Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-22dnz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-26T07:17:14.826Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Taxing the Tails in a Global Economy: How Electoral, Party and Wage Bargaining Systems Interact to Determine the Taxes Paid by the Poor and Rich

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  31 March 2021

Jude C. Hays*
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, University of Pittsburgh, Pittsburgh, PA, USA
*

Abstract

A prominent line of research on electoral systems and income redistribution argues that proportional representation (PR) leads to tax-and-transfer policies that benefit the poor at the expense of the rich. This is because PR produces encompassing center-left coalitions that protect the poor and middle classes. Yet countries with PR electoral systems tend to rely heavily on consumption taxes and tax profits lightly, both of which are inconsistent with this expectation. Both policies are regressive and seem to benefit the rich at the expense of the poor. This article argues that PR electoral institutions, when combined with trichotomous multipartism, are not as hostile to the rich as commonly believed, and that it is important to understand how electoral and party systems interact with labor market institutions in order to explain the puzzling pattern of taxation that is observed. The author develops a theoretical model and evaluates its empirical implications for a world in which production has become multinational.

Type
Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2021. Published by Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Akaishi, T and Steinmo, S (2006) Consumption taxes and the welfare state in Sweden and Japan. In Garon, S and Maclachlan, PL (eds), The Ambivalent Consumer: Questioning Consumption in East Asia and the West, Chapter 9. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, pp. 213235.Google Scholar
Armingeon, K et al. (2017) Comparative Political Data Set 1960–2015. Bern: Institute of Political Science, University of Berne.Google Scholar
Austen-Smith, D (2000) Redistributing income under proportional representation. Journal of Political Economy 108(6), 12351269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Basinger, SJ and Hallerberg, M (2004) Remodeling the competition for capital: how domestic politics erases the race to the bottom. American Political Science Review 98(2), 261276.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becher, M (2016) Endogenous credible commitment and party competition over redistribution under alternative electoral institutions. American Journal of Political Science 60(3), 768782.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bell, A and Jones, K (2015) Explaining fixed effects: random effects modeling of time-series cross-sectional and panel data. Political Science Research and Methods 3(1), 133153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beramendi, P and Rueda, D (2007) Social democracy constrained: indirect taxation in industrialized democracies. British Journal of Political Science 37(4), 619641.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bormann, N-C and Golder, M (2013) Democratic electoral systems around the world, 1946–2011. Electoral Studies 32(2), 360369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bueno De Mesquita, B, Downs, G and Smith, A (2017) A political economy of income tax policies. Political Science Research and Methods 5(1), 129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caminada, K et al. (2017) Income inequality and fiscal redistribution in 47 LIS-countries (1967–2014). LIS Working Paper Series.Google Scholar
Chinn, MD and Ito, H (2008) A new measure of financial openness. Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis 10(3), 309322.Google Scholar
Clark, WR, Golder, M and Golder, SN (2017) An exit, voice and loyalty model of politics. British Journal of Political Science 47(4), 719748.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Döring, H and Manow, P (2017) Is proportional representation more favourable to the left? Electoral rules and their impact on elections, parliaments and the formation of cabinets. British Journal of Political Science 47(1), 149164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, T (2000) The Lexus and the Olive Tree. New York: Anchor Books.Google Scholar
Garrett, G (1998) Partisan Politics in the Global Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Golden, MA, Wallerstein, M and Lange, P (1999) Postwar Trade-Union Organization and Industrial Relations in Twelve Countries, Chapter 7. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 194230.Google Scholar
Gygli, S et al. (2019) The KOF Globalisation Index–revisited. The Review of International Organizations 14(3), 543574.Google Scholar
Hall, PA and Gingerich, DW (2009) Varieties of capitalism and institutional complementarities in the political economy. British Journal of Political Science 39(3), 449482.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hays, J (2020) “Replication Data for: Taxing the Tails in a Global Economy: How Electoral, Party and Wage Bargaining Systems Interact to Determine the Taxes Paid by the Poor and Rich”, https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/HINSEA, Harvard Dataverse, V1, UNF:6:iCMAWI8ifvqKcsKgnMOELQ== [fileUNF]Google Scholar
Hays, JC (2003) Globalization and capital taxation in consensus and majoritarian democracies. World Politics 56(01), 79113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hays, JC (2009) Globalization and the New Politics of Embedded Liberalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hines, JR (2007) Taxing consumption and other sins. Journal of Economic Perspectives 21(1), 4968.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirschman, AO (1970) Exit, Voice, and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States, vol. 25. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
International Monetary Fund (IMF) (2010) From Stimulus to Consolidation: Revenue and Expenditure Policies in Advanced and Emerging Economies. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Iversen, T and Soskice, D (2006) Electoral institutions and the politics of coalitions: why some democracies redistribute more than others. American Political Science Review 100(2), 165181.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iversen, T and Soskice, D (2010) Real exchange rates and competitiveness: the political economy of skill formation, wage compression, and electoral systems. American Political Science Review 104(3), 601623.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iversen, T and Soskice, D (2015) Democratic limits to redistribution: inclusionary versus exclusionary coalitions in the knowledge economy. World Politics 67(2), 185225.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kato, J (2003) Regressive Taxation and the Welfare State: Path Dependence and Policy Diffusion. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kenworthy, L (2008) Jobs with Equality. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Korpi, W and Palme, J (1998) The paradox of redistribution and strategies of equality: welfare state institutions, inequality, and poverty in the Western countries. American Sociological Review 65(5), 661687.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lijphart, A (2012) Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-six Countries. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Lijphart, A and Crepaz, MM (1991) Corporatism and consensus democracy in eighteen countries: conceptual and empirical linkages. British Journal of Political Science 21(2), 235246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lupu, N and Pontusson, J (2011) The structure of inequality and the politics of redistribution. American Political Science Review 105(2), 316336.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martin, CJ and Swank, D (2012) The Political Construction of Business Interests: Coordination, Growth, and Equality. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moene, KO and Wallerstein, M (2001) Inequality, social insurance, and redistribution. American Political Science Review 95(4), 859874.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
OECD (2010) Tax Policy Reform and Economic Growth. Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
OECD (2018) Income distribution database. Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
Persson, T and Tabellini, GE (2000) Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Pontusson, J (2005) Inequality and Prosperity: Socal Europe vs. Liberal America. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, D (1997) Has Globalization Gone Too Far? Washington, DC: Peterson Institute.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmidt, MG (1996) When parties matter: a review of the possibilities and limits of partisan influence on public policy. European Journal of Political Research 30(2), 155183.Google Scholar
Steinmo, S (1993) Taxation and Democracy: Swedish, British and American Approaches to Financing the Modern State. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Swank, D (2016) Taxing choices: international competition, domestic institutions and the transformation of corporate tax policy. Journal of European Public Policy 23(4), 571603.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thelen, K (2014) Varieties of Liberalization and the New Politics of Social Solidarity. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Visser, J (2016) Database on institutional characteristics of trade unions, wage setting, state intervention and social pacts, 1960–2014 (ICTWSS). Amsterdam Institute for Advanced Labour Studies, University of Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: Link
Link
Supplementary material: PDF

Hays supplementary material

Hays supplementary material

Download Hays supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 243.6 KB