Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-c4f8m Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-17T10:56:53.470Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

5 - Petroleum Rents without Rentierism

Domestic Private Ownership in the Russian Federation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 June 2012

Pauline Jones Luong
Affiliation:
Brown University, Rhode Island
Erika Weinthal
Affiliation:
Duke University, North Carolina
Get access

Summary

If the [Russian] state does not learn to collect taxes, it will cease to exist.

– Sergei Kiriyenko, Prime Minister, June 23, 1998

Competitiveness of the economy … rests on stability and predictability, clearness and transparency of rules and procedures. Otherwise, we can hardly ever succeed. Capital is invested in areas where it is guaranteed best possible conditions, and love to Russia alone is not a sufficient motivator.

– Sergey Dimitrievich Shatalov, First Deputy Minister of Finance, July 5, 2002

The most important feature of the new Tax Code is its stability. Even if you don’t like paying taxes, there are now rules that do not change. Even if it is not perfect, it is clear and predictable. This is good for business … . It is good for the major oil companies. And what is good for the major oil companies is good for Russia. Just like Ford [Motor Co.] in America … .

– Representative of Lukoil, June 25, 2002

Whereas Turkmenistan and Uzbekistan adopted one of the most common ownership structures among petroleum-rich states – state ownership with control (S1) – from the early 1990s through the mid-2000s, the Russian Federation adopted one of the rarest over its oil sector – private domestic ownership (P1). According to our research, over the course of the twentieth century, only a handful of developing countries – Brazil (1891–1937), Venezuela (1904–1906), Romania (1924–1944), and Guatemala (1949–1982) – have opted to privatize their petroleum sector to domestic actors. Russia officially joined this small group in 1993 when it created three vertically integrated joint-stock oil companies – Lukoil, Surgutneftegaz, and Yukos – to replace the state-owned Soviet oil monopoly. As a result, we predict that it is also more likely to enjoy a rare outcome across mineral-rich states: a strong fiscal regime – that is, one that encompasses a tax system that is stable, broad-based, and relies primarily on direct and explicit taxation and a system of expenditures that emphasizes budgetary stability and transparency. In this chapter, we demonstrate not only that Russia did indeed adopt a strong fiscal regime from 1999–2005 – contrary to what both scholars of Russia and the resource curse predicted – but also that this outcome was facilitated by its choice of ownership structure.

As we argue in Chapter 3, P1 fosters strong fiscal regimes because – in contrast to S1 – it provides both the direct claimants (here, domestic private owners) and indirect claimants (here, governing elites and the population) with an incentive to supply and demand institutions that set effective limits on the state’s ability to extract and spend the proceeds from mineral wealth – incentives that are reinforced by the process through which these institutions emerge. More specifically, P1 generates high transaction costs (TCs), societal expectations for limited redistribution, and interdependent power relations. The combination of high TCs and low societal expectations promotes a mutual desire for fiscal stability, more visible forms of taxation across sectors, and limited public spending, while interdependent power relations in the context of low TCs and high societal expectations serve to reinforce these incentives via an explicit bargaining process.

Type
Chapter
Information
Oil Is Not a Curse
Ownership Structure and Institutions in Soviet Successor States
, pp. 121 - 180
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×