Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-pftt2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-17T17:11:58.337Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

19 - Nonprofits as Distributors of Toll Goods

from Part III - New Directions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 January 2024

Eva Witesman
Affiliation:
Brigham Young University, Utah
Curtis Child
Affiliation:
Brigham Young University, Utah
Get access

Summary

Witesman provides an institutional theory of the nonprofit. The chapter considers the argument developed by the author in a 2016 Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly article. In it, she proposes an institutional theory of the nonprofit that defines its distinction from public and private institutions through (1) the voluntary (rather than coercive) assignment of roles and (2) the use of the good or service by non-payers. The voluntary and redistributive nature of such nonprofit-type institutions makes them primarily compatible with the distribution of goods that are non-subtractable and excludable (toll goods). This view is in contrast to legalistic or sector-based theories of the nonprofit.

Type
Chapter
Information
Reimagining Nonprofits
Sector Theory in the Twenty-First Century
, pp. 372 - 393
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2024

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abzug, R. (1999). The nonprofit sector and the informal sector: A theoretical perspective. Voluntas: International Journal of Voluntary and Nonprofit Organizations, 10(2), 131149.Google Scholar
Amendola, A., Garofalo, M. R., & Nese, A. (2011). Is the third sector an emerging economic institution? Social preferences versus poverty traps. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 40(5), 850872.Google Scholar
Bator, F. M. (1958). The anatomy of market failure. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 72(3), 351379.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumol, W. J. (1952). Welfare economics and the theory of the state. Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Ben-Ner, A. (2002). The shifting boundaries of the mixed economy and the future of the nonprofit sector. Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, 73(1), 540.Google Scholar
Ben-Zion, U., & Spiegel, U. (1983). Philanthropic motives and contribution policy. Public Choice, 40(2), 117133.Google Scholar
Billis, D., & Glennerster, H. (1998). Human services and the voluntary sector: Towards a theory of comparative advantage. Journal of Social policy, 27(01), 7998.Google Scholar
Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. M. (1980). The power to tax: Analytic foundations of a fiscal constitution. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Brinkerhoff, J. M., & Brinkerhoff, D. W. (2002). Government–nonprofit relations in comparative perspective: Evolution, themes and new directions. Public Administration and Development, 22(1), 318.Google Scholar
Brody, E. (1996a). Agents without principals: The economic convergence of the nonprofit and for-profit organizational forms. New York Law School Law Review, 40(3), 547536.Google Scholar
Brody, E. (1996b). Institutional dissonance in the nonprofit sector. Villanova Law Review, 41(2), 433.Google Scholar
Brody, E. (2003). Are nonprofit organizations different? In Anheier, H. K. & Ben-Ner, A. (Eds.), The study of the nonprofit enterprise (pp. 239244). Kluwer Academic/Plenum Publishers.Google Scholar
Bromley, P., & Meyer, J. W. (2014). “They are all organizations”: The cultural roots of blurring between the nonprofit, business, and government sectors. Administration & Society, 0095399714548268.Google Scholar
Bushouse, B. K. (1999). The mixed economy of child care: An institutional analysis of nonprofit, for-profit, and public enterprises [Doctoral dissertation]. Retrieved from http://search.proquest.com/docview/304532864?accountid=4488.Google Scholar
Bushouse, B. K. (2011). Governance structures: Using IAD to understand variation in service delivery for club goods with information asymmetry. Policy Studies Journal, 39(1), 105119.Google Scholar
Child, C. (2015). Tip of the iceberg the nonprofit underpinnings of for-profit social enterprise. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 0899764015572901.Google Scholar
Child, C., Witesman, E. M., & Braudt, D. B. (2014). Sector choice: How fair trade entrepreneurs choose between nonprofit and for-profit forms. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 0899764014542688.Google Scholar
Cooney, K. (2006). The institutional and technical structuring of nonprofit ventures: Case study of a US hybrid organization caught between two fields. Voluntas: International Journal of Voluntary and Nonprofit Organizations, 17(2), 137155.Google Scholar
Dees, J. G., & Anderson, B. B. (2003). Sector-bending: Blurring lines between nonprofit and for-profit. Society, 40(4), 1627.Google Scholar
Douglas, J. A. (1983). Why charity? The case for a third sector. Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Douglas, J. A. (2003). Political theories of nonprofit organization. In Powell, W. W. & Steinberg, R. (Eds.), The nonprofit sector: A research handbook (pp. 4354). Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Eikenberry, A. M., & Kluver, J. D. (2004). The marketization of the nonprofit sector: Civil society at risk? Public Administration Review, 64(2), 132140.Google Scholar
Feeney, S. (1997). Shifting the prism: Case explications of institutional analysis in nonprofit organizations. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 26(4), 489508.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferris, J. M., & Graddy, E. (1999). The role of the nonprofit sector in a self-governing society: A view from the United States. Voluntas: International Journal of Voluntary and Nonprofit Organizations, 9(2), 137151.Google Scholar
Friedman, M., & Friedman, R. (1980). Free to choose. Secker and Warburg.Google Scholar
Froelich, K. A. (1999). Diversification of revenue strategies: Evolving resource dependence in nonprofit organizations. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 28(3), 246268.Google Scholar
Frumkin, P. (2002). On being nonprofit: A conceptual and policy primer. Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Gazley, B. (2008). Beyond the contract: The scope and nature of informal government–nonprofit partnerships. Public Administration Review, 68(1), 141154.Google Scholar
Grimm, Jr., R. T. (1999). Reforming property tax exemption policy in the nonprofit sector: Commercialism, collective goods, and the donative theory. Nonprofit Management and Leadership, 9(3), 241259.Google Scholar
Grønbjerg, K. A., Liu, H. K., & Pollak, T. H. (2010). Incorporated but not IRS-registered: Exploring the (dark) grey fringes of the nonprofit universe. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 39(5), 925945.Google Scholar
Guo, C. (2007). When government becomes the principal philanthropist: The effects of public funding on patterns of nonprofit governance. Public Administration Review, 67(3), 458473.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Handy, F., Seto, S., Wakaruk, A., Mersey, B. A., Mejia, A., & Copeland, L. (2010). The discerning consumer: Is nonprofit status a factor? Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 39(5), 866883.Google Scholar
Hansmann, H. B. (1980). The role of nonprofit enterprise. The Yale Law Journal, 89(5), 835901.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heinrich, C. J. (2003). Organizational form and performance: An empirical investigation of nonprofit and for-profit job-training service providers. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 19(2), 233261.Google Scholar
Kennedy, P. W. (1990). The market provision of club goods in the presence of scale economies. Economica, 57(228), 515524.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kingma, B. R. (2003). Public good theories of the nonprofit sector. In Anheier, H. K. & Ben-Ner, A. (Eds.), The study of the nonprofit enterprise (pp. 5365). Kluwer Academic/Plenum Publishers.Google Scholar
Kramer, R. M. (2000). A third sector in the third millennium? Voluntas: International Journal of Voluntary and Nonprofit Organizations, 11(1), 123.Google Scholar
Kushner, R., & King, A. E. (1994). Performing arts as a club good: Evidence from a nonprofit organization. Journal of Cultural Economics, 18(1), 1528.Google Scholar
Leviten-Reid, E. (2010). Organizational form, parental involvement, and quality of care in child day care centers. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 41(1), 3657.Google Scholar
Lipsky, M., & Smith, S. R. (1989). Nonprofit organizations, government, and the welfare state. Political Science Quarterly, 104(4), 625648.Google Scholar
Lowi, T. J. (1979). The end of liberalism. Norton.Google Scholar
Luksetich, W., Edwards, M., & Carroll, T. (2000). Organizational form and nursing home behavior. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 29(2), 255279.Google Scholar
Mayer, L. H., & Ganahl, J. R. (2014). Taxing social enterprise. Stanford Law Review, 66, 387.Google Scholar
Moore, M. H. (2000). Managing for value: Organizational strategy in for-profit, nonprofit, and governmental organizations. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 29(suppl 1), 183208.Google Scholar
Morris, S. (2000). Defining the nonprofit sector: Some lessons from history. Voluntas: International Journal of Voluntary and Nonprofit Organizations, 11(1), 2543.Google Scholar
Newhouse, J. P. (1970). Toward a theory of nonprofit institutions: An economic model of a hospital. The American Economic Review, 62(1/2), 6474.Google Scholar
Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (2003). How types of goods and property rights jointly affect collective action. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 15(3), 239270.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (2005). Understanding institutional diversity. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, V., & Ostrom, E. (1977). Public goods and public choices. In Savas, E. S. (Ed.), Alternatives for delivering public services: Towards improved performance (pp. 749). Westview Press.Google Scholar
Potoski, M., & Prakash, A. (2009). Voluntary programs: A club theory perspective. MIT Press.Google Scholar
Powell, W. W., & Steinberg, R. (Eds.) (2006). The nonprofit sector: A research handbook. Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Reiter, M., & Weichenrieder, A. J. (1999). Public goods, club goods and the measurement of crowding. Journal of Urban Economics, 46(1), 6979.Google Scholar
Rosenau, P., & Linder, S. (2003). Two decades of research comparing for-profit and nonprofit health provider performance in the United States. Social Science Quarterly, 84(2), 219241.Google Scholar
Saidel, J. R. (1991). Resource interdependence: The relationship between state agencies and nonprofit organizations. Public Administration Review, 51(6), 543553.Google Scholar
Salamon, L. M. (1987). Of market failure, voluntary failure, and third-party government: Toward a theory of government–nonprofit relations in the modern welfare state. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 16(1–2), 2949.Google Scholar
Salamon, L. M. (1999). The nonprofit sector: A primer. The Foundation Center.Google Scholar
Salamon, L. M. (2003). Voluntary failure theory correctly viewed. In Anheier, H. K. & Ben-Ner, A. (Eds.), The study of the nonprofit enterprise (pp. 183186). Kluwer Academic/Plenum Publishers.Google Scholar
Salamon, L. M., & Anheier, H. K. (1992a). In search of the non-profit sector. I: The question of definitions. Voluntas: International Journal of Voluntary and Nonprofit Organizations, 3(2), 125151.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Salamon, L. M., & Anheier, H. K. (1992b). In search of the non-profit sector II: The problem of classification. Voluntas: International Journal of Voluntary and Nonprofit Organizations, 3(3), 267309.Google Scholar
Salamon, L. M., & Anheier, H. K. (1998). Social origins of civil society: Explaining the nonprofit sector cross-nationally. Voluntas: International Journal of Voluntary and Nonprofit Organizations, 9(3), 213248.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 36(4), 387389.Google Scholar
Sandler, T., & Tschirhart, J. (1997). Club theory: Thirty years later. Public Choice, 93(3), 335355.Google Scholar
Schweik, C. M., Mergel, I., Sandfort, J. R., & Zhao, Z. J. (2011). Toward open public administration scholarship. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 21(suppl. 1), 175198.Google Scholar
Sefton, M., & Steinberg, R. (1996). Reward structures in public good experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 61(2), 263287.Google Scholar
Sefton, T. (2008). Distributive and redistributive policy. In R. E. Goodin, M. Moran, & M. Rein (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of public policy (pp. 607623). Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Seibel, W. (1990). Government/third sector relationships in a comparative perspective: The cases of France and West Germany. Voluntas: International Journal of Voluntary and Nonprofit Organizations, 1(1), 4261.Google Scholar
Sen, A. (1993). Markets and freedom: Achievements and limitations of the market mechanism in promoting individual freedoms. Oxford Economic Papers, 45 (4), 519541.Google Scholar
Smith, D. H. (1975). Voluntary action and voluntary groups. Annual Review of Sociology, 1(1), 247270.Google Scholar
Smith, D. H. (1997). The rest of the nonprofit sector: Grassroots associations as the dark matter ignored in prevailing “flat earth” maps of the sector. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 26(2), 114131.Google Scholar
Steen, T. (2008). Not a government monopoly: The private, nonprofit, and voluntary sectors. In Perry, J. & Hondeghem, A. (Eds.), Motivation in public management: The call of public service (pp. 203222). Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Steinberg, R. (1987). Voluntary donations and public expenditures in a federalist system. The American Economic Review, 72(1), 2436.Google Scholar
Steinberg, R., & Weisbrod, B. A. (1998). Pricing and rationing by nonprofit organizations with distributional objectives. In Weisbrod, B. A. (Ed.), To profit or not to profit: The commercial transformation of the nonprofit sector (pp. 6482). Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Steinberg, R., & Weisbrod, B. A. (2005). Nonprofits with distributional objectives: Price discrimination and corner solutions. Journal of Public Economics, 89(11), 22052230.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, J. E. (1989). Markets, market failures, and development. American Economic Review, 79(2), 197203.Google Scholar
Stoker, G. (1998). Governance as theory: Five propositions. International Social Science Journal, 50(155), 1728.Google Scholar
Van Til, J. (2000). Growing civil society: From nonprofit sector to third space. Indiana University Press.Google Scholar
Weimer, D. L., & Vining, A. R. (2005). Policy analysis: Concepts and practice (4th ed.). Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Weisbrod, B. A. (Ed.) (1977). The voluntary nonprofit sector: An economic analysis. Lexington Books.Google Scholar
Weisbrod, B. A. (1997). The future of the nonprofit sector: Its entwining with private enterprise and government. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 16(4), 541555.3.0.CO;2-G>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weisbrod, B. A. (2000). To profit or not to profit: The commercial transformation of the nonprofit sector. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Witesman, E. M., & Fernandez, S. (2013). Government contracts with private organizations: Are there differences between nonprofits and for-profits? Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 0899764012442592.Google Scholar
Young, D. R. (2016). Contract failure theory. In Ott, J. S. & Dicke, L. A. (Eds.), The nature of the nonprofit sector (3rd ed.) (pp. 193196). Westview.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×