Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-wq2xx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-20T05:07:11.911Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

9 - Emotional Reactions to Law and Economics, Market Metaphors, and Rationality Rhetoric

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 July 2009

Mark D. White
Affiliation:
City University of New York
Get access

Summary

This chapter makes three fundamental points about law and economics. First, some people have strong, negative emotional reactions to utilizing microeconomics to analyze nonbusiness areas of law, whereas others have no such reactions. This chapter advances the hypothesis that people who do not view the world through an economics lens are likely to experience negative feelings toward applying microeconomics to nonbusiness law areas, whereas people who view the world through an economics lens are unlikely to do so. Second, while law and economics remains an uncontroversial subfield of applied microeconomics, it has become a dominant yet controversial field of scholarship in legal academia. This chapter proposes that differences in how most academic and professional economists perceive law and economics versus how most academic and professional lawyers perceive law and economics are due primarily to differences in how familiar they are with microeconomics presented in a mathematically rigorous fashion. Third, much research considerably and significantly qualifies many well-known and often quoted alleged benefits of competitive markets and unbounded rationality. People who comprehend this research appreciate that the extent to which markets and rationality are socially desirable is more complicated than people who do not understand this research often suggest. This research involves traditional microeconomics, behavioral economics, cognitive psychology, social psychology, and neuroeconomics.

EMOTIONAL AND UNEMOTIONAL REACTIONS TO LAW AND ECONOMICS

It is uncontroversial to apply economics to analyze business-related law fields. Most applications of economics to law utilize microeconomics, but a few applications of macroeconomics to law exist.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2008

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Goolsbee, Austan, 2006, “The 486th Convocation Address: ‘Why People Hate Economists (and Why We Don't Care),’The University of Chicago Record, 41, pp. 18–19Google Scholar
Murphy, Kevin M., 2006, “The 485th Convocation Address: ‘Seeing the World through the Economics Lens,’The University of Chicago Record, 41, pp. 12–13Google Scholar
Westen, Drew, 2007, The Political Brain: The Role of Emotion in Deciding the Fate of the Nation, New York: Public AffairsGoogle Scholar
Mercuro, Nicholas and Medema, Steven G., 2006, Economics and the Law: From Posner to Postmodernism and Beyond, 2nd ed., Princeton: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Schwartz, Hugh, 2000, Rationality Gone Awry?: Decision Making Inconsistent with Economic and Financial Theory, New York: PraegerGoogle Scholar
Cremer, David D. et al., eds., 2006, Social Psychology and Economics, Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates
Diamond, Peter and Vartiainen, Hannu, eds., 2007, Behavioral Economics and Its Applications, Princeton: Princeton University Press
Ross, Don, 2005, Economic Theory and Cognitive Science: Microexplanation, Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Lange, Paul A. M., ed., 2006, Bridging Social Psychology: Benefits of Transdisciplinary Approaches, Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates
Camerer, Colin F., 2007, “Neuroeconomics: Using Neuroscience to Make Economic Predictions,” Economic Journal, 117, pp. C26–C42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kelman, Mark, 1993, “Could Lawyers Stop Recessions? Speculations on Law and Macroeconomics,” Stanford Law Review, 45, pp. 1215–1310Google Scholar
Ramirez, Steven A., 2003, “The Law and Macroeconomics of the New Deal at 70,” Maryland Law Review, 62, pp. 515–572Google Scholar
Ramirez, Steven A., 2002, “Fear and Social Capitalism: The Law and Macroeconomics of Investor Confidence,” Washburn Law Review, 42, pp. 31–77Google Scholar
Bone, Robert G., 2002, Civil Procedure: Economics of Civil Procedure, New York: Foundation PressGoogle Scholar
Cooter, Robert D., 2002, The Strategic Constitution, Princeton: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Goldberg, Victor, 2007, Framing Contract Law: An Economic Perspective, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Bandes, Susan, 2008, “The Heart Has Its Reasons: Examining the Strange Persistence of the American Death Penalty,” Studies in Law, Politics and Society, 42, pp. 21–52CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miceli, Thomas J., 1997, Economics of the Law: Torts, Contracts, Property and Litigation, Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Landes, Elisabeth M. and Posner, Richard A., 1978, “The Economics of the Baby Shortage,” Journal of Legal Studies, 7, pp. 323–348CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brinig, Margaret F., 2005, “Some Concerns about Applying Economics to Family Law,” in Fineman, Martha Albertson and Dougherty, Terence, eds., Feminism Confronts Homo Economicus: Gender, Law, and Society, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, pp. 450–466Google Scholar
Wittman, Donald A., 2005, “The Internal Organization of the Family: Economic Analysis and Psychological Advice,” Kyklos, 58, pp. 121–144CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mahoney, Rhona, 1995, Kidding Ourselves: Breadwinning, Babies, and Bargaining Power, New York: Basic BooksGoogle Scholar
Ackerman, Frank and Heinzerling, Lisa, 2005, Priceless: On Knowing the Price of Everything and the Value of Nothing, New York: The New PressGoogle Scholar
Zerbe, Jr. Richard O., and Bellas, Allen S., 2006, A Primer for Benefit–Cost Analysis, Northampton, MA: Edward ElgarGoogle Scholar
Kahan, Dan M., 2008, “Two Conceptions of Emotion in Risk Regulation,” University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 156, pp. 741–766Google Scholar
Huang, Peter H., 2008, “Diverse Conceptions of Emotions in Risk Regulation” (in response to ibid.), University of Pennsylvania Law Review PENNumbra, 156, pp. 435–447Google Scholar
Hill, Claire A., 2004, “Law and Economics in the Personal Sphere,” Law and Social Inquiry, 29, p. 224, n. 11CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Eric A., 1998, “The Strategic Basis of Principled Behavior: A Critique of the Incommensurability Thesis,” University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 146, pp. 1185–1214Google Scholar
Radin, Margaret J., 2001, Contested Commodities, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Huang, Peter H., 1998, “Dangers of Monetary Commensurability: A Psychological Game Model of Contagion,” University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 146, pp. 1701–1722CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J., 1997, “Invaluable Goods,” Journal of Economic Literature, 35, p. 757Google Scholar
Jordan, Emma Coleman and Harris, Angela P., 2005, Economic Justice: Race, Gender, Identity, and Economics, New York: Foundation Press, pp. 379–384Google Scholar
Calabresi, Guido and Bobbitt, Philip, 1978, Tragic Choices: The Conflicts Society Confronts in the Allocation of Tragically Scarce Resources, New York: W. W. NortonGoogle Scholar
Styron, William, 1979, Sophie's Choice, New York: Vintage, pp. 483–484Google Scholar
Winter, Harold, 2005, Trade-offs: An Introduction to Economic Reasoning and Social Issues, Chicago: University of Chicago PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luce, Mary F. et al., 2001, Emotional Decisions: Trade-off Difficulty and Coping in Consumer Choice, Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Fiske, Alan Page and Tetlock, Philip E., 1997, “Taboo Trade-offs: Reactions to Transactions That Transgress the Spheres of Justice,” Political Psychology, 18, pp. 255–297CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiske, Alan Page, 1992, “The Four Elementary Forms of Sociality: Framework for a Unified Theory of Social Relations,” Psychological Review, 99, pp. 689–723CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Tetlock, Philip E. et al., 1996, “Revising the Value Pluralism Model: Incorporating Social Content and Context Postulates,” in Seligman, Clive et al., eds., The Psychology of Values: The Ontario Symposium, vol. 8, Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum, pp. 25–51Google Scholar
McGraw, A. Peter and Tetlock, Philip E., 2005, “Taboo Trade-offs, Relational Framing, and the Acceptability of Exchanges,” Journal of Consumer Psychology, 15, pp. 2–15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, Jonathan and Spranca, Mark, 1997, “Protected Values,” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 70, pp. 1–16CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
MacCoun, Robert J., 2000, “The Costs and Benefits of Letting Juries Punish Corporations: Comment on Viscusi,” Stanford Law Review, 52, pp. 1821–1828CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, Elizabeth, 1995, Value in Ethics and Economics, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Harvey, Philip, 2004, “Aspirational Law,” Buffalo Law Review, 52, pp. 701–726Google Scholar
Brocas, Isabelle and Carrillo, Juan D., The Psychology of Economic Decisions, Volume I: Rationality and Well-Being, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 105–123
Prelec, Drazen and Bodner, Ronit, 2003, “Self-Signaling and Self-Control,” in Loewenstein, George et al., eds., Time and Decision: Economic and Psychological Perspectives on Intertemporal Choice, New York: Russell Sage Foundation, pp. 277–298Google Scholar
Birsch, Douglas and Fielder, John H., 1994, The Ford Pinto Case: A Study in Applied Ethics, Business, and Technology, Albany, NY: State University of New York PressGoogle Scholar
Viscusi, W. Kip, 2000, “Corporate Risk Analysis: A Reckless Act,” Stanford Law Review, 52, pp. 547–597CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prelec, Drazen and Herrnstein, R. J., 1991, “Preferences or Principles: Alternative Guidelines for Choice,” in Zeckhauser, Richard, ed., Strategy and Choice, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp. 319–340Google Scholar
Ubel, Peter A., 2000, Pricing Life: Why It's Time for Health Care Rationing, Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Thomson, Sir William (Lord Kelvin), 1889, “Electrical Units of Measurement,” lecture delivered to the Institution of Civil Engineers on May 3, 1883, in Popular Lectures and Addresses, vol. 1, London: McMillan, p. 73Google Scholar
Henshaw, John M., 2006, Does Measurement Measure Up?: How Numbers Reveal and Conceal the Truth, Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins Press, p. xGoogle Scholar
Boyle, David, 2004, The Sum of Our Discontent: Why Numbers Make Us Irrational, New York: TexereGoogle Scholar
Mäki, Uskali, “The Dismal Queen of the Social Sciences,” 2003, in Mäki, Uskali, ed., Fact and Fiction in Economics: Models, Realism, and Social Construction, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, p. 3Google Scholar
Rubinstein, Ariel, 2006, “A Sceptic's Comment on the Study of Economics,” Economic Journal, 116, pp. C1–C9Google Scholar
Frank, Robert H. et al., 1993, “Does Studying Economics Inhibit Cooperation?” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7, pp. 159–171CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, Robert H. et al., 1996, “Do Economists Make Bad Citizens?” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10, pp. 187–192CrossRefGoogle Scholar
James, Tammy et al., 2001, “Are Economists Rational, or Just Different?” Social Behavior and Personality, 29, pp. 359–364CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yezer, Anthony M. et al., 1996, “Does Studying Economics Discourage Cooperation? Watch What We Do, Not What We Say or How We Play,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10, pp. 177–186CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laband, David N. and Beil, Richard O., 1999, “Are Economists More Selfish than Other ‘Social’ Scientists?Public Choice, 100, pp. 85–101CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, Bruno S. et al., 1993, “Economics Indoctrination or Selection: Some Empirical Results,” Journal of Economics Education, 24, pp. 271–281CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, Bruno S. and Meier, Stephan, 2003, “Are Political Economists Selfish and Indoctrinated? Evidence from a Natural Experiment,” Economic Inquiry, 41, pp. 448–462CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vohs, Kathleen D. et al., 2006, “The Psychological Consequences of Money,” Science, 314, pp. 1154–1156CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Friedman, David D., 2001, Law's Order: What Economics Has to Do with Law and Why It Matters, Princeton: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Levitt, Steven D. and Dubner, Stephen J., 2006, Freakonomics: A Rogue Economist Explores the Hidden Side of Everything, rev. ed., New York: William MorrowGoogle Scholar
Ippolito, Richard A., 2005, Economics for Lawyers, Princeton: Princeton University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huang, Peter H., 1995, “Strategic Behavior and the Law: A Guide for Legal Scholars to Game Theory and the Law and Other Game Theory Texts,” Jurimetrics: Journal of Law, Science, and Technology, 36, pp. 99–114Google Scholar
Baird, Douglas G. et al., 1994, Game Theory and the Law, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Harford, Tim, 2008, The Logic of Life: The Rational Economics of an Irrational World, New York: Random HouseGoogle Scholar
Cowen, Tyler, 2007, Discover Your Inner Economist: Use Incentives to Fall in Love, Survive Your Next Meeting, and Motivate Your Dentist, New York: DuttonGoogle Scholar
Harford, Tim, 2007, The Undercover Economist: Exposing Why the Rich Are Rich, Why the Poor Are Poor – and Why You Can Never Buy a Decent Used Car! New York: Random HouseGoogle Scholar
Frank, Robert H., 2007, The Economic Naturalist: In Search of Explanations for Everyday Enigmas, New York: Basic BooksGoogle Scholar
Overtveldt, Johan, 2007, The Chicago School: How the University of Chicago Assembled the Thinkers who Revolutionized Economics and Business, Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
George, Donald A. R., “Consolations for the Economist: The Future of Economics Orthodoxy,” Journal of Economic Surveys, 21, pp. 417–425CrossRef
Weintraub, E. Roy, 2002, How Economics Became a Mathematical Science, Durham, NC: Duke University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schofield, Norman, 2004, Mathematical Methods in Economics and Social Choice, Berlin: Springer-VerlagCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leijonhufvud, Axel, 2004, “Life Among the Econ,” Western Economic Journal, 11, pp. 327–337Google Scholar
Marglin, Stephen A., 2008, The Dismal Science: How Thinking Like an Economist Undermines Community, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, p. 292Google Scholar
Sugden, Robert, 2004, “The Opportunity Criterion: Consumer Sovereignty without the Assumption of Coherent Preferences,” American Economic Review, 94, pp. 1014–1033CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J., 1963–1964, “The Role of Securities in the Optimal Allocation of Risk-Bearing,” Review of Economic Studies, 31, pp. 91–96CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huang, Peter H., 2000, “A Normative Analysis of New Financially Engineered Derivatives,” Southern California Law Review, 73, pp. 471–521Google Scholar
Wittman, Donald A., 1995, The Myth of Democratic Failure: Why Political Institutions Are Efficient, Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Casebeer, William D., 2008, “The Stories Markets Tell: Affordances for Ethical Behavior in Free Exchange,” in Zak, Paul J., ed., Moral Markets: The Critical Role of Values in the Economy, Princeton: Princeton University Press, pp. 3–15Google Scholar
Papke, David Ray et al., 2007, Law and Popular Culture: Text, Notes, and Questions, Newark, NJ: LexisNexis, pp. 433–439Google Scholar
Robbins, Ruth Anne, 2006, “Harry Potter, Ruby Slippers, and Merlin: Telling the Client's Story Using the Characters and Paradigm of the Archetypal Hero's Journey,” Seattle University Law Review, 29, pp. 767–802Google Scholar
Weinreb, Lloyd L., 2005, Legal Reason: The Use of Analogy in Legal Argument, New York: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Pamela, 1996, “The Quest for Enabling Metaphors for Law and Lawyering in the Information Age,” Michigan Law Review, 94, pp. 2029–2057CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reiter, Sara Ann, 1997, “Storytelling and Ethics in Financial Economics,” Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 8, pp. 605–632CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thoben, H., 1982, “Mechanistic and Organistic Analogies in Economics Reconsidered,” Kyklos, 35, pp. 292–306CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skorczynska, Hanna, 2006, “Readership and Purpose in the Choice of Economics Metaphors,” Metaphor and Symbol, 21, pp. 87–104CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Turner, Mark, 1998, The Literary Mind: The Origins of Thought and Language, New York: Oxford University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gentner, Dedre et al., 2001, The Analogical Mind: Perspectives from Cognitive Science, Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Lakoff, George and Johnson, Mark, 1980, Metaphors We Live By, Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Henig, Jeffrey R., 1994, Rethinking School Choice: Limits of the Market Metaphor, Princeton: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Quelch, John A. and Jocz, Katherine E., 2008, Greater Good: How Good Marketing Makes for Better Democracy, Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School PressGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Milton, 1962, Capitalism and Freedom, Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Spence, Michael, 1976, “Product Differentiation and Welfare,” American Economic Review, 66, pp. 407–414Google Scholar
Spence, Michael, 1976, “Product Selection, Fixed Costs, and Monopolistic Competition,” Review of Economic Studies, 43, pp. 217–235CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Waldfogel, Joel, 2007, The Tyranny of the Market: Why You Can't Always Get What You Want, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
George, Lisa, 2006, “The New York Times and the Market for Local Newspapers,” American Economic Review, 96, pp. 435–447CrossRefGoogle Scholar
George, Lisa and Waldfogel, Joel, 2003, “Who Affects Whom in Daily Newspaper Markets,” Journal of Political Economy, 111, pp. 765–784CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berry, Steven T. and Waldfogel, Joel, 1999, “Free Entry and Social Inefficiency in Radio Broadcasting,” RAND Journal of Economics, 30, pp. 397–420CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Waldfogel, Joel, 2003, “Preference Externalities: An Empirical Study of Who Benefits Whom in Differentiated-Product Markets,” RAND Journal of Economics, 34, pp. 557–568CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Waldfogel, Joel, 2004, “Who Benefits Whom in Local Television Markets?Brookings-Wharton Papers on Urban Affairs, 5, pp. 257–284CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Teles, Steven M., 2008, The Rise of the Conservative Legal Movement: The Battle for Control of the Law, Princeton: Princeton University Press, pp. 3–4Google Scholar
Dawkins, Richard, 1976, The Selfish Gene, Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Blackmore, Susan, 2000, The Meme Machine, new ed., Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Gans, Joshua S. and Shepherd, George B., 1994, “How Are the Mighty Fallen: Rejected Classic Articles by Leading Economists,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8, pp. 165–179CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard, 1936, The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, London: Macmillan, p. 383Google Scholar
Kuhn, Thomas S., 1962, The Structure of Scientific Revolutions, Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, George, 2007, Exotic Preferences: Behavioral Economics and Human Motivation, New York: Oxford University Press, p. xiiiGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J., 1974, The Limits of Organization, New York: Norton, p. 16Google Scholar
Kőszegi, Botond and Rabin, Matthew, 2007, “Mistakes in Choice-Based Welfare Analysis,” American Economic Review, 97, pp. 477–481CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lichtenstein, Sarah and Slovic, Paul, 2006, The Construction of Preference, Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gardner, James, 2007, “Deliberation or Tabulation? The Self-Undermining Constitutional Architecture of Election Campaigns,” Buffalo Law Review, 54, pp. 1413–1482Google Scholar
Bazerman, Max H. and Malhotra, Deepak, 2006, “Economics Wins, Psychology Loses, and Society Pays,” in Cremer, et al., Social Psychology and Economics, pp. 263–280Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Sugden, Robert, 2005, “Experienced Utility as a Standard of Policy Evaluation,” Environmental and Resource Economics, 32, pp. 161–181CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huang, Peter H., 2008, “How Do Securities Laws Influence Affect, Happiness, and Trust?Journal of Business and Technology Law, 3, pp. 257–308Google Scholar
Brickman, Philip et al., 1978, “Lottery Winners and Accident Victims: Is Happiness Relative?Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 36, pp. 917–927CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gilbert, Daniel T., 2006, Stumbling on Happiness, New York: KnopfGoogle Scholar
Gilbert, Daniel T. and Wilson, Timothy D., 2000, “Miswanting: Some Problems in Affective Forecasting,” in Forgas, Joseph P., ed., Feeling and Thinking: The Role of Affect in Social Cognition, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 178–197Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Thaler, Richard H., 2006, “Utility Maximization and Experienced Utility,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20, pp. 221–234CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel et al., 2004, “A Survey Method for Characterizing Daily Life Experience: The Day Reconstruction Method,” Science, 306, pp. 1776–1780CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hsee, Christopher K. and Zhang, Jiao, 2004, “Distinction Bias: Misprediction and Mischoice due to Joint Evaluation,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 86, pp. 680–695CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gilbert, Daniel T. et al., 1998, “Immune Neglect: A Source of Durability Bias in Affective Forecasting,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 75, pp. 617–638CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Buehler, Roger and McFarland, Cathy, 2001, “Intensity Bias in Affective Forecasting: The Role of Temporal Focus,” Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 27, pp. 1480–1493CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Layard, Richard, 2005, Happiness: Lessons from a New Science, London: Allen LaneGoogle Scholar
Riis, Jason et al., 2005, “Ignorance of Hedonic Adaptation to Hemo-Dialysis: A Study using Ecological Momentary Assessment,” Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 134, pp. 3–9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blumenthal, Jeremy A., 2005, “Law and the Emotions: The Problem of Affective Forecasting,” Indiana Law Journal, 80, pp. 155–238Google Scholar
Bagenstos, Samuel R. and Schlanger, Margo, 2007, “Hedonic Damages, Hedonic Adaptation, and Disability,” Vanderbilt Law Review, 60, pp. 745–797Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Krueger, Alan B., 2006, “Developments in the Measurement of Subjective Well-Being,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20, pp. 3–24CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, George and Ubel, Peter A., 2008, “Hedonic Adaptation and the Role of Decision and Experience Utility in Public Policy,” Journal of Public Economics, 92, pp. 1795–1810CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J., 1978, “The Future and the Present in Economic Life,” Economic Inquiry, 16, pp. 157–169CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bewley, Truman F., 1999, Why Wages Don't Fall during a Recession, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Frey, Bruno S., 2008, Happiness: A Revolution in Economics, Cambridge, MA: MIT PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, Andrew E. and Oswald, Andrew J., 2002, “A Simple Statistical Method for Measuring How Life Events Affect Happiness,” International Journal of Epidemiology, 31, pp. 1139–1144CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Frey, Bruno S. et al., 2007, “Calculating Tragedy: Assessing the Costs of Terrorism,” Journal of Economic Surveys, 21, pp. 1–24CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Praag, Bernard M. S. and Baarsma, Barbara E., 2005, “Using Happiness Surveys to Value Intangibles: The Case of Airport Noise,” Economic Journal, 115, 224–246CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tella, Rafael Di et al., 2003, “The Macroeconomics of Happiness,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 85, pp. 809–827CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tella, Rafael Di et al., 2001, “Preferences over Inflation and Unemployment: Evidence from Surveys of Happiness,” American Economic Review, 91, pp. 335–341CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J., 1982, “Risk Perception in Psychology and Economics,” Economic Inquiry, 20, pp. 7–8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huang, Peter H., 2008, “Authentic Happiness, Self-Knowledge, and Legal Policy,” Minnesota Journal of Law, Science, and Technology, 9, pp. 755–783Google Scholar
Huang, Peter H. and Blumenthal, Jeremy A., forthcoming, “Positive Law and Policy,” in Encyclopedia of Positive Psychology, Lopez, Shane J., ed., New York: Blackwell Publishing
Huang, Peter H. and Blumenthal, Jeremy A., forthcoming, “Positive Institutions, Law, and Policy,” in Handbook of Positive Psychology, 2nd ed., Lopez, Shane J., ed., Oxford: Oxford University Press
Huang, Peter H. and Swedloff, Rick, 2008, “Authentic Happiness and Meaning at Law Firms,” Syracuse Law Review, 58, pp. 341–356Google Scholar
Thaler, Richard H. and Sunstein, Cass R., 2008, Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth, and Happiness, New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Thaler, Richard H. and Sunstein, Cass R., 2003, “Libertarian Paternalism,” American Economic Review, 93, pp. 175–179CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glaeser, Edward L., 2006, “Paternalism and Psychology,” Regulation, 29, pp. 32–38Google Scholar
Blumenthal, Jeremy A., 2007, “Emotional Paternalism,” Florida State University Law Review, 35, pp. 1–72Google Scholar
Camerer, Colin et al., 2003, “Regulation for Conservatives: Behavioral Economics and the Case for ‘Asymmetric Paternalism,’University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 151, pp. 1211–1254CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Richard A., 2006, “Behavioral Economics: Human Errors and Market Corrections,” University of Chicago Law Review, 73, pp. 111–132Google Scholar
Hill, Claire A., 2007, “Anti-anti-anti-paternalism,” NYU Journal of Law and Liberty, 2, pp. 444–454Google Scholar
Klick, Jonathan and Mitchell, Gregory, 2006, “Government Regulation of Irrationality: Moral and Cognitive Hazards,” Minnesota Law Review, 90, pp. 1620–1663Google Scholar
Mitchell, Gregory, 2005, “Libertarian Paternalism Is an Oxymoron,” Northwestern University Law Review, 99, pp. 1245–1277Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×