Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-89wxm Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-05T10:47:31.638Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Taking “All Men Are Created Equal” Seriously: Toward a Metric for the Intergroup Comparison of Utility Functions Through Life Values

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 January 2015

David Courard-Hauri
Affiliation:
Drake University
Stephen A. Lauer
Affiliation:
Iowa State University
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

The use of wage differential techniques to estimate the value of a statistical life (VSL) leads to the conclusion that willingness to pay for risk reduction increases with income. However, the use of this result in policy-relevant calculations, such as benefit-cost analysis, has led to criticism among ethicists and the lay public, at the same time as it has been defended in the economic literature. In this paper, we argue that differential valuation measures not a differential value that individuals place upon their own lives, but a differential value that they place upon marginal economic resources. Using two sets of VSL estimates from metastudies, we provide an initial estimate of the relative marginal value of income, allowing interpersonal comparison at the societal level. With these results, we propose an empirically determined, ethically justifiable social welfare function that can be easily incorporated into benefit-cost analysis and that has important implications for development economics, although more work is necessary to provide a robust estimate.

Type
Article
Copyright
Copyright © Society for Benefit-Cost Analysis 2012

References

Adler, M. D. (2008): “Risk equity: A new proposal,” Harvard Environmental Law Review, 32, 147.Google Scholar
Adler, M. D. and Posner, E. A. (2006): New Foundations of Cost-Benefit Analysis, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alberini, A. and Chiabai, A. (2006): “Urban environmental health and sensitive populations: How much are the Italians willing to pay to reduce their risks?ERSA conference papers, European Regional Science Association, URL http://ideas.repec.org/p/wiw/wiwrsa/ersa06p293.html.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alberini, A., Cropper, M., Krupnick, A., and Simon, N. B. (2004): “Does the value of a statistical life vary with age and health status? Evidence from the US and Canada,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 48, 769792.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alberini, A., Scasny, M., and Kohlova, M. B. (2005): “The value of a statistical life in the Czech Republic: Evidence from a contingent valuation study,” EAERE conference papers, European Association of Environmental and Resource Economists annual meeting.Google Scholar
Alberini, A., Tonin, S., Turvani, M., and Chiabai, A. (2007): “Paying for permanence: Public preferences for contaminated site cleanup,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 34, 155178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aldred, J. (2009): The Skeptical Economist, Sterling, VA: Earthscan.Google Scholar
Arabsheibani, G. and Marin, A. (2000): “Stability of estimates of the compensation for danger,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 20, 247269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baranzini, A. and Luzzi, G. F. (2001): “The economic value of risks to life: Evidence from the Swiss labour market,” Swiss Society of Economics and Statistics, 137, 149170.Google Scholar
Bengston, V. L., Cuellar, J. B., and Ragan, P. K. (1977): “Stratum contrasts and similarities in attitudes toward death,” Journal of Gerontology, 32, 7688.Google Scholar
Berger, M. and Gabriel, P. (1991): “Risk aversion and the earnings of U.S. immigrants and natives,” Applied Economics, 23, 311318.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bhattacharya, S., Alberini, A., and Cropper, M. L. (2007): “The value of mortality risk reductions in Delhi, India,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 34, 2147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blackorby, C. and Donaldson, D. (1978): “Measures of relative equality and their meaning in terms of social welfare,” Journal of Economic Theory, 18, 5980.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boardman, A., Greenberg, D., Vining, A., and Weimer, D. (2010): Cost-Benefit Analysis, New York: Prentice Hall, fourth edition.Google Scholar
Bossert, W., Chakravarty, S., and D’Ambrosio, C. (2009): “Multidimensional poverty and material deprivation,” Technical Report Working Paper 129, ENCINEQ, Society for the Study of Economic Inequality.Google Scholar
Brent, R. J. (1984): “Use of distributional weights in cost-benefit analysis: A survey of schools,” Public Finance Review, 12, 213230.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brent, R. J. (1996): Applied Cost-Benefit Analysis, Brookfield, NY: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Brown, C. (1980): “Equalizing differences in the labor market,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 94, 113134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cameron, T. A. (2010): “Euthanizing the value of a statistical life,” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 4, 162178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chestnut, L. G., Rowe, R. D., and Brefle, W. S. (2011): “Economic valuation of mortality-risk reduction: Stated preference estimates from the United States and Canada,” Contemporary Economic Policy, doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7827.2011.00269.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, A., Frijters, P., and Shields, M. (2008): “Relative income, happiness, and utility: An explanation for the Easterlin Paradox and other puzzles,” Journal of Economic Literature, 46, 95144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corso, P. S., Hammitt, J. K., and Graham, J. D. (2001): “Valuing mortality-risk reduction: Using visual aids to improve the validity of contingent valuation,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 23, 165184.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cousineau, J.-M., Lacroix, R., and Girard, A.-M. (1992): “Occupational hazard and wage compensating differentials,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 74, 166169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cowell, F. A. and Gardiner, K. (1999): “Welfare weights,” Economics Research Paper 20, STICERD, London School of Economics.Google Scholar
Deaton, A. (2008): “Income, health, and well-being around the world: Evidence from the Gallup World Poll,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 22, 5372.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Desaigues, B., Rabl, A., Ami, D., Kene, B. M., Masson, S., Salomon, M.-A., and Santoni, L. (2007): “Monetary value of a life expectancy gain due to reduced air pollution: Lessons from a contingent valuation in France,” Revue d’Conomie Politique, 675698.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dikhanov, Y. (2005): “Trends in global income distribution, 1970–2000, and scenarios for 2015,” Human Development occasional papers HDOCPA-2005-08, United Nations Development Programme.Google Scholar
Dilingham, A. (1985): “The influence of risk variable definition on value-of-life estimates,” Economic Inquiry, 23, 277294.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dolan, P., Fujiwara, D., and Metcalfe, R. (2011): “A step towards valuing utility the marginal and cardinal way,” Technical report, Centre for Economic Performance Discussion Paper No 1062.Google Scholar
Dziegielewska, D. P. and Mendelsohn, R. (2005): “Valuing air quality in Poland,” Environmental and Resource Economics, 30, 131163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farrow, S. (2011): “Incorporating equity in regulatory and benefit-cost analysis using risk-based preferences,” Risk Analysis, 3, 902907.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fleurbaey, M. (2008): Fairness, Responsibility, and Welfare, New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foley, D. (1967): “Resource allocation and the public sector,” Yale Economic ssays, 7, 4598.Google Scholar
Frey, B. S. and Stutzer, A. (2002): Happiness and Economics, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Graham, J. D. (2007): “Saving lives through administrative law and economics,” University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 157, 395540.Google Scholar
Greenberg, D. H., Deitch, V., and Hamilton, G. (2010): “A synthesis of random assignment benefit-cost studies of welfare-to-work programs,” Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis, 1, Article 3.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guo, X., Haab, T. C., and Hammitt, J. K. (2006): “Contingent valuation and the economic value of air-pollution-related health risks in China,” 2006 Annual Meeting, July 23–26, Long Beach, CA 21366, American Agricultural Economics Association (New Name 2008: Agricultural and Applied Economics Association), URL http://ideas.repec.org/p/ags/aaea06/21366.html.Google Scholar
Guria, J., Leung, J., Jones-Lee, M., and Loomes, G. (2005): “The willingness to accept value of statistical life relative to the willingness to pay value: Evidence and policy implications,” Environmental and Resource Economics, 32, 113127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hammitt, J. K. and Liu, J.-T. (2004): “Effects of disease type and latency on the value of mortality risk,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 28, 7395.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hammitt, J. K. and Robinson, L. A. (2011): “The income elasticity of the value per statistical life: Transferring estimates between high and low income population,” Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis, 2, Article 1.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hammitt, J. K. and Treich, N. (2007): “Statistical vs. identified lives in benefit-cost analysis,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 35, 4566.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hammitt, J. K. and Zhou, Y. (2006): “The economic value of air-pollution-related health risks in China: A contingent valuation study,” Environmental Resources and Economics, 33, 399423.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harberger, A. C. (1978): “The use of distributional weights in social cost-benefit analysis,” Journal of Political Economy, 86, S87S120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harrington, W., Heinzerling, L., and Morgenstern, R. D. (2009): “Controversies surrounding regulatory impact analysis,” in Harrington, W., Heinzerling, L., and Morgenstern, R. D., eds., Reforming Regulatory Impact Analysis, Washington, DC: Resources For the Future Press, pp. 2032.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, J. C. (1977): “Non-linear social welfare functions: a rejoinder to Professor Sen,” in Butts, R. E. and Hintikka, J., eds., Foundational Problems in the Special Sciences, Boston, MA: D. Reidel Publishing Company, pp. 297302.Google Scholar
Herzog, H. Jr., and Schlottmann, A. (1990): “Valuing risk in the workplace: Market price, willingness to pay, and the optimal provision of safety,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 72, 463470.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
IPCC (1995): Climate Change 1995: Impacts, Adaptation, and Mitigation of Climate Change: Scientific-Technical Analysis. Contributions of Working Group II to the Second Assessment Report, New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Itaoka, K., Krupnick, A., Saito, A., and Akai, M. (2007): “Morbidity valuation with a cessation lag: Choice experiments for public- and private-goods contexts in Japan,” Discussion papers dp-07-07, Resources for the Future, URL http://ideas.repec.org/p/rff/dpaper/dp-07-07.html.Google Scholar
Jeavons, W. (1911): The Theory of Political Economy, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Johannesson, M., Johansson, P.-O., and O’Conor, R. M. (1996): “The value of private safety versus the value of public safety,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 13, 263275.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johannesson, M., Johansson, P.-O., and Löfgren, K.-G. (1997): “On the value of changes in life expectancy: Blips versus parametric changes,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 15, 221239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, J., Pecquet, G., and Taylor, L. (2007): “Potential gains from trade in dirty industries: Revisiting Lawrence Summers’ memo,” Cato Journal, 27, 397410.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaldor, N. (1939): “Welfare propositions of economics and interpersonal comparisons of utility,” Economic Journal, 49, 549552.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalist, D., Molinari, N., and Siahaan, F. (2007): “Income, employment and suicide behavior,” Journal of Mental Health Policy and Economics, 10, 177187.Google Scholar
Kniesner, T. and Leeth, J. (1991): “Compensating wage differentials for fatal risk in Australia, Japan, and the United States,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 4, 7590.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krupnick, A., Alberini, A., Cropper, M., Simon, N., O’Brien, B., Goeree, R., and Heintzelman, M. (2002): “Age, health and the willingness to pay for mortality risk reductions: A contingent valuation survey of Ontario residents,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 24, 161186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kurzweil, R. (2005): The Singularity is Near: When Humans Transcend Biology, New York: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Lawsky, S. B. (2011): “On the edge: Declining marginal utility and tax policy,” Minnesota Law Review, 95, 904952.Google Scholar
Layard, R., Mayraz, G., and Nickell, S. J. (2008): “The marginal utility of income (revised version),” Journal of Public Economics, 92, 18461857.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leigh, J. (1991): “No evidence of compensating wages for occupational fatalities,” Industrial Relations, 30, 382395.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leigh, J. (1995): “Compensating wages, value of a statistical life, and inter-industry differentials,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 28, 8397.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leigh, J. and Folsom, R. (1984): “Estimates of the value of accident avoidance at the job depend on the concavity of the equalizing differences curve,” Quarterly Review of Economics and Business, 24, 5666.Google Scholar
Lindhjem, H., Navrud, S., Braathen, N. A., and Biausque, V. (2011): “Valuing mortality risk reductions from environmental, transport and health policies: A metaanalysis of stated preference studies,” Risk Analysis, 31, 13811407.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Liu, J.-T., Hammitt, J., and Liu, J.-L. (1997): “Estimating hedonic wage function and value of life in a developing country,” Economics Letters, 57, 353358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liu, J.-T., Hammitt, J., Wan, J.-D., and Tsou, M.-W. (2005): “Valuation of the risk of SARS in Taiwan,” Health Economics, 14, 8391.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Loomis, J. B. (2010): “Incorporating distributional issues into benefit cost analysis: why, how, and two empirical examples using non-market valuation,” Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis, 2, Article 5.Google Scholar
Mandler, M. (1999): Dilemmas in Economic Theory: Persisting Foundational Problems of Microeconomics, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marin, A. and Psacharopoulos, H. (1982): “The reward for risk in the labor market: evidence from the United Kingdom and a reconciliation with other studies,” Journal of Political Economy, 90, 827853.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Masood, E. (1995): “Developing countries dispute use of figures on climate change impact,” Nature, 376, 374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meng, R. (1989): “Compensating differences in the Canadian labour market,” Canadian Journal of Economics, 22, 413424.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meng, R. and Smith, D. (1991): “Compensating wages for long-term job hazards in Canadian industry,” Economics Letters, 36, 331336.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyer, A. (1995): “Economics of climate change,” Nature, 378, 433.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, P., Mulvey, C., and Norris, K. (1997): “Compensating differentials for risk of death in Australia,” Economic Record, 73, 363372.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moore, M. and Viscusi, W. (1988a): “Doubling the estimated value of life: Results using new occupational fatality data,” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 7, 476490.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moore, M. and Viscusi, W. (1988b): “The quantity-adjusted value of life,” Economic Inquiry, 26, 369388.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nicholson, W. (1995): Microeconomic Theory: Basic Principles and Extensions, New York: Dryden Press, sixth edition.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, W. D. (2007): “A review of the Stern review on the economics of climate change,” Journal of Economic Literature, 45, 686702.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, C. (1981): “An analysis of wage differentials received by workers on dangerous jobs,” Journal of Human Resources, 16, 167185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O’Riordan, T. (1995): “Review of Climate Change 1995 – economic and social dimension,” Environment, 39, 3439.Google Scholar
Ortiz, R. A., Markandya, A., and Hunt, A. (2009): “Willingness to pay for mortality risk reduction associated with air pollution in São Paulo,” Revista Brasileira de Economica, 63, 322.Google Scholar
Ramsey, F. P. (1928): “A mathematical theory of saving,” Economic Journal, 38, 543559.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, L. (2008): “Valuing mortality risk reductions in homeland security regulatory analysis,” Prepared for U.S. Customs and Border Protection, Department of Homeland Security, by Industrial Economics, Inc.Google Scholar
Sen, A. (1973): On Economic Inequality, Oxford: Clarendon Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, A. (1974): “Informational bases of alternative welfare approaches: Aggregation of income distribution,” Journal of Public Economics, 3, 387403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, A. (1976): “Welfare inequalities and Rawlsian axiomatics,” Theory and Decision, 7, 243262.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, A. (1979): “Personal utilities and public judgments: or what’s wrong with welfare economics?Economic Journal, 89, 537558.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, A. and Foster, J. E. (1997): On Economic Inequality, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Shanmugam, K. (1996): “The value of life: Estimates from Indian labour,” Indian Economic Journal, 44, 105114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shanmugam, K. (2000): “Valuations of life and injury risks,” Environmental and Resource Economics, 16, 379389.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shanmugam, K. (2001): “Self selection bias in the estimates of compensating differentials for job risks in India,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 22, 263275.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shrader-Frechette, K. (2002): Environmental Justice: Creating Equality, Reclaiming Democracy, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Siebert, W. and Wei, X. (1998): “Wage compensation for job risks: the case of Hong Kong,” Asian Economic Journal, 12, 171181.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, N. B., Cropper, M. L., Alberini, A., and Arora, S. (1999): “Valuing mortality reductions in India: a study of compensating wage differentials,” Policy Research Working Paper Series 2078, The World Bank.Google Scholar
Singer, P. (2009): The Life You Can Save: Acting Now to End World Poverty, New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Smith, R. (1974): “The feasibility of an ‘injury tax’ approach to occupational safety,” Law and Contemporary Problems, 38, 730744.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, R. (1976): The Occupational Safety and Health Act: Its Goals and Its Achievements, Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute.Google Scholar
Starrett, D. (1988): Foundations of Public Economics, New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stevenson, B. and Wolfers, J. (2008): “Economic growth and subjective well-being: Reassessing the Easterlin Paradox,” NBER Working Paper 14282, National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Strand, J. (2009): “Public- and private-good values of statistical lives results from a combined choice-experiment and contingent-valuation survey,” HERO Online Working Paper Series 2002: 2, Oslo University, Health Economics Research Programme.Google Scholar
Svensson, M. (2009): “Precautionary behavior and willingness to pay for a mortality risk reduction: Searching for the expected relationship,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 39, 6585.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tonin, S., Tuvani, M., and Alberini, A. (2008): “The value of reuse and reducing cancer risks at contaminated sites,” Technical report, Paper presented at the EAERE Conference in Gothenburg, Sweden, 2528 June.Google Scholar
Treasury, H. (2003): “The green book: Appraisal and evaluation in central government,” Technical report, London: TSO.Google Scholar
Tsuge, T., Kishimoto, A., and Takeuchi, K. (2005): “A choice experiment approach to the valuation of mortality,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 31, 7395.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
USCG (2008): “Implementation of the 1995 amendments to the international convention on standards of training, certification, and watchkeeping for seafarers, 1978, preliminary regulatory analysis and initial regulatory flexibility analysis,” Technical report USCG-2004-17914, U.S. Coast Guard, U.S. Department of Homeland Security.Google Scholar
USDA (2008): “Supplemental nutrition assistance program eligibility,” URL http://www.fns.usda.gov/snap/applicant recipients/eligibility.htm.Google Scholar
USDOT (2009): “Treatment of the economic value of a statistical life in departmental analyses –2009 annual revision,” Memorandum to secretarial officers and modal administrators from J. Szabat, Deputy Assistant Secretary for Transportation Policy, and L. Knapp, Acting General Counsel, U.S. Department of Transportation.Google Scholar
USEPA (1999): “The benefits and costs of the clean air act, 1990 to 2010,” Technical report EPA 410-R-99-001, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency.Google Scholar
USEPA (2010): “Guidelines for preparing economic analyses,” EPA 240-R-10-001, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency.Google Scholar
Vining, A. and Weimer, D. (2010): “An assessment of important issues concerning the application of benefit-cost analysis to social policy,” Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis, 1, Article 6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Virén, M. (1999): “Testing the ‘natural rate of suicide’ hypothesis,” International Journal of Social Economics, 26, 14281440.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Viscusi, W. K. (1978): “Labor market valuations of life and limb: Empirical evidence and policy implications,” Public Policy, 26, 359386.Google ScholarPubMed
Viscusi, W. K. (1981): “Occupational safety and health regulation: Its impact and policy alternatives,” in Crecine, J., ed., Research in Public Policy Analysis and Management, volume 2, Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, pp. 281299.Google Scholar
Viscusi, W. K. and Aldy, J. E. (2003): “The value of a statistical life: a critical review of market estimates throughout the world,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 27, 576.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, C. E. (2005): “Diminishing marginal value of income without apology,” Oxford Economic Papers, 57, 586609.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weiss, P., Maier, G., and Gerking, S. (1986): “The economic evaluation of job safety: a methodological survey and some estimates for Austria,” Empirica, 13, 5367.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weymark, J. A. (2005): “Measurement theory and the foundations of utilitarianism,” Social Choice and Welfare, 25, 527555.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zerbe, R. O. Jr., (2007): “The legal foundation of cost-benefit analysis,” Charleston Law Review, 2, 94184.Google Scholar
Zhao, J. and Kling, C. L. (2001): “A new explanation for the WTP/WTA disparity,” Economics Letters, 73, 293300.CrossRefGoogle Scholar