Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-2lccl Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-28T09:57:39.530Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Fixed Capital in the Industrial Revolution in Britain*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 February 2011

Sidney Pollard
Affiliation:
University of Sheffield

Extract

The provision of capital is generally recognized to be one of the main problems of countries undergoing the process of industrialization. This is true also of the special case of Great Britain, the first country to experience an industrial revolution. In the British case, however, it is important to note that much capital had been accumulated even before the 1760's, the decade when industrial growth began to accelerate and to change its direction. Most of this earlier capital was invested in commerce, in finance, in farming, and in stocks of manufactured goods and raw materials, and what was noteworthy in the next two generations was, not so much the absolute (and probably also relative) growth in the quantity of capital, but a change in its composition: the emergence, for the first time, of large concentrations of fixed capital.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The Economic History Association 1964

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Deane, Phyllis and Cole, W. A., British Economic Growth 1688–1959 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1962), pp. 259–63Google Scholar.

2 For example, Weber, Max, General Economic History (Glencoe: Free Press, 1950), pp. 163, 173–74Google Scholar; Lord, John, Capital and Steam Power (London: King & Son, 1923), p. 62Google Scholar.

3 See my Capital Accounting in the Industrial Revolution,” Yorkshire Bulletin of Economic and Social Research, XV, No. 2 (Nov. 1963), 7591Google Scholar.

4 For example, Wilson, Charles, “The Entrepreneur in the Industrial Revolution in Britain,” History, XLII (June 1957), 115Google Scholar.

5 Adam Smith's belief that joint-stock organization was suitable only for canals, waterworks, banks, and insurance companies, and his reasons for it, are well known. Adam Smith, Wealth of Nations, Book V, ch. i, Part III, Art. I.

6 Examples are Wadsworth, A. P. and Mann, J. DeL., The Cotton Trade and Industrial Lancashire (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1931), p. 489Google Scholar; Heaton, Herbert, “Financing the Industrial Revolution,” Bulletin of the Business Historical Society, XI (Feb. 1937), 2Google Scholar; Select Committee on Manufactures, Commerce and Shipping, Parliamentary Papers, 1833, VI, ev. Henry Houldsworth, Q. 5303–4; Wooster, Henry A., “Manufacturer and Artisan, 1790–1840,” Journal of Political Economy, XXXIV (Feb. 1926), 6162CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Unwin, G., Samuel Oldknow and the Arkwrights (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1924), pp. 147–49Google Scholar; Pigott, S., Hollins, a Study of Industry, 1784–1949 (Nottingham: Hollins, 1949), p. 63Google Scholar.

7 See Donald, M. B., Elizabethan Copper, The History of the Company of the Mines Royal 1568–1605 (London: Pergamon Press, 1955), p. 244Google Scholar; also his Elizabethan Monopolies. The History of the Company of Mineral and Battery Works from 1565 to 1604 (Edinburgh and London: Oliver & Boyd, 1961) p. 75Google Scholar; Bouch, C. M. C. and Jones, G. P., A Short Economic and Social History of the Lake Counties, 1500–1830 (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1961), p. 126Google Scholar; John, D. Glyn, “Contributions to the Economic History of South Wales,” Part I (unpublished D.Sc. Thesis, University of Wales, 1930), p. 4 and appendixGoogle Scholar.

8 Flinn, M. W., Men of Iron, the Crowleys in the Early Iron Industry (Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press, 1962), pp. 174–75Google Scholar; Raistrick, A., Quakers in Science and Industry (London: Bannisdale, 1950), p. 98Google Scholar; also Dynasty of Ironfounders, the Darbys and Coalbrookdale (London: Longmans, 1953), p. 61Google Scholar; Unwin, Oldknow, p. 24; Chaloner, W. H., “Charles Roe of Macclesfield (1715–81): An Eighteenth-Century Industrialist,” Part I, Trans, of the Lancashire and Cheshire Antiquarian Society, LXII (1953), p. 138Google Scholar; Wadsworth and Mann, Cotton Trade, p. 290; Mathias, Peter, The Brewing Industry in England, 1700–1830 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1959), especially pp. 63, 77, 79, 474, 556–58Google Scholar. To arrive at these figures, all doubtful items were included in “fixed capital.” James Steuart and Adam Smith both assumed the capital needs of the “manufacturer” (as distinct from the merchant) to be small: Wealth of Nations (Cannan ed. 1904), I, 325; SirSteuart, James, An Inquiry into the Principles of Political Oeconomy (1767), II, 137Google Scholar.

9 Fong, H. D., Triumph of the Factory System in England (Tientsin: Chihli Press, 1930), pp. 40, 41Google Scholar; Factories Inquiry Commission, First Report, Parliamentary Papers, 1833, XX, ev. Pooley; S. C. on Manufactures, 1833, ev. Henry Houldsworth, Q. 5303–4.

10 Baines, Edward Jr., History of the Cotton Manufacture in Great Britain (1835), pp. 401, 412–14Google Scholar; Fong, Factory System p. 42; Factories Inquiry Commission, First Report, D 2, appendix A, p. 34, R. H. Greg; Blaug, M., “The Productivity of Capital in the Lancashire Cotton Industry During the Nineteenth Century,” Economic History Review, 2d Series, XIII (Apr. 1961), p. 359Google Scholar; Montgomery, J., The Theory and Practice of Cotton Spinning (Glasgow, 1833), p. 281Google Scholar; S. C. on Manufactures, 1833, ev. Joshua Milne, Q. 11070.

11 Crump, W. B., ed., The Leeds Woollen Industry, 1780–1820 (Leeds: Thoresby Society, 1931), p. 257Google Scholar; Rimmer, W. G., Marshalls of Leeds, Flax Spinners 1788–1886 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1960), pp. 39, 43–44, 313Google Scholar; Marshall Papers (Ms., Brotherton Library, Leeds), Book 2 (“Leeds Mill, 1804”), Book 3 (“Shrewsbury Accounts, 1806”).

12 Ashton, T. S., Iron and Steel in the Industrial Revolution (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1924), p. 163Google Scholar; Garner, S. Paul, Evolution of Cost Accounting to 1925 (University of Alabama Press, 1954), p. 28Google Scholar; Edwards, R. S., “Some Notes on the Early Literature and Development of Cost Accounting in Great Britain,” The Accountant, XCVII (June-Dec. 1937), 193Google Scholar.

13 Possibly based on Anthony Hill's statement that invested capital (of all kinds) in the iron trade amounted to four times the annual turnover. S. C. on Manufactures, 1833, ev. Hill, Q. 10402.

14 Campbell, R. H., “The Financing of Carron Company,” Business History, I (Dec. 1958), 26, 27Google Scholar. Compare pp. 312–13.

15 Cyfarthfa Mss. (National Library of Wales, Aberystwyth), Box 12, Balance Sheet 30 June, 1812.

16 Mona Mine Mss. (University College of North Wales, Bangor), Nos. 166, 3039, 3048; Boulton & Watt Accounts, Ms. (Assay Office, Birmingham), “M. Boulton, Inventory,” 22 June 1782; Boulton & Watt Accounts, etc. Ms. (Birmingham Central Library), Inventory Books, 1822–1831; Neville Mss. (National Library of Wales, Aberystwyth), No. 20; Pontrhydyrun [Tin] Works Mss. (Cardiff Public Library), Account Book.

17 Payne, Peter L., “The Govan Collieries, 1804–1805,” Business History, III (June 1961), 8789Google Scholar.

18 Westworth, O. A., “The Albion Steam Flour Mill,” Economic History, II (Jan. 1932), 383Google Scholar.

19 Compare my paper on “Capital Accounting.”

20 Crump, Leeds Woollen Industry, p. 255; Gott Papers, Ms. (Brotherton Library, Leeds), Box VI, Annual Statements of Partnership Accounts, 1 Jan. 1796; Flinn, Men of Iron, pp. 174–75.

21 Francis, George Grant, The Smelting of Copper in the Swansea District (2d ed., 1881), pp. 106–8Google Scholar; Barker, T. C. and Harris, J. R., A Merseyside Town in the Industrial Revolution: St. Helens, 1750–1900 (Liverpool: Liverpool University Press, 1954), p. 121Google Scholar; Pontrhydyrun Account Book; Mona Mine Mss., Nos. 3039, 3048; Raistrick, Dynasty, pp. 277–78; Archibald, and Clow, Nan L., The Chemical Revolution, A Contribution to Social Technology (London: Batchworth, 1952), p. 288Google Scholar.

22 Hower, Ralph M., “The Wedgwoods, Ten Generations of Potters,” Journal of Economic and Business History, IV (Feb. 1932), 672–73Google Scholar; Raistrick, Dynasty, pp. 214–15.

23 Heaton, “Financing” (cited in n. 6), especially pp. 2–5, 10.

24 Hartwell, R. M., “The Yorkshire Woollen and Worsted Industry, 1800–1850” (unpublished D. Phil. Thesis, Oxford, 1955)Google Scholar, especially pp. 371, 373, 623, 660.

25 Ibid. p. 11.

26 For example, Ashton, T. S., The Industrial Revolution 1760–1830 (London: Oxford University Press, 1946), pp. 105–6Google Scholar, and An Eighteenth-Century Industrialist, Peter Stubs of Warrington 1756–1806 (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1939), p. 116Google Scholar; Court, W. H. B., Concise Economic History of Britain from 1750 to Recent Times (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1954), pp. 9192Google Scholar; Pressnell, L. S., Country Banking in the Industrial Revolution (Oxford: Clarendon, 1956), ch. xGoogle Scholar. The best recent discussion of this and some related points touched upon in this paper will be found in an essay by F. Crouzet, “La Formation du Capital en Grande-Bretagne pendant la Révolution Industrielle,” unpublished at the time of writing but to appear shortly in the Proceedings of the Second International Economic History Conference, held at Aix-en-Provence in 1962.

27 Habakkuk, H. J., American and British Technology in the Nineteenth Century (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1962), p. 175Google Scholar.

28 Court, W. H. B., “A Warwickshire Colliery in the Eighteenth Century,” Economic History Review, VII (May 1937), 227Google Scholar; Addis, John P., The Crawshay Dynasty, a Study in Industrial Organisation and. Development, 1765–1867 (Cardiff: University of Wales Press, 1957), p. 156Google Scholar.

29 Flinn, Men of Iron, p. 175.

30 “The Rate of Interest in the Eighteenth Century,” in Pressnell, L. S., Studies in the Industrial Revolution (London: Athlone Press, 1960), p. 199Google Scholar.

31 Ashton, T. S., An Economic History of England, The Eighteenth Century (London: Methuen, 1955), pp. 2629Google Scholar; Hughes, J. R. T., Fluctuations in Trade Industry and Finance, (Oxford: Clarendon, 1960), pp. 266–68Google Scholar.

32 Heaton, “Financing,” p. 5.

33 Owen, Robert, Life of Owen, by Himself (London: Bell, 1920 ed.), p. 31Google Scholar.

34 John, A. H., ed., The Walker Family, Ironfounders and Lead Manufacturers, 1741–1893 (London: Business Archives Council, 1951), p. vGoogle Scholar; Williams, L. J., “The Welsh Tinplate Trade in the Mid-Eighteenth Century,” Economic History Review, 2d series, XIII (Apr. 1961), 447Google Scholar; Allen, G. C., “An Eighteenth Century Combination in the Copper-Mining Industry,” Economic Journal, XXXIII (Mar. 1923), 80Google Scholar.

35 For example, Dunn, Matthias, View of the Coal Trade of the North of England (Newcastle-upon-Tyne, 1844), p. 151Google Scholar. Credit by bills became so regular that manufacturers and traders were wont to pay at irregular intervals by bills covering only approximately the outstanding debts, thus carrying debits and credits in their ledgers for years without ever exactly balancing their accounts with customers and suppliers: Ashton, Peter Stubs, p. 111.

36 This problem is treated at length in my article quoted above, and therefore only touched upon here.

37 Heaton, “Financing,” p. 4.

38 Cule, J. E., “The Financial History of Matthew Boulton, 1759–1800” (unpublished M. Com. Thesis, Birmingham, 1935), especially pp. 89, 21–22, 44, 63Google Scholar; and Finance and Industry in the Eighteenth Century: The Firm of Boulton and Watt,” Economic History, IV (Feb. 1940), 320–22Google Scholar; Boulton & Watt Mss. (Birmingham Assay Office), Boulton to J. H. Ebbinghaus, 18 Nov. 1767, 2d March 1768; Campbell, “Financing of Carron Co.,” pp. 22 ff. and Carron Company (Edinburgh and London: Oliver & Boyd, 1961), pp. 123 ff.Google Scholar; Dickinson, H. W., Matthew Boulton (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1937), p. 109Google Scholar.

39 For an earlier example, see Moller, Asta, “Coal Mining in the Seventeenth Century,” Trans. of the Royal Historical Society, 4th Series, VIII (1925), 87Google Scholar.

40 Wedgwood was subject to the same factors with similar consequences.