSIONS

Figure 4

Figure 2 OCCUPATIONAL EARNINGS REGRESSION, BY COUNTRY OF ORIGIN

Notes: I estimate a version of equation (1) in which I replace the Immigrant indicator with separate indicators for each of the countries included in my sample, as well as an interaction of each of these country indicators with an 1895 census indicator. This figure shows the estimated coefficient around a 95 percent confidence interval corresponding to each country of origin indicator and the coefficient corresponding to the interaction between the country of origin indicator and the 1895 census indicator. Omitted category are natives.Sources: Data are from the sample of linked census records, as described in the text and Online Appendix.
Figure 5

Table 4 OCCUPATIONAL EARNINGS REGRESSIONS, ROBUSTNESS

Figure 6

Table 5 OCCUPATIONAL MOBILITY OF IMMIGRANTS, DECLARED UPON ARRIVAL (ROWS) AND IN 1895 CENSUS (COLUMNS)

Figure 7

Table 6 INTERGENERATIONAL MOBILITY OF CHILDREN OF NATIVES AND IMMIGRANTS, FATHERS IN 1869 (ROWS) AND SONS IN 1895 (COLUMNS)

Figure 8

Table 7 ECONOMIC OUTCOMES OF THE SECOND GENERATION

Figure 9

Figure 3 ECONOMIC OUTCOMES OF THE SECOND GENERATION, BY FATHER'S COUNTRY OF ORIGIN

Notes: I estimate a version of equation (2) in the main text in which I replace the Second Generation indicator with separate indicator variables for each of the countries included my sample. The figure shows the estimated coefficient around a 95 percent confidence interval corresponding to each country of origin indicator. The dependent variable in Panel (a) is a literacy indicator, Panel (b) is the log of occupational earnings, and Panel (c) is an indicator of access to real estate property. Omitted category are sons of natives.Sources: Data are from the sample of linked census records, as described in the text and Online Appendix.
Supplementary material: File

Pérez supplementary material

Online Appendix

Download Pérez supplementary material(File)
File 7.5 MB