Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-wg55d Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-18T19:22:17.494Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Systemic Power in Community Decision Making: A Restatement of Stratification Theory

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2014

Clarence N. Stone*
Affiliation:
University of Maryland

Abstract

In their continued considerations of political inequality, urban scholars are especially concerned with less visible influences surrounding community decision making, and have employed such concepts as potential power, nondecision making, and anticipated reactions. However, these concepts leave some patterns of influence unexplained. There is also a dimension of power in which durable features of the socioeconomic system confer advantages and disadvantages on groups in ways that predispose public officials to favor some interests at the expense of others. Public officials make their decisions in a context in which strategically important resources are hierarchically arranged. Because this system of stratification leaves public officials situationally dependent on upper-strata interests, it is a factor in all that they do. Consequently, system features lower the opportunity costs of exerting influence for some groups and raise them for others. Thus socioeconomic inequalities put various strata on different political footings.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1980

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Anton, Thomas J. (1963). “Power, Pluralism, and Local Politics.” Administrative Science Quarterly 7: 425–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bachrach, Peter, and Baratz, Morton S. (1970). Power and Poverty. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Banfield, Edward C. (1961). Political Influence. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Blau, Peter (1964). Exchange and Power in Social Life. New York: John Wiley.Google Scholar
Clark, Kenneth B. (1965). Dark Ghetto. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Crenson, Matthew A. (1971). The Un-Politics of Air Pollution. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press.Google Scholar
Dahl, Robert A. (1961). Who Governs? New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Davis, Morris, and Weinbaum, Marvin G. (1969). Metropolitan Decision Processes. Chicago: Rand Mc-Nally.Google Scholar
Domhoff, G. William (1977). Who Really Rules? New Haven and Community Power Reexamined. New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books.Google Scholar
Downs, Anthony (1967). Inside Bureaucracy. Chicago: Little, Brown.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Emerson, Richard M. (1962). “Power-Dependence Relations.” American Sociological Review 27: 3140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, Frederick W. (1962). “Comment: On Issues and Non-Issues in the Study of Power.” American Political Science Review 65: 10811101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frohlich, Norman, and Oppenheimer, Joe A. (1978). Modern Political Economy. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Greene, Kenneth R. (1979). “The Impact of Agency and Individual Decision Rules on the Delivery of Urban Services.” Presented at the annual meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. (1962). “The Measurement of Social Power, Opportunity Costs, and the Theory of Two Person Bargaining Games.” Behavioral Science 7: 6775.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hollingshead, August B., and Redlich, Frederick C. (1958). Social Class and Mental Illness. New York: John Wiley.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindblom, Charles A. (1977). Politics and Markets. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Lineberry, Robert L. (1977). Equality and Urban Policy. Beverly Hills, Calif.: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Long, Norton (1958). “The Local Community as an Ecology of Games.” American Journal of Sociology 64: 251–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Matras, Judah (1975). Social Inequality, Stratification, and Mobility. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Miliband, Ralph (1969). The State in Capitalist Society. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Morlock, Laura L. (1974). “Business Interests, Countervailing Groups and the Balance of Influence in 91 Cities.” In Hawley, Willis D. and Wirt, Frederick M. (eds.), The Search for Community Power. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, pp. 309–28.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur (1965). The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Oppenheim, Felix E. (1978). “‘Power’ Revisited.” Journal of Politics 40: 598608.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peterson, Paul E. (1976). School Politics Chicago Style. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Peterson, Paul E. (1978). “The Politics of Taxation and Expenditure—A Unitary Approach.” Presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, New York.Google Scholar
Rogers, David (1968). 110 Livingston Street. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Rosenthal, Robert, and Jacobson, Lenore (1968). Pygmalion in the Classroom. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schon, Donald A. (1970). “The Blindness System.” The Public Interest 18: 2538.Google Scholar
Shefter, Martin (1977). “New York City's Fiscal Crisis: The Politics of Inflation and Retrenchment.” The Public Interest 48: 98127.Google Scholar
Stokes, Carl B. (1973). Promises of Power. New York: Simon and Schuster.Google Scholar
Stone, Clarence N. (1976). Economic Growth and Neiborhood Discontent. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Yates, Douglas (1977). The Ungovernable City. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar