Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-zzh7m Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-26T17:54:19.282Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Competition in Congressional Elections: Money versus Votes

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 September 2022

DANIELLE M. THOMSEN*
Affiliation:
University of California, Irvine, United States
*
Danielle M. Thomsen, Associate Professor, Department of Political Science, University of California, Irvine, United States, dthomsen@uci.edu.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Competition among candidates or parties is a necessary condition for democracy. But who counts as a candidate and what counts as competition? The influence of money in American elections makes fundraising an appropriate alternative to vote totals, and it provides a new vantage point to assess the quality of electoral competition. I draw on a dataset of preelection campaign receipts to measure competition in U.S. House primaries from 1980 to 2020. When competition is measured with receipts, it looks markedly worse than vote share measures suggest. Moreover, the difference between vote share and fundraising measures is largest in open-seat primaries, or the best-case scenarios of competition. The disparity between measures is driven largely by candidates who have little chance of winning. The findings shed new light on resource disparities in elections and demonstrate that our conclusions about the quality of competition are tied to our measures.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the American Political Science Association

Competition among candidates or parties is a necessary condition for democracy (Dahl Reference Dahl1956; Reference Dahl1971; Key Reference Key1949; Schlesinger Reference Schlesinger1966; Schumpeter Reference Schumpeter1942). But who counts as a candidate and what counts as competition? The competitive struggle for the people’s vote is so central to our understanding of democratic government that the makeup of the ballot and the outcomes of elections have, mostly implicitly, come to dominate our depictions of the state of electoral competition. Political scientists have relied on vote totals and victory margins to examine core questions in the study of American politics and representation such as whether citizens are able to hold their elected officials accountable and whether elections are living up to democratic ideals (i.e., Achen and Bartels Reference Achen and Bartels2016; Ansolabehere, Snyder, and Stewart Reference Ansolabehere, Snyder and Stewart2001; Bonica and Cox Reference Bonica and Cox2018; Canes-Wrone, Brady, and Cogan Reference Canes-Wrone, Brady and Cogan2002; Fraga and Hersh Reference Fraga and Hersh2018; Hirano and Snyder Reference Hirano and Snyder2019).Footnote 1 It is almost exclusively through the lens of the ballot that scholars have evaluated the nature and quality of competition in the United States over the short and long run.

One strength of vote share measures of candidates and competition is that the data collection is straightforward. Candidates are listed, votes are tallied, and some win and others lose. Vote totals also have theoretical appeal because they have the most direct consequences for the election of officeholders and the makeup of legislative institutions. Yet the reliance on votes has limitations as well. Ferejohn (Reference Ferejohn1977, 166) alluded to the imperfections of vote share measures over four decades ago, noting that they have “the defect of suggesting that what might be called the vulnerability of a seat is related in some way to vote margin.” Vote totals can indicate which races were likely viewed as competitive during the campaign cycle, but only after the election has occurred. Nor do vote totals always reflect how candidates were perceived prior to the election. Upset victories are an obvious example, but candidates often outperform or underperform expectations.

This article departs from the use of vote shares and examines the quality of competition through the lens of fundraising. The influence of money in American elections makes fundraising an especially appropriate alternative to the ballot. Campaign war chests are one of the most widely used indicators of viability and vulnerability prior to the election.Footnote 2 Fundraising reports are shorthand for who is ahead or behind in the race and who is stronger or weaker as a candidate. Coverage of the “financial horse race” gives a barometer of support for a candidate and their likelihood of winning (La Raja Reference La Raja2007). The use of receipts as a heuristic for electability has become even more prevalent as candidates raise record sums of money with each election cycle.Footnote 3 Additional evidence of the importance of money is that it is explicitly incorporated in prominent forecasting models. Fundraising is one of the “fundamentals” in 538’s models, and the Cook Political Report similarly draws on fundraising data for their reputable ratings of competitive House and Senate races.

Candidates run against their opponents throughout an election cycle, and the race culminates in, but is not limited to, a vote. Resource disparities matter for material and symbolic reasons well before the election. Donations have direct implications for whether candidates can hire staffers and consultants, buy advertisements, and access the goods and services that fuel their campaigns. A strong fundraising haul also attracts attention from the media and partisan elites. Following the money during the campaign cycle has become a staple of political journalism, in part because it is measurable, comparable across candidates, and fits easily into the horse race frame (Graber and Dunaway Reference Graber and Dunaway2017; La Raja Reference La Raja2007). Resource disparities influence candidate behavior prior to the election as well, and those who struggle to raise money are more likely to exit the race (Bonica Reference Bonica2017). Of course, at the heart of the emphasis on fundraising is the strong association between money and election outcomes (Bonica Reference Bonica2017; Center for Responsive Politics 2020).Footnote 4 In short, money has meaning because it matters for the resources available to candidates, because receipts are readily accessible and widely cited during the campaign, and because the top fundraiser usually wins.

The influence and even necessity of money in modern campaigns compels us to examine resource disparities among candidates, and it provides a new vantage point to assess the quality of competition in American elections. I focus on primaries due to the recent emphasis on the primary stage and their increasing role in the selection of officeholders.Footnote 5 I leverage preelection receipts in more than 16,000 U.S. House primaries from 1980 to 2020. I first show that receipts and votes differ in important ways that bear on our understanding of competition. In particular, long-shot candidates, or those who raise little or no money, outperform their receipt share at the ballot box. I then construct new fundraising measures of competition to examine how they differ from vote share measures. The first is a binary indicator of whether the top fundraiser raised less than 57.5% of preprimary receipts or whether their fundraising margin is within 20 points of the second highest fundraiser. The second is a measure of the effective number of candidates in the race calculated with receipts (Laakso and Taagepera Reference Laakso and Taagepera1979).

When the quality of primary competition is viewed through a fundraising lens, it looks markedly worse than recent research suggests. Fewer races are competitive with fundraising measures, and the number of candidates decreases. Open-seat primaries are often held up as bright spots in an era of declining general election competition, but the difference between vote share and fundraising measures is largest in open seats. The likelihood that an open-seat primary is competitive with vote share measures but not fundraising measures increases by 15 percentage points, and the effective number of candidates calculated with receipts decreases by nearly half in safe districts and by 40% in competitive districts. The disparity between vote share and fundraising measures is driven largely by financial long shots who outperform their receipt share at the ballot box. The quality of competition in these best-case scenarios is increasingly relevant as more elections are decided at the primary stage.

The article makes several contributions to the study of elections and representation. It provides the first analysis of the quality of competition through the lens of fundraising. The soaring cost of elections matters for who runs, who wins, and how legislators spend their time in office (i.e., Bonica Reference Bonica2020; Carnes Reference Carnes2018; Fouirnaies Reference Fouirnaies2021; Hall Reference Hall2019; Kaslovsky Reference Kaslovsky2022; Kirkland Reference Kirkland2021; Powell Reference Powell2012). Grappling more directly with resource disparities is important because of the outsized role that fundraising plays in running for office and gaining attention on the campaign trail. Although vote share measures of competition have long been the gold standard, the findings raise new questions about their limitations within both the US and other democracies, particularly when there are numerous small parties or unknown candidates in the race. Alternative measures of viability will necessarily vary by context, but future research should give more attention to how vote share measures influence our view of competition across democratic governments.

In addition, the framework allows us to draw distinctions between dimensions of competition. The fundraising arena is undergoing enormous and rapid change. The historic amount of money in elections has been spurred by both legal and technological developments (Magleby Reference Magleby2019; Magleby, Goodliffe, and Olsen Reference Magleby, Goodliffe and Olsen2018). The rise in online fundraising has decreased the barriers to giving money, and small donors play an increasingly central role in the funding of campaigns (Alvarez, Katz, and Kim Reference Alvarez, Katz and Kim2020; Kim Reference Kim2022). The ease of donating coupled with the engagement of energized partisans can lead to unlikely influxes in resources. For instance, a handful of recent House and Senate challengers running against high-profile incumbents raised huge sums in unfavorable districts and lost by large margins (Skelley Reference Skelley2021).Footnote 6 Although donors for the most part bet on the candidates who win, the framework allows us to distinguish preelection viability from electoral performance and study where donor behavior and election outcomes deviate from expectations.

Finally, the article raises new questions about how we define and study political candidacies. The availability of new data has resulted in a surge in attention to the factors that shape candidate emergence and success. Most samples start with the ballot, but scholars increasingly draw on candidate and committee data from the Federal Election Commission or focus on those who raise money. Most of the time, it is simply not clear how candidacies are measured because there has been a dearth of attention to this topic (Fowler Reference Fowler1993; Thomsen Reference Thomsen2017). Those who campaign for office but drop out before the election complicate our definitions even more. Yet these distinctions matter for the makeup of candidate pools, particularly with respect to income, education, and occupation. They also matter for victory rates if our samples include or exclude candidates who are more or less viable. This article measures candidates and competition with money, but the question of what counts as either has theoretical, empirical, and normative implications and warrants additional scholarly discussion.

MEASURING ELECTORAL COMPETITION

Scholars have long relied on vote totals to examine competition. A series of influential articles in the 1970s studied the “vanishing marginals” and the rise in incumbent vote share that unfolded over the late twentieth century.Footnote 7 The steady decline in competitive general elections has amplified the importance of primaries and sparked new interest in the quality of primary competition. Hirano and Snyder (Reference Hirano and Snyder2019) provide the most comprehensive study of primaries to date. They use four measures of competition: the percentage of primaries that were contested, the percentage of primaries where the winner received less than 57.5% of the total votes, the number of candidates in the race, and the votes cast for all losing candidates as a percentage of the total votes (Hirano and Snyder Reference Hirano and Snyder2019, 39). They find that, across primaries from 1900 to 2016, the level of competition is highest in open-seat races and in constituencies with a partisan advantage. The authors have a positive view of primaries, and they conclude that primaries contribute to the electoral system by allowing candidates to compete in constituencies that would otherwise lack competition.

As noted above, fundraising is an appropriate alternative to votes in large part because of its association with election outcomes. Indeed, money is perhaps the single most valuable resource for candidates who want to win. Top fundraisers win the primary 92% of the time; if we exclude unopposed candidates, they win 81% of the time.Footnote 8 Fundraising is at least as good a predictor of outcomes as previous political experience, the most commonly used measure of candidate quality (i.e., Hirano and Snyder Reference Hirano and Snyder2019; Jacobson Reference Jacobson1989). Fifty-two percent of experienced nonincumbents won the primary, compared with 85% of nonincumbents who raised the most money; among opposed nonincumbents, these figures are 42% and 69%, respectively. Here we are not interested in the effect of money on outcomes, but the association between the two adds validity to fundraising measures of competition.

Yet money and votes also differ in small but systematic ways that bear on our understanding of competition. Figure 1 shows binned scatter plots of the relationship between primary receipt share and vote share for more than 30,000 U.S. House candidates from 1980 to 2020. The left graph includes all candidates, and the right graph excludes unopposed candidates. Candidates who raise less than 10% of receipts still receive 15% of the vote, on average.Footnote 9 Indeed, the relationship between money and votes is weakest for those who are most likely to lose.Footnote 10 The correlation between receipt share and vote share among those who raise less than 10% of receipts is 0.11, compared with 0.77 for opposed candidates who raise more than 10%.Footnote 11 Moreover, long-shot candidates who raise little or no money make up a significant share of primary contenders: 45% of nonincumbents raise less than 10% of primary receipts, and nearly 25% of nonincumbents did not file a fundraising report with the Federal Election Commission, indicating that they raised less than $5,000.Footnote 12

Figure 1. Relationship between Primary Receipt Share and Vote Share

Note: The left graph shows a binned scatter plot of the relationship between primary receipt share and vote share for U.S. House candidates from 1980 to 2020. The right graph excludes unopposed candidates. The lower correlation between receipt share and vote share among long-shot candidates provides motivation for why vote share and fundraising measures of competition are likely to differ.

Because long shots receive more votes than they do money, vote share measures are likely to produce a more optimistic view of competition than fundraising measures. What is more, vote share measures will be more likely to differ from fundraising measures in open-seat races, or the best-case scenarios of competition. Hirano and Snyder (Reference Hirano and Snyder2019) show that open seats attract the most candidates, but more amateurs run in these contexts as well (Canon Reference Canon1993). In advantaged-party open-seat races, the average number of candidates who raise less than 10% of receipts is 2.5, compared with 0.5 in all other primaries, and the share of candidates raising less than 10% of receipts is 39% and 16%, respectively. The top two candidates are more evenly matched than in other primaries, but the average difference between the top two vote-getters in contested advantaged-party open seats is 20 points, compared with 29 points for the top two fundraisers.Footnote 13 The implication that vote share measures are most likely to diverge from fundraising measures in open seats is important because much of the optimism around primaries is driven by these races in particular (Hirano and Snyder Reference Hirano and Snyder2019).

I construct new measures of competition with preprimary fundraising totals to examine how they differ from vote share measures. First, I create a binary measure of whether the race was competitive that considers the fundraising advantage of those at the top: whether the top fundraiser raised less than 57.5% of all preprimary receipts as well as whether the top fundraiser’s share of receipts is within 20 percentage points of the second highest fundraiser.Footnote 14 I use both measures because, unlike in general elections with two candidates, a 55 or 60 percent threshold in primary elections does not necessarily indicate a narrow fundraising or victory margin because money and votes can be divided among more than two candidates.Footnote 15 The 20-point margin measure further distinguishes between primaries where the top two candidates are more evenly matched and those where they are not.

Second, I create a weighted measure of the number of candidates in the race based on preprimary receipts. I follow Laakso and Taagepera’s (Reference Laakso and Taagepera1979) measure of the effective number of parties, where each party is weighted by being squared.Footnote 16 The advantage of using the effective number of parties is that it differentiates significant parties from less significant ones. I build on this approach to generate a fundraising-based measure of the effective number of candidates:

(1) $$ {N}_c=\frac{{\left(\sum \limits_{i=1}^n{f}_{irt}\right)}^2}{\sum \limits_{i=1}^n{f}_{irt}^2}, $$

where $ {f}_{irt} $ is the amount of money raised by candidate i in race r at time t. In races where receipts are evenly distributed among candidates, the effective number of candidates is the same as the number of candidates on the ballot. In races where one candidate raises the bulk of receipts, the effective number of candidates is slightly larger than one. Because weighted values are almost always lower than unweighted values, our concern is where they differ the most.

These measures provide a summary view of competition prior to the election. Because competition evolves during the cycle, we could also examine the relative strength of candidates at any snapshot before the election. Contexts change, too, if the incumbent decides to retire or if district lines are redrawn. Competition measures based on early money will only include candidates who have entered at that point and are less complete views than measures based on later fundraising. In addition, because seed money increases later fundraising success (Biersack, Herrnson, and Wilcox Reference Biersack, Herrnson and Wilcox1993; Krasno, Green, and Cowden Reference Krasno, Green and Cowden1994), early money measures will not capture any momentum that follows. We would thus expect fundraising measures later in the cycle to more closely map onto (or differ less from) vote totals than those earlier in the cycle (see also Gelman and King Reference Gelman and King1993). Here we are interested in overall levels of competition, but the measures with early money conform to this expectation (see Figure A8).

Although fundraising measures offer a number of advantages, they have their own limitations. First, the time frame is unable to match the historical breadth of studies that draw on votes.Footnote 17 Second, the measures are contingent on an association between money and outcomes. The connection is overwhelmingly apparent in the US, but if money is unrelated to viability or mandated to be equitable, other measures would be more useful. The measures have serious normative implications as well. The emphasis on money has negative consequences for who runs as well as who wins, and it leads to unorthodox conclusions about representation that are not based on levels of constituent support (Canes-Wrone and Miller Reference Canes-Wrone and Miller2022; Gimpel, Lee, and Pearson-Merkowitz Reference Gimpel, Lee and Pearson-Merkowitz2008). However, it is important to note that these concerns are rooted in the state of American elections rather than the measure itself. More generally, fundraising measures provide a new opportunity to study the quality of competition through the lens that receives the most attention in political campaigns today: the ability to raise money.

DATA AND METHOD

As noted above, I focus on primaries in light of their growing relevance for the selection of officeholders. The analyses follow the same structure as those in Hirano and Snyder (Reference Hirano and Snyder2019). Competition is measured at the race level, and primaries are divided into several types based on seat type and partisan leaning. I draw on a dataset of more than 33,000 U.S. House candidates who filed fundraising reports with the Federal Election Commission (FEC) and/or were on the primary ballot from 1980 to 2020. I collected the full sample of on-ballot primary candidates from the America Votes series and the FEC website. Those who were not on the ballot but raised money are from the FEC database and Bonica’s (Reference Bonica2014) Database on Ideology, Money in Politics, and Elections (DIME).Footnote 18 The dataset here includes the FEC candidate identifier, the FEC committee identifier (when available), and the DIME identifier for each candidate to facilitate merges across datasets. All of the fundraising data are from FEC reports.Footnote 19

There are significant challenges associated with collecting preprimary fundraising data and thus measuring competition based on preprimary receipts. The first hurdle was merging the candidates with FEC data, which was made possible with the identifiers noted above.Footnote 20 The other challenge is related to FEC reporting requirements. The FEC has collected quarterly and preprimary reports since 1980, but the document did not ask candidates to provide the total amount raised in the preprimary period (election cycle to date) until 2002. Thus, from 2002 on, I use the total preprimary amount reported by the candidate. From 1980 to 2000, I use the sum of the amount reported in each quarterly period before the primary and the amount in the preprimary report, which covers the first day of the current quarterly period through the twentieth day before the election.Footnote 21 I validated these measures with the post-2002 preprimary totals provided by the candidates. The preprimary totals that I generated with quarterly and preprimary reports are correlated with the preprimary totals reported by the candidates at 0.99, so I am confident in the validity of these totals for the pre-2002 period.

The unit of analysis is the party primary by district and year from 1980 to 2020. Only Democratic and Republican candidates are considered here.Footnote 22 There are approximately 16,600 primaries, though the number decreases to 16,300 with the fundraising measures due to missing observations on preprimary receipts in about 2% of races. The analyses focus on two main factors that are widely known to affect primary competition: seat type and district partisanship. Like Hirano and Snyder (Reference Hirano and Snyder2019), partisan balance is coded as disadvantaged if the party received less than 42.5% of the district vote share in the current or previous presidential election, balanced if the party received between 42.5% and 57.5%, and advantaged if the party received more than 57.5%.Footnote 23 I use their classification of primary types: (a) advantaged-party open-seat primaries, (b) advantaged-party incumbent-contested primaries, (c) parties-balanced open-seat primaries, (d) parties-balanced challenger-party primaries, (e) parties-balanced incumbent-contested primaries, (f) disadvantaged-party open-seat primaries, and (g) disadvantaged-party challenger-party primaries.Footnote 24

The first set of dependent variables includes four binary indicators of whether the primary is competitive. The vote share measures are whether the top vote-getter received less than 57.5% of the vote and whether their victory margin is within 20 percentage points of the second highest vote-getter. The fundraising measures are whether the top fundraiser raised less than 57.5% of preprimary receipts and whether their fundraising margin is within 20 percentage points of the second highest fundraiser. The second set of dependent variables includes three measures of the number of candidates in the race: the total number of candidates on the ballot, the effective number of candidates based on vote shares, and the effective number of candidates based on receipts.Footnote 25 I also calculate the difference between the respective vote share and fundraising measures to examine where the two measures differ most. Descriptive statistics of the competitive primary variables are provided in Table A1, and distributions of the number of candidates variables are provided in Figures A1 and A2.Footnote 26

Each model includes a binary variable for open-seat and challenger-party primaries, with incumbent-contested primaries as the baseline. To measure partisan leaning, I include indicators for parties-balanced and advantaged-party primaries, with disadvantaged-party primaries as the baseline. I interact seat type and party balance to examine how competition varies across primary types. Although entirely self-funded candidates are rare, many candidates loan money to their campaigns. In additional analyses, I exclude candidate loans from the preprimary totals, and the results are the same (see Tables A5, A6, and A7). I follow Hirano and Snyder’s (Reference Hirano and Snyder2019) focus on seat type and district partisanship due to the overwhelming influence of these variables on primary competition, but all of the models include district and year fixed effects to account for time-invariant attributes of the district and election-specific trends.

DESCRIPTIVE TRENDS OVER TIME

Before turning to the results, I plot the vote share and fundraising measures over time. The top graphs in Figure 2 show the percentage of primaries where the top vote-getter received less than 57.5% of the vote and where the top fundraiser raised less than 57.5% of receipts. The bottom graphs show the total number of candidates on the ballot and the effective number of candidates with receipts.Footnote 27 The data are broken down by incumbent-contested, challenger-party, and open-seat races. Two main patterns emerge. First, the fundraising measures reveal lower levels of competition across primary types. In open seats, 55% of races are competitive with the vote share measure, compared with 40% with the fundraising measure. In challenger-party primaries, 19% of races are competitive with the vote share measure, versus 7% with the fundraising measure. Very few incumbent-contested primaries are competitive, but the share is lower with the fundraising measure (6% vs. 3%).Footnote 28 On average, the total number of candidates is 1.6 in incumbent-contested primaries, 1.5 in challenger-party primaries, and 3.7 in open seats. By comparison, the effective number in each is 1.1, 1.1, and 2.1, respectively.

Figure 2. Measures of Primary Competition over Time and By Seat Type

Note: The top graphs show the percentage of primaries where the top vote-getter received less than 57.5% of total votes and where the top fundraiser raised less than 57.5% of total receipts. The bottom graphs show the number of candidates on the ballot and the effective number of candidates calculated with preprimary receipts.

Second, differences between the number of candidate measures are more pronounced in recent election cycles, particularly in open-seat primaries. The total number of candidates in open seats has risen sharply since 2008. From 1980 to 2006, the average total number of candidates in incumbent-contested, challenger-party, and open-seat primaries is 1.4, 1.4, and 3.4, respectively. These figures increase to 1.9, 1.7, and 4.3, respectively, during the period from 2008 to 2020. Whereas the total number of candidates doubled from 2008 to 2020 in open-seat races, the increase in the effective number of candidates is not nearly as stark (37% increase). Similarly, in incumbent-contested races, the total number of candidates increased by 53% from 2008 to 2020, but the effective number of candidates increased by 9%. The change in the effective number of candidates is much more muted than the change in the total number of candidates.

Although the highs and lows track similarly, the largest single-year differences between measures correspond to years in which top fundraisers fared worse. The worst year for top fundraisers was in 1992, when 15% of top fundraisers lost (compared with the average of 8%), and their loss rates were above average in 1994, 2010, 2018, and 2020. These years are widely considered to be wave elections or atypical with respect to victory patterns. For example, women were favored in primaries in 1992 and 2018, and outsiders fared better in 2018 as well (Dittmar Reference Dittmar2020; Porter and Treul Reference Porter and Treul2018; Scott et al. Reference Scott, Dickinson, Lajevardi and Olson2019; Thomsen Reference Thomsen, Dodd, Oppenheimer and Evans2021). To be sure, top fundraisers are far more likely to win across this period, but atypical elections are useful contrasts because the outcomes differed from the norm or from expectations. More generally, the trends provide initial support for the expectation that competition looks better with vote share measures than with measures based on resource disparities. The next section incorporates district partisanship to further explore variation across race types.

RESULTS

Table 1 presents the results for whether the primary is competitive with the vote share and fundraising measures, and Table 2 presents the results with the number of candidate measures.Footnote 29 We can see in Table 1 that, consistent with Hirano and Snyder’s (Reference Hirano and Snyder2019) findings, advantaged-party open-seat primaries are the most competitive across all four measures. The lower levels of competition in incumbent-contested primaries and in disadvantaged-party constituencies (the baseline categories) is unsurprising. Yet the size of the coefficients varies significantly with the vote share and fundraising measures, and the difference is largest in open-seat primaries. The magnitude of the difference is discussed in more detail below. Another notable pattern is that, even between the vote share measures (Models 1 and 3), the likelihood that a primary is competitive is lower with the 20-point vote margin measure than with the 57.5% vote share measure because unlike in general elections, winning with less than 57.5% of the vote does not necessarily indicate a narrow 20-point margin.

Table 1. Likelihood of Competitive Primary with Votes and Receipts

Note: Results are from ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions from 1980 to 2020. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. The dependent variable in Models 1 and 2 is whether the top vote-getter received less than 57.5% of total votes and whether the top fundraiser raised less than 57.5% of total receipts, respectively. The dependent variable in Models 3 and 4 is whether the top vote-getter’s victory margin is within 20 points of the second highest vote-getter and whether the top fundraiser’s fundraising margin is within 20 points of the second highest fundraiser, respectively. The baseline categories are incumbent-contested primaries and disadvantaged-party constituencies. The models include district and year fixed effects. *p < 0.05, **p < 0.01

Table 2. Expected Number of Candidates with Votes and Receipts

Note: Results are from OLS regressions from 1980 to 2020. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. The dependent variable in Model 1 is the total number of candidates on the ballot, and the dependent variable in Models 2 and 3 is the effective number of candidates based on votes and receipts, respectively. The baseline categories are incumbent-contested primaries and disadvantaged-party constituencies. The models include district and year fixed effects. *p < 0.05, **p < 0.01.

The same patterns emerge in Table 2. Across measures, the number of candidates increases in open-seat primaries in advantaged-party and parties-balanced constituencies. The weighted measures calculated with votes as well as receipts (Models 2 and 3) indicate that the unweighted measure of the number of candidates on the ballot includes a large number who fail to attract support from voters as well as donors. The coefficients are much smaller with the effective number of candidates measure based on votes (Model 2), and the effective number of candidates based on preprimary receipts is lower yet (Model 3). As in Table 1, the magnitude of the difference across the number of candidate measures varies dramatically by primary type, with the largest disparity emerging in open seats.

In addition, I calculated the difference between the fundraising and vote share measures to examine where they differ most (i.e., whether the race is competitive with the 57.5% vote share and 20-point vote margin measure minus whether the race is competitive with the respective fundraising measure; the total and effective number of candidates with votes minus the effective number of candidates with receipts). The full models are provided in Table A2. Predicted values are plotted by seat type in Figure 3.Footnote 30 The top graphs show the predicted probability that the primary is competitive with the vote share measure but not the fundraising measure. The bottom graphs show the expected difference between the number of candidates with the vote share and fundraising measures; positive (negative) values correspond to an increase (decrease) in the number of candidates with the vote share measures.

Figure 3. Difference between Vote Share and Fundraising Measures of Competition, by Race Type

Note: Predicted values are calculated from the models in Table A2. The top graphs show the probability the primary is competitive with the vote share measure but not the fundraising measure (for the 57.5% and 20-point margin measures, respectively). The bottom graphs show the difference between the total and effective number of candidates (based on receipts) and the difference between the effective number of candidates based on votes and receipts, respectively. Across measures, primaries are more competitive with vote share measures than with fundraising measures.

All four graphs indicate that competition looks better with vote share measures, but the disparity is smallest in incumbent-contested races and largest in open seats. In advantaged-party open-seat primaries, the probability that a primary is competitive with the vote share measure but not the fundraising measure increases by 14 percentage points with the 57.5% vote share measure and by 13 points with the 20-point vote margin measure, as shown in graphs (a) and (b), respectively. In parties-balanced open seats, the probability increases by 16 percentage points with both the 57.5% vote share measure and the 20-point vote margin measure.Footnote 31 If unopposed primaries are excluded, the probability that an open-seat race is competitive increases by 25 percentage points with both the 57.5% vote share and the 20-point vote-margin measures.

The number of candidates results also reveal sizable differences between measures. The disparity between the total and effective number of candidates based on receipts reaches a height of 2.3 candidates in advantaged-party open-seat primaries (from 4.9 total to 2.6 effective candidates) and 1.5 candidates in parties-balanced open-seat primaries (from 3.6 total to 2.1 effective candidates), as shown in graph (c). In other words, the number of candidates decreases by nearly half in advantaged-party open seats and by 40% in parties-balanced open seats with the fundraising measure. Unweighted measures are often higher than weighted measures, but the difference between the effective number of candidate measures based on votes and receipts is largest in open-seat primaries as well, as shown in graph (d). The magnitude is smaller at 0.4 candidates, but it is substantively meaningful as the average effective number of candidates based on votes and receipts is 2.5 and 2.1 in open seats, respectively.

These two measures of competition—the top vote-getter’s or top fundraiser’s advantage and the number of candidates—do not have quite the same implications for democracy. Races where resources are heavily skewed are more clearly worrisome. By comparison, additional candidates do not necessarily improve competition, but there is a strong association between the effective number of candidates and electoral margins. In safe open-seat primaries, the average vote margin between the top two vote-getters in primaries with fewer than 2.6 effective candidates is 39 points, versus 12 points in primaries with more. In opposed incumbent-contested races, the average victory margin in primaries with fewer than the mean of 1.3 effective candidates is 60 points, versus 30 points in primaries with more. Incumbents rarely lose, but the percentage of incumbents who win drops from 99.5% in opposed primaries with fewer than 1.3 effective candidates to 91.8% in primaries with more. In primaries with at least two effective candidates, incumbent victory rates decrease to 86.2%. In short, these measures are collectively tapping into viability and vulnerability.

HOW LONG-SHOT CANDIDATES INFLUENCE OUR MEASURES

We may be tempted to interpret the findings above as good news because candidates can outperform a fundraising disadvantage at the ballot box. Yet the main reason why vote share measures are expected to overstate the degree of competition is because of the entry of long-shot candidates. This section examines whether the disparity between measures widens as the number of candidates with limited resources and a minimal chance of winning increases. The analyses are structured the same as above and include seat type and partisan balance. Here the main independent variable is the number of candidates in the primary who raise less than 10% of preprimary receipts.Footnote 32 I use indicator variables for the number of long-shot candidates in the race, with zero candidates raising less than 10% of receipts as the baseline. More than 95% of primaries have fewer than five long shots, so primaries with five or more candidates raising less than 10% of receipts are combined into one category. The results are presented in Table 3.

Table 3. Relationship between Long Shots and Difference between Measures

Note: The results in Models 1 and 2 are from ordinal logistic regressions, and the results in Models 3 and 4 are from OLS regressions (1980–2020). The dependent variable in Models 1 and 2 is the difference between whether the primary is competitive with the 57.5% vote share and fundraising measures and the difference between whether the primary is competitive with the 20-point victory and fundraising margin measures, respectively. The dependent variable in Models 3 and 4 is the difference between the total and effective number of candidates (based on receipts) and the difference between the effective number of candidates based on votes and receipts, respectively. The baseline categories are incumbent-contested primaries, disadvantaged-party constituencies, and primaries with zero long-shot candidates. The models include district and year fixed effects. *p < 0.05, **p < 0.01.

The coefficient on open seat is still positive and significant in Models 1 and 2, but the magnitude is smaller. Moreover, the coefficients on the number of long-shot candidates are much larger than that on open seat. For the most part, the difference between the vote share and fundraising measures increases with each additional long-shot candidate, although the size of the increase varies across models. In the number of candidate models, open seat is not even significant once the number of long shots is taken into account. Much of what is driving the relationship between open-seat primaries and the disparity between vote share and fundraising measures is the number of long-shot candidates in the race. In fact, if we add the coefficients on open-seat primaries, competition even looks better with the fundraising measures in Model 4 when there are zero long shots in the race (as the values are negative).

Figure 4 shows the expected difference between measures by the number of long-shot candidates for advantaged-party open seats. The negative value in graph (d) when there are zero long shots illustrates the point above, but the majority of open-seat races have at least one. On average, there are 2.5 candidates who raise less than 10% of receipts in advantaged-party open seats. In races with at least three long shots, the likelihood a primary is competitive increases by 25 percentage points with the 57.5% vote share measure and by 15 to 20 points with the 20-point margin measure. Similarly, the disparity between the total and effective number of candidates increases by about one candidate with each additional long shot. Even the disparity between the two effective candidate measures (graph [d]), both of which are weighted, is approximately one candidate in races with four or more long shots. The degree to which our measures differ thus depends on the number of candidates who raise little or no money, but vote share measures most often result in a better view of competition than do measures based on resources.

Figure 4. Difference between Measures, by Number of Long Shots

Note: Predicted values are calculated from the models in Table 3. The top graphs show the probability the primary is competitive with the vote share measure but not the fundraising measure (for the 57.5% and 20-point margin measures, respectively). The bottom graphs show the difference between the total and effective number of candidates (based on receipts) and the difference between the effective number of candidates based on votes and receipts, respectively. The disparity between vote share and fundraising measures is driven largely by long-shot candidates.

Although the above analyses are at the race level, we can also look at the amount raised per primary vote to examine how much cheaper votes are for long shots. Vote prices differ dramatically by candidate type, with opposed winners raising a median of $10 per primary vote and long shots raising a median of $0. Seat type has a significant impact as well, and more competitive races come with a steeper price tag: the median amount raised by open-seat candidates is $11 per vote, and this increases to $14 for candidates in advantaged-party open seats. In open-seat primaries, non-long shots raise a median of $19 per vote, compared with $3 for long-shot candidates. In advantaged-party open seats, these values are $25 and $6, respectively. Incumbents raise a median of $14 per vote, compared with $0 for long shots in incumbent-contested races. (These comparisons are limited to those in contested elections because vote totals are not available for all unopposed candidates.) Additional analyses in Table A13 demonstrate that long-shot candidates raise much less money per vote ($18 less, on average) than non-long shots.

In sum, our interest is not in why so many long-shot candidates run but rather how measures based on resources change our view of competition. However, it is clear that the exponential increase in the amount of money needed to win has not deterred candidates from entering the fray, even those who have little chance of success.Footnote 33 It may be that long-shot candidates have a higher, though still very slim, chance of winning in open seats than they do in races with an incumbent (Canon Reference Canon1993). Candidates may also miscalculate their ability to gain traction and expect to raise more money than they do. The broader media environment might play a role as well. Arceneaux et al. (Reference Arceneaux, Dunaway, Johnson and Wielen2020) find that the density of Fox News in congressional districts altered the perceptions of high-quality potential Republican candidates and increased their likelihood of running for Congress. Media markets may be associated with the entry of inexperienced candidates as well. Regardless of the motivations of long shots, they are unlikely to be formidable in the current context.

GENERAL ELECTIONS

Although our main focus is on primary elections, we might wonder whether similar patterns emerge in general elections as well. A more detailed overview is provided in the Appendix.Footnote 34 The relationship between general election receipts and votes echoes that in the primary, with long shots who raise less than 10% of general election receipts receiving 29% of the vote, on average (see Figure A10). Indeed, the floor for long-shot candidates is even higher in general elections due to the significant influence of partisanship on voting behavior.Footnote 35 The ceiling for those who are almost certain to win is similarly lower than their receipt share, as candidates who raise more than 80% of receipts receive 76% of the vote, on average. I construct the same analyses as above to examine the difference in competition between vote share and fundraising measures in general elections. I use the 57.5% threshold for votes and receipts in four types of general elections: incumbent-contested and open-seat races in competitive and uncompetitive districts.

The results are provided in Table A14, and predicted values of the difference between measures are shown in Figure A11. Across races, the quality of competition is higher with vote share measures than with fundraising measures. For the competition variables, the difference between measures is again largest in open seats. The predicted probability that a race is competitive with the vote share measure but not the fundraising measure increases by 32 percentage points in open-seat races in competitive districts. In these best-case scenarios, the number of competitive races declines from 248 with the vote share measure to 108 with the fundraising measure. However, in contrast to the primary results, the difference between the number of candidate measures is smallest in open seats because both candidates are more viable than in uncompetitive districts (a difference of 0.26 candidates in competitive open seats). Primaries differ from general elections in substantial ways, but the results suggest that competition is better with vote share measures than with fundraising measures in both.

CONCLUSION

To be sure, it is difficult to say what truly counts as electoral competition. One goal of this article is to generate a new conversation about how our conclusions about the quality of competition are tied to and influenced by the measures we use. Fundraising is a valuable metric and a useful alternative to votes because it matters for whether candidates can access the goods and services associated with victories and whether they are perceived as viable contenders. A small minority of candidates overcome the odds and prevail without raising as much money, but the ability to fundraise is seen as an advantage by the vast majority of candidates and officeholders who win. And although financial long shots do outperform their receipt shares at the ballot box, they overwhelmingly lose and usually by large margins. Future work should examine how candidates perceive the difficulty of obtaining votes versus receipts. The results suggest that it is easier to garner a negligible amount of votes than it is to raise a negligible amount of receipts, perhaps because voters use different criteria than donors when deciding who to support.

The main finding is that when competition is viewed through the lens of fundraising, it looks significantly worse than vote share measures suggest. The likelihood that primaries are competitive decreases across race types, with the largest difference emerging in open seats. The notion that several viable candidates are vigorously competing for voter support is not borne out when competition is measured with fundraising patterns. In open seats—the best-case scenarios of competition—the effective number of primary candidates decreases by nearly half in advantaged-party districts and by 40% in competitive districts. Moreover, comparisons with the same vote and receipt margin thresholds and with weighted vote and receipt shares similarly reveal lower levels of competition with the fundraising measures. Much of the disparity between vote share and fundraising measures is driven by candidates who have little chance of winning.

Primaries have attracted more attention in recent years due to the decline in competitive general elections and the notion that the heart of competition has shifted to the primary stage. The findings in open seats are thus particularly troublesome due to the role these primaries play in ensuring that elected officials face high-quality competition before they are selected initially. Although some have also uncovered negative consequences of close elections, democratic governments are premised on electoral contestation. It may be difficult to agree on how competitive our elections should be or how many elections ought to be close, but the sheer volume of work in this area reflects a broader assumption that, at some point either prior to or during an officeholder’s tenure, there is a clear normative benefit of close elections. The lower levels of competition across the fundraising measures is concerning because of the fundamental role that competition plays in American democracy.

Fundraising is likely to remain central to candidate viability in the years to come. Calls for campaign finance reform have gained momentum as the amount of money in elections continues to soar. Reformers face a difficult task of balancing various democratic priorities with the potential implications for legislative institutions. As Pildes (Reference Pildes2021) notes in a recent New York Times editorial, “Campaign-finance efforts are now rightly focused on ‘leveling up’ campaign dollars—by providing public funds to candidates—rather than trying to ‘level down’ by imposing caps on election spending.” At the heart of efforts to increase access to campaign dollars is the concern that fundraising hurdles hinder those with fewer resources from seeking office or mounting a competitive campaign. At the same time, Pildes (Reference Pildes2021) argues that we must focus not only on the values of participation or equality but also on the overall effects of reforms on political extremism and moderation. The growing influence of small donors may induce more extreme candidates to run and help them to win, and the rise in safe seats further increases the stakes of fundraising in primary elections for the selection of officeholders.

Beyond the study of competition, fundraising measures open up new opportunities to examine questions that would be difficult or impossible to look at with vote totals. For one, because money is a good indicator of success, preelection fundraising metrics can be used to study primary outcomes where the party cue plays a limited role (i.e., Bonica Reference Bonica2017; Reference Bonica2020). We can leverage quarterly reports to analyze how resource disparities shape dropout decisions and incorporate demographic variables to see which candidates have a fundraising advantage in the preprimary stage. Second, because campaign receipts can be aggregated in several ways, money can shed light on differences among elected officials across contexts (Powell Reference Powell2012; Weschle Reference Weschle2022). In the US, lawmaker influence is unlikely to be associated with vote shares, but fundraising has been linked to the distribution of party goods (i.e., Heberlig, Hetherington, and Larson Reference Heberlig, Hetherington and Larson2006; Kistner Reference Kistner2022; Powell and Grimmer Reference Powell and Grimmer2016). As long as money matters in American politics, fundraising measures of viability and strength allow us to explore a variety of questions about elections and representation.

SUPPLEMENTARY MATERIALS

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit http://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055422000764.

DATA AVAILABILITY STATEMENT

Research documentation and data that support the findings of this study are available at the American Political Science Review Dataverse: https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/RTGDFW.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

This paper was presented at the annual meetings of the American Political Science Association and the Midwest Political Science Association. I am grateful to John Aldrich, Bernie Grofman, Hans Hassell, Seth Hill, Gary Jacobson, Patricia Kirkland, Josh Yoshio Lerner, Neil Malhotra, Ken Miller, Kevin Munger, Spencer Piston, Rachel Potter, William Smith, Rein Taagepera, Michael Tesler, Simon Weschle, Antoine Yoshinaka, and Hye Young You, as well as to seminar participants at Texas A&M University, University of Tennessee, and University of California, Irvine for helpful comments and feedback.

CONFLICT OF INTEREST

The author declares no ethical issues or conflicts of interest in this research.

ETHICAL STANDARDS

The author affirms this research did not involve human subjects.

Footnotes

1 Others have instead examined the influence of competition on a host of political outcomes such as voter turnout, political engagement, and government responsiveness (i.e., Ansolabehere, Brady, and Fiorina Reference Ansolabehere, Brady and Fiorina1992; Cox and Munger Reference Cox and Munger1989; Gimpel, Kaufmann, and Pearson-Merkowitz Reference Gimpel, Kaufmann and Pearson-Merkowitz2007; Griffin Reference Griffin2006; Lipsitz Reference Lipsitz2011; Patterson and Caldeira Reference Patterson and Caldeira1983).

2 Scholars of presidential nominations have given significant attention to the “money primary,” or the competition for financial resources prior to the election, and its implications for viability and success (i.e., Adkins and Dowdle Reference Adkins and Dowdle2002; Aldrich Reference Aldrich1980; Feigenbaum and Shelton Reference Feigenbaum and Shelton2013; Goff Reference Goff2005; Mayer Reference Mayer2003; Norrander Reference Norrander2006).

3 Candidates raise as much or more today before the primary than general election candidates did in the 1980s. The top fundraiser in opposed primaries raised an average of $196,000 in 1980, compared with $1.1 million in 2020—an increase of more than fivefold. What is more, this average includes primary winners who are unlikely to win the general election. The top-raising general election candidate, who is likely to be elected, raised an average of $239,000 in preprimary funds in 1980, compared with $1.5 million in 2020 (all in 2020 dollars). The million dollar price tag of primary elections would have been unforeseen by the earliest reformers who set total spending limits several times lower than this amount.

4 Scholars have examined the relationship between money and election outcomes since the FEC began collecting data in the 1970s. Most agree that challenger spending is positively associated with House and Senate outcomes (but see Levitt Reference Levitt1994), though the marginal returns to incumbents have been a contested subject of debate (Gerber Reference Gerber1998; Green and Krasno Reference Green and Krasno1988; Reference Green and Krasno1990; Jacobson Reference Jacobson1980, Reference Jacobson1990; Krasno and Green Reference Krasno and Green1988). Money has also been incorporated into measures of quality (Bond, Covington, and Fleisher Reference Bond, Covington and Fleisher1985; Ragsdale and Cook Reference Ragsdale and Cook1987), but the core difficulty of using expenditures to measure quality is that it mixes ability with the expected outcome. More recently, Bonica (Reference Bonica2017; Reference Bonica2020) argues that previous studies showing minimal returns of fundraising reflect a focus on general elections, and he uncovers a substantial effect of early money in primaries.

5 Whereas 42% of House members were elected from safe districts in the 1980s, this figure rose to 68% in the 2010s. Among winners in open seats, 50% and 63% came from safe districts in the 1980s and 2010s, respectively. However, I also examine fundraising and vote share measures of competition in general elections, and competition looks better with vote share measures than with fundraising measures in general elections as well. A discussion of general elections is provided in the Appendix.

6 Candidates run for office for many reasons. Underdogs who show an impressive ability to fundraise but lose can put a race on the map, increase attention to various issues, and reap professional rewards in the future. Previous work has examined what motivates long-shot candidates to run (i.e., Banks and Kiewiet Reference Banks and Kiewiet1989; Boatright Reference Boatright2004; Canon Reference Canon1993; Fishel Reference Fishel1973; Fowler and McClure Reference Fowler and McClure1989; Huckshorn and Spencer Reference Huckshorn and Spencer1971; Kazee Reference Kazee1994; Maisel Reference Maisel1982), but that question is beyond the scope of this article.

7 There is a large body of research on the decline in close general elections and the increase in the incumbency advantage (i.e., Abramowitz Reference Abramowitz1991; Abramowitz, Alexander, and Gunning Reference Abramowitz, Alexander and Gunning2006; Alford and Hibbing Reference Alford and Hibbing1981; Ansolabehere, Brady, and Fiorina Reference Ansolabehere, Brady and Fiorina1992; Cox and Katz Reference Cox and Katz1996; Erikson Reference Erikson1971; Reference Erikson1972; Ferejohn Reference Ferejohn1977; Fiorina Reference Fiorina1977; Gelman and King Reference Gelman and King1990; Jacobson Reference Jacobson1987; Mayhew Reference Mayhew1974; Tufte Reference Tufte1973; see Jacobson Reference Jacobson2015 for a recent update).

8 The victory rates of opposed incumbents and nonincumbents who raise the most are 98% and 69%, respectively. The rare incumbents who lose raise an average of 52% of preprimary receipts, compared with opposed winning incumbents who raise an average of 90%. This sizable difference between winning and losing incumbents suggests that fundraising patterns are a good reflection of incumbent vulnerability as well.

9 Similarly, at the race level, the difference between the top two fundraisers is larger than that between the top two vote-getters. In opposed races, the average difference between the top two fundraisers is 66 points, compared with 36 points between the top two vote-getters; in the full sample, the average difference between the top two fundraisers and vote-getters is 85 points and 72 points, respectively.

10 Only 5% of candidates who raised less than 10% of preprimary receipts won the primary. In advantaged-party open seats, this figure is lower, at 3%. Of the 461 total primary winners who won with less than 10% of receipts, 346, or 75%, won in challenger-party primaries; only 6 of the 346 won in the general election. It is appropriate to describe those who raise less than 10% of receipts as long shots.

11 Vote totals also understate the advantage of fundraisers at the top. Opposed candidates who raise more than 90% of receipts receive an average of 72% of the vote, and the correlation is 0.12. Yet 74% of candidates who raise more than 90% of receipts are unopposed. When unopposed candidates are included, the average vote share is 93%. Most of the difference between measures of competition is driven by long-shot candidates because the vote share and fundraising values are the same in unopposed races.

12 Unlike traditional scatter plots, binned scatter plots are not a visualization of the entire dataset (Cattaneo et al. Reference Cattaneo, Crump, Farrell and Feng2019). A traditional scatter plot obscures the relationship between money and votes due to the size of the dataset, but Figure 1 does not effectively convey the distribution of candidates at the low and high ends of fundraising. The distribution matters for our expectations of where vote share and fundraising measures are likely to differ. Histograms of primary receipt share are provided in Figure A3.

13 The top two vote-getters received an average of 47% and 27% of the vote, and the top two fundraisers raised an average of 54% and 25% of receipts. The disparity between the top two vote-getters and the top two fundraisers is smaller in open seats than it is in challenger-party and incumbent-contested races, but both fundraising and vote share measures are well above the thresholds of competitiveness in the vast majority of challenger-party and incumbent-contested races.

14 The 57.5% threshold is from Hirano and Snyder (Reference Hirano and Snyder2019) and follows previous work on general election competition. Ninety-five percent of candidates who raise at least 57.5% of receipts won the primary. Ninety-one percent of candidates whose receipt share is more than 20 percentage points lower than the top fundraiser’s share lost the primary; of the 9% whose receipt share is more than 20 points lower than the top fundraiser’s share but won, three-fourths lost in the general election. I also examined a measure of whether the winner raised less than 57.5% of receipts and whether the winner’s fundraising margin is within 20 points of the top-raising loser. The results are the same, but I use preelection data here for the fundraising measures. In addition, I use Herfindahl measures of competition calculated with vote and receipt shares, and the results are the same (see Figure A9).

15 The average difference between the top two vote-getters when the top vote-getter won with less than 57.5% of the primary vote is 12 points, ranging from 0.01 to 44 points. Twenty-one percent of the top vote-getters who won with less than 57.5% of the primary vote won by more than 20 points. Even in opposed open-seat primaries in safe districts, the average difference between the top two vote-getters when the top vote-getter won with less than 57.5% of the primary vote is 12 points, ranging from 0.03 to 41 points.

16 Scholars of comparative politics have given significant attention to what counts as a political party (i.e., Cox Reference Cox1997; Laakso and Taagepera Reference Laakso and Taagepera1979; Lijphart Reference Lijphart1994; Molinar Reference Molinar1991; Taagepera and Shugart Reference Taagepera and Shugart1993) and to measuring competition across electoral systems (i.e., Blais and Lago Reference Blais and Lago2009; Cox, Fiva, and Smith Reference Cox, Fiva and Smith2020; Folke Reference Folke2014; Grofman and Selb Reference Grofman and Selb2011). Yet this line of research similarly draws on vote or seat shares, whereas I use preelection resource disparities. One recent exception is a measure of effective spending in UK elections by Fouirnaies (Reference Fouirnaies2021).

17 The 1974 amendments to the Federal Election Campaign Act (FECA) established the Federal Election Commission (FEC), which administers the reporting system for campaign finance disclosures. For a brief history of federal campaign finance laws, see https://transition.fec.gov/info/appfour.htm.

18 Dropouts are included if they raised money in the same election cycle they registered with the FEC, and they comprise 6% of the sample. Incumbents who raised money but retired are excluded from the dataset.

19 The dataset also includes overall fundraising totals from the DIME data, which allows for additional checks on preprimary values. Virtually all of those in the DIME dataset who raise no money did not file preprimary reports, which increases our confidence in the zero values of preprimary receipts in these cases.

20 Of the 33,100 candidates in the dataset, 25,100 have nonzero values of preprimary receipts and of total receipts. Another 6,200 have zero values of preprimary receipts and of total receipts. The preprimary receipts are correlated with total receipts at 0.90; for primary losers (who thus did not continue to raise money after the primary), this increases to 0.96. There are approximately 1,800 candidates with nonzero values of total receipts but zero values of preprimary receipts. Of these 1,800 candidates, 700 were unopposed primary winners; these races are coded as uncompetitive with one candidate in the race. The preprimary figures were further validated by summing all of the reports filed by the candidate in a cycle and matching these totals to their overall totals. This ensures that the zero values in the preprimary stage are zero values rather than an error. In the analyses below, 354 of the 16,635 primaries have missing values on the fundraising measures because no candidate in the primary reported raising money. In other analyses, I followed Jacobson (Reference Jacobson1990) and imputed $5,000 for all candidates who did not file fundraising reports. The findings are the same because $5,000 is still very low, but this assumption is more of a stretch for primary candidates who do not file reports.

21 In the 1980s and 1990s, candidates sometimes filed midyear reports instead of quarterly reports; I use midyear reports when quarterly reports are not available. Candidates who did not file a preprimary report or any quarterly report before the primary and were not unopposed primary winners are coded as raising no money.

22 Like Hirano and Snyder (Reference Hirano and Snyder2019, 39), primaries in which no candidate ran for the nomination are counted as uncontested, with zero candidates on the ballot and zero effective candidates. Unlike them, I include cases in which a nomination was made by convention and count these as uncontested; however, they note that the patterns are similar when conventions are excluded or counted as uncontested. The 13 cases in which the general election winner or future general election winner (i.e., Bernie Sanders in 1988) is an Independent are also excluded. It is unclear how Hirano and Snyder (Reference Hirano and Snyder2019) code blanket primaries; here they are considered by party in order to account for district partisanship. Because vote totals are tabulated at the primary level in blanket primaries, the total number of candidates is calculated at the primary level as well, so the average number of candidates is higher. The results are the same if blanket primaries are excluded.

23 I use Jacobson’s presidential vote share data to measure district partisanship.

24 Like Hirano and Snyder (Reference Hirano and Snyder2019, 39), I exclude advantaged-party challenger-party primaries and disadvantaged-party incumbent-contested primaries. The full sample of 18,270—2 primaries in 435 districts over 21 cycles—diminishes by 1,647 as a result; 26 primaries with Independent general election winners are excluded; 2 primaries in South Dakota’s 2nd district in 1980 are excluded because the district was abolished in 1982; and an additional 40 duplicate primaries when districts were redrawn or a special election was held (i.e., Texas in 1996 and 2006; Ohio in 1992, 2006, and 2010) are included. The number of observations in the vote share models is 16,635.

25 The effective number of candidates based on receipts is correlated with the total number of candidates and the effective number of candidates based on votes at 0.76 and 0.82, respectively.

26 There is a slight distinction between earlier research on the relationship between spending and general election vote shares and more recent work on the relationship between fundraising and primary vote shares. Fundraising totals are used far more frequently to convey viability than are disbursement totals, so I focus on fundraising. I also created measures of competition with preprimary disbursements, and the results are the same (see Table A3, Table A4, and Figure A7). Preprimary disbursements are correlated with preprimary receipts at 0.93, so the similarity is unsurprising. In addition, I constructed measures of competition by contribution type—those from individuals, PACs, and limited to itemized receipts—in light of Reynolds and Hall’s (Reference Reynolds, Hall and Magleby2019) finding that House incumbents receive more from PACs than do challengers and open-seat candidates, and the patterns are the same.

27 The total number of candidates is slightly lower than that in Hirano and Snyder (Reference Hirano and Snyder2019, 181) because disadvantaged-party primaries are excluded from their figures.

28 Of the 7,765 incumbent-contested primaries, 444 and 207 are competitive with the 57.5% vote share and fundraising measures, respectively. Of the 7,164 challenger-party primaries, 1,338 and 479 are competitive with the vote share and fundraising measures, respectively. Of the 1,706 open-seat primaries, 938 and 676 are competitive with the vote share and fundraising measures, respectively. In the full sample of 16,635 primaries, 2,720 are competitive with the vote share measures, compared with 1,362 with the fundraising measures (or 16% and 8% of primaries, respectively). The number of primaries that are competitive is low with the vote share measures, but it is significantly lower with the fundraising measures.

29 I also ran the analyses without dropouts, and the results are the same. Dropout candidates are included because the measure of competition is rooted in resource disparities, and candidates can amass resources without appearing on the ballot. The models without dropouts are provided in Tables A8, A9, and A10. In other analyses, I accounted for party and group activity in the race. I use Hassell’s (Reference Hassell2021) data to control for the number of party-connected donors and FEC data to control for party coordinated expenditures and independent expenditures before the primary (Tables A11 and A12). The insignificant relationships are unsurprising. As Hassell shows, factors like seat type and district partisanship influence party engagement.

30 The graphs follow the format in Hirano and Snyder (Reference Hirano and Snyder2019; see Figure A4). The main comparisons are with the top right (percentage of competitive races) and bottom left (number of candidates) graphs. Their two other measures—whether the race was contested and the total vote percentage to losing candidates—are not incorporated here. The measure of whether there is any candidate in the race is an exceedingly low standard. The measure of the total vote percentage to losing candidates also reveals higher levels of competition than does a similar measure based on fundraising, but I focus on the top candidate’s advantage and the number of competitors. The number of candidates in open seats is slightly lower in their graphs, which is likely due to differences in the periods of study. Their data extend from 1950 to 2016, whereas the data here are from 1980 to 2020 when the number of candidates in open-seat primaries is higher (Hirano and Snyder Reference Hirano and Snyder2019, 183). However, the patterns are clearly similar. I focus on the expected difference between the measures, but the predicted values in Tables 1 and 2 are plotted in Figures A5 and A6, respectively.

31 Of the 481 advantaged-party open-seat primaries in the dataset, 339 are competitive with the 57.5% vote share measure, compared with 277 with the 57.5% fundraising measure. Of the 744 parties-balanced open seats, 413 are competitive with the 57.5% vote share measure, versus 296 with the 57.5% fundraising measure.

32 More specifically, we are interested in the number of long-shot candidates whose vote share is higher than their receipt share. Ninety-six percent of long shots outperform their receipt share, so I use this simpler measure of the number of candidates who raise less than 10% of receipts. Similarly, the total number of long shots and the total number of long shots who outperform their receipt share are correlated at 0.98.

33 However, several studies illustrate that the high price tag of running for Congress deters some potential candidates more than others (Bonica Reference Bonica2020; Carnes Reference Carnes2018; Hall Reference Hall2019).

34 I also provide a brief discussion of overall levels of primary and general election competition and address whether primaries are effective substitutes for the decline in general election competition (see Figure A12).

35 Long shots in general elections also matter in different ways for the competition variables because there are only two candidates. In particular, they are likely to increase the difference between the number of candidate measures, but general elections with long shots are unlikely to be competitive with either the vote share or fundraising measure. Here our main interest is in overall differences between the two measures.

References

Abramowitz, Alan I. 1991. “Incumbency, Campaign Spending, and the Decline of Competition in U.S. House Elections.” Journal of Politics 53 (1): 3456.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abramowitz, Alan I., Alexander, Brad, and Gunning, Matthew. 2006. “Incumbency, Redistricting, and the Decline of Competition in U.S. House Elections.” Journal of Politics 68 (1): 7588.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Achen, Christopher H., and Bartels, Larry M.. 2016. Democracy for Realists: Why Elections Do Not Produce Responsive Government. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adkins, Randall E., and Dowdle, Andrew J.. 2002. “The Money Primary: What Influences the Outcome of Pre-Primary Presidential Nomination Fundraising?Presidential Studies Quarterly 32 (2): 256–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aldrich, John H. 1980. Before the Convention: Strategies and Choices in Presidential Nomination Campaigns. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alford, John R., and Hibbing, John R.. 1981. “Increased Incumbency Advantage in the House.” Journal of Politics 43 (4): 1042–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alvarez, R. Michael, Katz, Jonathan N., and Kim, Seo-young Silvia. 2020. “Hidden Donors: The Censoring Problem in U.S. Federal Campaign Finance Data.” Election Law Journal: Rules, Politics, and Policy 19 (1): 118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ansolabehere, Stephen, Brady, David, and Fiorina, Morris. 1992. “The Vanishing Marginals and Electoral Responsiveness.” British Journal of Political Science 22 (1): 2138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ansolabehere, Stephen, Snyder, James M. Jr., and Stewart, Charles III. 2001. “Candidate Positioning in U.S. House Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 45 (1): 136–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arceneaux, Kevin, Dunaway, Johanna, Johnson, Martin, and Wielen, Ryan J. Vander. 2020. “Strategic Candidate Entry and Congressional Elections in the Era of Fox News.” American Journal of Political Science 64 (2): 398415.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banks, Jeffrey S., and Kiewiet, D. Roderick. 1989. “Explaining Patterns of Candidate Competition in Congressional Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 33 (4): 9971015.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Biersack, Robert, Herrnson, Paul S., and Wilcox, Clyde. 1993. “Seeds for Success: Early Money in Congressional Elections.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 18 (4): 535–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blais, André, and Lago, Ignacio. 2009. “A General Measure of District Competitiveness.” Electoral Studies 28 (1): 94100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boatright, Robert G. 2004. Expressive Politics: Issue Strategies of Congressional Challengers. Columbus: Ohio State University Press.Google Scholar
Bond, Jon R., Covington, Cary, and Fleisher, Richard. 1985. “Explaining Challenger Quality in Congressional Elections.” Journal of Politics 47 (2): 510–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonica, Adam. 2014. “Mapping the Ideological Marketplace.” American Journal of Political Science 58 (2): 367–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonica, Adam. 2017. “Professional Networks, Early Fundraising, and Electoral Success.” Election Law Journal: Rules, Politics, and Policy 16 (1): 153–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonica, Adam. 2020. “Why Are There so Many Lawyers in Congress?Legislative Studies Quarterly 45 (2): 253–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonica, Adam, and Cox, Gary W.. 2018. “Ideological Extremists in the U.S. Congress: Out of Step but Still in Office.” Quarterly Journal of Political Science 13 (2): 207–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Canes-Wrone, Brandice, Brady, David W., and Cogan, John F.. 2002. “Out of Step, out of Office: Electoral Accountability and House Members’ Voting.” American Political Science Review 96 (1): 127–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Canes-Wrone, Brandice, and Miller, Kenneth M.. 2022. “Out-of-District Contributors and Representation in the US House.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 47 (2): 361–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Canon, David T. 1993. “Sacrificial Lambs or Strategic Politicians? Political Amateurs in U.S. House Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 37 (4): 1119–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carnes, Nicholas. 2018. The Cash Ceiling: Why Only the Rich Run for Office–and What We Can Do about It. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Cattaneo, Matias D., Crump, Richard K., Farrell, Max H., and Feng, Yingjie. 2019. “On Binscatter.” FRB of New York Staff Report No. 881, February 1, 2019; Rev. August 2021. https://ssrn.com/abstract=3344739 or http://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3344739.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Center for Responsive Politics. 2020. “Did Money Win?” Open Secrets. https://www.opensecrets.org/elections-overview/winning-vs-spending?cycle=2020.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary W. 1997. Making Votes Count: Strategic Coordination in the World’s Electoral Systems. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Gary W., and Katz, Jonathan N.. 1996. “Why Did the Incumbency Advantage in U.S. House Elections Grow?American Journal of Political Science 40 (2): 478–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Gary W., Fiva, Jon H., and Smith, Daniel M.. 2020. “Measuring the Competitiveness of Elections.” Political Analysis 28 (2): 168–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Gary W., and Munger, Michael C.. 1989. “Closeness, Expenditures, and Turnout in the 1982 U.S. House Elections.” American Political Science Review 83 (1): 217–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dahl, Robert A. 1956. A Preface to Democratic Theory. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Dahl, Robert A. 1971. Polyarchy: Participation and Opposition. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Dittmar, Kelly. 2020. “Urgency and Ambition: The Influence of Political Environment and Emotion in Spurring US Women’s Candidacies in 2018.” European Journal of Politics and Gender 3 (1): 143–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Erikson, Robert S. 1971. “The Advantage of Incumbency in Congressional Elections.” Polity 3 (3): 395405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Erikson, Robert S. 1972. “Malapportionment, Gerrymandering, and Party Fortunes in Congressional Elections.” American Political Science Review 66 (4): 1234–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feigenbaum, James J., and Shelton, Cameron A.. 2013. “The Vicious Cycle: Fundraising and Perceived Viability in US Presidential Primaries.” Quarterly Journal of Political Science 8 (1): 140.Google Scholar
Ferejohn, John A. 1977. “On the Decline of Competition in Congressional Elections.” American Political Science Review 71 (1): 166–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiorina, Morris P. 1977. “The Case of the Vanishing Marginals: The Bureaucracy Did It.” American Political Science Review 71 (1): 177–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fishel, Jeff. 1973. Party and Opposition: Congressional Challengers in American Politics. New York: David McKay Company.Google Scholar
Folke, Olle. 2014. “Shades of Brown and Green: Party Effects in Proportional Election Systems.” Journal of the European Economic Association 12 (5): 1361–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fouirnaies, Alexander. 2021. “How Do Campaign Spending Limits Affect Elections? Evidence from the United Kingdom 1885– 2019.” American Political Science Review 115 (2): 395411.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fowler, Linda. 1993. Candidates, Congress, and the American Democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fowler, Linda L., and McClure, Robert D.. 1989. Political Ambition: Who Decides to Run for Congress. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Fraga, Bernard L., and Hersh, Eitan D.. 2018. “Are Americans Stuck in Uncompetitive Enclaves? An Appraisal of U.S. Electoral Competition.” Quarterly Journal of Political Science 13 (3): 291311.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gelman, Andrew, and King, Gary. 1990. “Estimating Incumbency Advantage without Bias.” American Journal of Political Science 34 (4): 1142–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gelman, Andrew, and King, Gary. 1993. “Why Are American Presidential Election Campaign Polls So Variable When Votes Are So Predictable?British Journal of Political Science 23 (4): 409–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerber, Alan. 1998. “Estimating the Effect of Campaign Spending on Senate Election Outcomes Using Instrumental Variables.” American Political Science Review 92 (2): 401–11.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gimpel, James G., Kaufmann, Karen M., and Pearson-Merkowitz, Shanna. 2007. “Battleground States versus Blackout States: The Behavioral Implications of Modern Presidential Campaigns.” Journal of Politics 69 (3): 786–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gimpel, James G., Lee, Frances E., and Pearson-Merkowitz, Shanna. 2008. “The Check Is in the Mail: Interdistrict Funding Flows in Congressional Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 52 (2): 373–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goff, Michael J. 2005. The Money Primary: The New Politics of the Early Presidential Nomination Process. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield.Google Scholar
Graber, Doris A., and Dunaway, Johanna. 2017. Mass Media and American Politics. Washington, DC: CQ Press.Google Scholar
Green, Donald Philip, and Krasno, Jonathan S.. 1988. “Salvation for the Spendthrift Incumbent: Reestimating the Effects of Campaign Spending in House Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 32 (4): 884907.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Green, Donald Philip, and Krasno, Jonathan S.. 1990. “Rebuttal to Jacobson’s ‘New Evidence for Old Arguments.’American Journal of Political Science 34 (2): 363–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Griffin, John D. 2006. “Electoral Competition and Democratic Responsiveness: A Defense of the Marginality Hypothesis.” Journal of Politics 68 (4): 911–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grofman, Bernard, and Selb, Peter. 2011. “Turnout and the (Effective) Number of Parties at the National and District Levels: A Puzzle-Solving Approach.” Party Politics 17 (1): 93117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Andrew B. 2019. Who Wants to Run? How the Devaluing of Political Office Drives Polarization. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hassell, Hans J. G. 2021. “Party Elite Engagement and Coordination in House Primary Elections: A Test of Theories of Parties.” American Journal of Political Science. https://doi.org/10.1111/ajps.12680.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heberlig, Eric, Hetherington, Marc, and Larson, Bruce. 2006. “The Price of Leadership: Campaign Money and the Polarization of Congressional Parties.” Journal of Politics 68 (4): 9921005.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirano, Shigeo, and Snyder, James M. Jr. 2019. Primary Elections in the United States. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huckshorn, Robert Jack, and Spencer, Robert C.. 1971. The Politics of Defeat: Campaigning for Congress. Amherst: University of Massachusetts Press.Google Scholar
Jacobson, Gary C. 1980. Money in Congressional Elections. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Jacobson, Gary C. 1987. “The Marginals Never Vanished: Incumbency and Competition in Elections to the U.S. House of Representatives, 1952-82.” American Journal of Political Science 31 (1): 126–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacobson, Gary C. 1989. “Strategic Politicians and the Dynamics of U.S. House Elections, 1946-86.” American Political Science Review 83 (3): 773–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacobson, Gary C. 1990. “The Effects of Campaign Spending in House Elections: New Evidence for Old Arguments.” American Journal of Political Science 34 (2): 334–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacobson, Gary C. 2015. “It’s Nothing Personal: The Decline of the Incumbency Advantage in US House Elections.” Journal of Politics 77 (3): 861–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaslovsky, Jaclyn. 2022. “Senators at Home: Local Attentiveness and Policy Representation in Congress.” American Political Science Review 116 (2): 645–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kazee, Thomas A. 1994. Who Runs for Congress? Ambition, Context, and Candidate Emergence. Washington, DC: CQ Press.Google Scholar
Key, V. O. Jr. 1949. Southern Politics in State and Nation. New York: A. A. Knopf.Google Scholar
Kim, Seo-young Silvia. 2022. “How Much to Ask? Platforms, Parties, and Suggested Amounts in Political Fundraising.” Paper presented at the 2022 meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago, IL.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirkland, Patricia A. 2021. “Business Owners and Executives as Politicians: The Effect on Public Policy.” Journal of Politics 83 (4): 1652–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kistner, Michael. 2022. “Fighting for Majorities? Explaining the Development of Caucus Fund-Raising in American Legislatures.” Journal of Politics 84 (1): 321–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krasno, Jonathan S., and Green, Donald Philip. 1988. “Preempting Quality Challengers in House Elections.” Journal of Politics 50 (4): 920–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krasno, Jonathan S., Green, Donald Philip, and Cowden, Jonathan A.. 1994. “The Dynamics of Campaign Fundraising in House Elections.” Journal of Politics 56 (2): 459–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
La Raja, Raymond J. 2007. “Sunshine Laws and the Press: The Effect of Campaign Disclosure on News Reporting in the American States.” Election Law Journal: Rules, Politics, and Policy 6 (3): 236–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laakso, Markku, and Taagepera, Rein. 1979. “‘Effective’ Number of Parties: A Measure with Application to West Europe.” Comparative Political Studies 12 (1): 327.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levitt, Steven D. 1994. “Using Repeat Challengers to Estimate the Effect of Campaign Spending on Election Outcomes in the U.S. House.” Journal of Political Economy 102 (4): 777–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lijphart, Arend. 1994. Electoral Systems and Party Systems: A Study of Twenty-Seven Democracies, 1945-1990. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lipsitz, Keena. 2011. Competitive Elections and the American Voter. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Magleby, David B. 2019. Financing the 2016 Election. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.Google Scholar
Magleby, David B., Goodliffe, Jay, and Olsen, Joseph A.. 2018. Who Donates in Campaigns? The Importance of Message, Messenger, Medium, and Structure. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maisel, Louis Sandy. 1982. From Obscurity to Oblivion: Running in the Congressional Primary. Knoxville: University of Tennessee Press.Google Scholar
Mayer, William G. 2003. “Forecasting Presidential Nominations or, My Model Worked Just Fine, Thank You.” PS: Political Science & Politics 36 (2): 153–57.Google Scholar
Mayhew, David R. 1974. “Congressional Elections: The Case of the Vanishing Marginals.” Polity 6 (3): 295317.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Molinar, Juan. 1991. “Counting the Number of Parties: An Alternative Index.” American Political Science Review 85 (4): 1383–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norrander, Barbara. 2006. “The Attrition Game: Initial Resources, Initial Contests and the Exit of Candidates during the US Presidential Primary Season.” British Journal of Political Science 36 (3): 487507.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patterson, Samuel C., and Caldeira, Gregory A.. 1983. “Getting out the Vote: Participation in Gubernatorial Elections.” American Political Science Review 77 (3): 675–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pildes, Richard H. 2021. “Opinion—How to Keep Extremists out of Power.” The New York Times, February 25. https://www.nytimes.com/2021/02/25/opinion/elections-politics-extremists.html.Google Scholar
Porter, Rachel A., and Treul, Sarah A.. 2018. “The Increasing Value of Inexperience in Congressional Primaries.” Paper presented at the 2018 meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago, IL.Google Scholar
Powell, Eleanor Neff, and Grimmer, Justin. 2016. “Money in Exile: Campaign Contributions and Committee Access.” Journal of Politics 78 (4): 974–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powell, Lynda W. 2012. The Influence of Campaign Contributions in State Legislatures: The Effects of Institutions and Politics. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ragsdale, Lyn, and Cook, Timothy E.. 1987. “Representatives’ Actions and Challengers’ Reactions: Limits to Candidate Connections in the House.” American Journal of Political Science 31 (1): 4581.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reynolds, Molly E., and Hall, Richard L.. 2019. “Financing the 2016 Congressional Election.” In Financing the 2016 Election, ed. Magleby, David B., 217–49. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.Google Scholar
Schlesinger, Joseph A. 1966. Ambition and Politics: Political Careers in the United States. Chicago, IL: Rand MacNally.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1942. Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy. New York: Harper and Bros.Google Scholar
Scott, Jamil, Dickinson, Kesicia, Lajevardi, Nazita, and Olson, Shayla. 2019. “Supply and Demand in 2018.” Paper presented at the 2019 Politics of Race, Immigration, and Ethnicity Consortium (PRIEC), St. Louis, MO.Google Scholar
Skelley, Geoffrey. 2021. “Why Candidates with Little Hope of Winning Are Raising More Money Than Ever.” FiveThirtyEight, August 26. https://fivethirtyeight.com/features/why-long-shot-candidates-are-raising-more-money-than-ever/.Google Scholar
Taagepera, Rein, and Shugart, Matthew Soberg. 1993. “Predicting the Number of Parties: A Quantitative Model of Duverger’s Mechanical Effect.” American Political Science Review 87 (2): 455–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomsen, Danielle M. 2017. Opting out of Congress: Partisan Polarization and the Decline of Moderate Candidates. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomsen, Danielle M. 2021. “Women Running, Women Winning: Voter Preferences in 2018.” In Congress Reconsidered, 12th edition, eds. Dodd, Lawrence C., Oppenheimer, Bruce I., and Evans, C. Lawrence, 133166. Washington, DC: CQ Press.Google Scholar
Thomsen, Danielle M. 2022. “Replication Data for Competition in Congressional Elections: Money versus Votes.” Harvard Dataverse. Dataset. https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/RTGDFW.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tufte, Edward R. 1973. “The Relationship between Seats and Votes in Two-Party Systems.” American Political Science Review 67 (2): 540–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weschle, Simon. 2022. Money in Politics: Self-Enrichment, Campaign Spending, and Golden Parachutes. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Relationship between Primary Receipt Share and Vote ShareNote: The left graph shows a binned scatter plot of the relationship between primary receipt share and vote share for U.S. House candidates from 1980 to 2020. The right graph excludes unopposed candidates. The lower correlation between receipt share and vote share among long-shot candidates provides motivation for why vote share and fundraising measures of competition are likely to differ.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Measures of Primary Competition over Time and By Seat TypeNote: The top graphs show the percentage of primaries where the top vote-getter received less than 57.5% of total votes and where the top fundraiser raised less than 57.5% of total receipts. The bottom graphs show the number of candidates on the ballot and the effective number of candidates calculated with preprimary receipts.

Figure 2

Table 1. Likelihood of Competitive Primary with Votes and Receipts

Figure 3

Table 2. Expected Number of Candidates with Votes and Receipts

Figure 4

Figure 3. Difference between Vote Share and Fundraising Measures of Competition, by Race TypeNote: Predicted values are calculated from the models in Table A2. The top graphs show the probability the primary is competitive with the vote share measure but not the fundraising measure (for the 57.5% and 20-point margin measures, respectively). The bottom graphs show the difference between the total and effective number of candidates (based on receipts) and the difference between the effective number of candidates based on votes and receipts, respectively. Across measures, primaries are more competitive with vote share measures than with fundraising measures.

Figure 5

Table 3. Relationship between Long Shots and Difference between Measures

Figure 6

Figure 4. Difference between Measures, by Number of Long ShotsNote: Predicted values are calculated from the models in Table 3. The top graphs show the probability the primary is competitive with the vote share measure but not the fundraising measure (for the 57.5% and 20-point margin measures, respectively). The bottom graphs show the difference between the total and effective number of candidates (based on receipts) and the difference between the effective number of candidates based on votes and receipts, respectively. The disparity between vote share and fundraising measures is driven largely by long-shot candidates.

Supplementary material: PDF

Thomsen supplementary material

Appendix

Download Thomsen supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 1.2 MB
Supplementary material: Link

Thomsen Dataset

Link