Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-sjtt6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-28T07:08:33.794Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Bibliography

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 June 2016

Nicola Acocella
Affiliation:
Università degli Studi di Roma 'La Sapienza', Italy
Giovanni Di Bartolomeo
Affiliation:
Università degli Studi di Roma 'La Sapienza', Italy
Andrew Hughes Hallett
Affiliation:
University of St Andrews, Scotland
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Macroeconomic Paradigms and Economic Policy
From the Great Depression to the Great Recession
, pp. 297 - 319
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2016

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aarle, van B., Di Bartolomeo, G., Engwerda, J. and Plasmans, J. (2004). “Policymakers coalitions and the stabilization policies in the EMU.” Journal of Economics, 82: 1–24.Google Scholar
Abrams, B. A. (2006). “How Richard Nixon pressured Arthur Burns: evidence from the Nixon tapes.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20: 177–188.Google Scholar
Acocella, N. (2005). Economic policy in the age of globalization. Cambridge University Press.
Acocella, N. (2014a). “The theoretical roots of EMU institutions and policies during the crisis.” Turin: Fondazione Einaudi, Annali 2013, 48: 3–36.Google Scholar
Acocella, N. (2014b). “The rise and decline of economic policy as a discipline: a critical survey.” Sapienza University of Rome, MEMOTEF Working Paper Series, No. 123.
Acocella, N. (2015). “A tale of two cities: the evolution of the crisis and exit policies in Washington and Frankfurt,” in Dallago, B. and McGowan, J. (eds.), Economic and political crises in Europe and the United States: prospects for policy cooperation. London: Routledge.
Acocella, N. (2016). “Signalling imbalances in the EMU,” in Dallago, B., Guri, G. and McGowan, J. (eds.), A global perspective on the European economic crisis. London: Routledge. Forthcoming.
Acocella, N. and Di Bartolomeo, G. (2004). “Non-neutrality of monetary policy in policy games.” European Journal of Political Economy, 20: 695–707.Google Scholar
Acocella, N. and Di Bartolomeo, G. (2007). “Is corporatism feasible?Metroeconomica, 58: 340–359.Google Scholar
Acocella, N. and Di Bartolomeo, G. (2013). “The cost of social pacts.” Bulletin of Economic Research, 65: 238–255.Google Scholar
Acocella, N., Di Bartolomeo, G. and Hibbs, D. (2008). “Labor market regimes and the effects of monetary policy.” Journal of Macroeconomics, 30: 134–156.Google Scholar
Acocella, N., Bartolomeo, G. Di and Hallett, A. Hughes (2012a). “Expectations dynamics: policy, announcements and limits to dynamic inconsistency.” Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics, BE Press Journals, 16: 1–25.Google Scholar
Acocella, N., Bartolomeo, G. Di and Hallett, A. Hughes (2012b). “A general theory of controllability and expectations anchoring for small–open economies.” Journal of International Money and Finance, 31: 397–411.Google Scholar
Acocella, N., Bartolomeo, G. Di and Hallett, A. Hughes (2013). The theory of economic policy in a strategic context. Cambridge University Press.
Acocella, N., Di Bartolomeo, G. and Tirelli, P. (2007a). “Fiscal leadership and coordination in the EMU.” Open Economies Review, 18: 281–289.Google Scholar
Acocella, N., Di Bartolomeo, G. and Tirelli, P. (2007b). “From first- to second-generation social pacts,” in Acocella, N. and Leoni, R. (eds.), Social pacts, employment and growth: essay in honor of Ezio Tarantelli: 239–251. Heildelberg and New York: Physica-Verlag.
Acocella, N., Di Bartolomeo, G. and Tirelli, P. (2007c). “Monetary conservatism and fiscal coordination in a monetary union.” Economics Letters, 94: 56–63.Google Scholar
Acocella, N., Di Bartolomeo, G. and Tirelli, P. (2009). “The macroeconomics of social pacts.” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 72: 202–213.Google Scholar
Acocella, N., Di Bartolomeo, G. and Pauwels, W. (2010). “Is there any scope for corporatism in macroeconomic policies?Empirica, 37: 403–424.Google Scholar
Acocella, N., Bartolomeo, G. Di, Hallett, A. Hughes and Piacquadio, P. (2014). “Announcement wars as an equilibrium selection device.” Oxford Economic Papers, 66: 325–347.Google Scholar
Adam, C. S. and Vines, D. (2009). “Remaking macroeconomic policy after the global financial crisis: a balance-sheet approach.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 25: 507–552.Google Scholar
Adam, S., Besley, T., Blundell, R., Bond, S., Chote, R., Gammie, M., Johnson, P., Myles, G. and Poterba, J. (2010). “Dimensions of tax design,” in Mirrless Review, Volume I. Oxford University Press.
Ahmed, S., Levin, A. and Wilson, B. A. (2004). “Recent US macroeconomic stability: good policies, good practices or good luck?Review of Economics and Statistics, 86: 824–832.Google Scholar
Aiyagari, S. and McGrattan, E. (1998). “The optimal quantity of debt.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 42: 447–469.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G. (1970). “The market for lemons. Uncertainty and the market mechanism.Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84: 488–500.Google Scholar
Albonico, A., Paccagnini, A. and Tirelli, P. (2015). “In search of the Eurozone fiscal stance.” University of Milan Bicocca, mimeo.
Alesina, A. (1987). “Macroeconomic policy in a two-party system as a repeated game.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102: 651–678.Google Scholar
Alesina, A. (1988). “Macroeconomics and politics,” in Fischer, S. (ed.), NBER macroeconomic annual 1988: 13–61. Cambridge MA: MIT Press.
Alesina, A. and Summers, L. H. (1993). “Central bank independence and macroeconomic performance: some comparative evidence.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 25: 151–162.Google Scholar
Alesina, A. and Perotti, R. (1997a). “Fiscal adjustments in OECD countries: composition and macroeconomic effects.” International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, 44: 210–248.Google Scholar
Alesina, A. and Perotti, R. (1997b). “The welfare state and competitiveness.” American Economic Review, 87: 921–939.Google Scholar
Alesina, A., Perotti, R. and Tavares, J. (1998). “The political economy of fiscal adjustments.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1: 197–266.Google Scholar
Alessandrini, P., Fratianni, M., Hallett, A. Hughes and Presbitero, A. (2014). “External imbalances and fiscal fragility in the euro area.” Open Economies Review, 25: 3–34.Google Scholar
Alvarez, R. M., Garrett, G. and Lange, P. (1991). “Government partisanship, labor organization, and macroeconomic performance.” American Political Science Review, 85: 539–556.Google Scholar
Andersen, T. and Risager, O. (1988). “Stabilization policies, credibility and interest rate determination in a small open economy.” European Economic Review, 32: 669–679.Google Scholar
Aoki, M. (2001). “To the rescue or to the abyss: notes on the Marx in Keynes.” Journal of Economic Issues, 35: 931–954.Google Scholar
Arias, A., Hansen, G. D. and Ohanian, L. E. (2007). “Why have business cycle fluctuations become less volatile.” Economic Theory, 32: 43–58.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J. (1951). Social choice and individual values. New York: Wiley and Son.
Ascari, G. and Rossi, L. (2011). “Real wage rigidities and disinflation dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg pricing.Economics Letters, 110: 126–131.Google Scholar
Aschauer, D. A. (2000). “Do states optimise? Public capital and economic growth.” Annals of Regional Science, 34: 343–363.Google Scholar
Auerbach, A. J. (2009). “Implementing the new fiscal policy activism.” American Economic Review, 99: 543–549.Google Scholar
Auerbach, A. J. and Gorodnichenko, Y. (2012). “Measuring the output responses to fiscal policy.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 4: 1–27.Google Scholar
Bacchetta, P. and van Wincoop, E. (2000). “Does exchange-rate stability increase trade and welfare?American Economic Review, 90: 1093–1109.Google Scholar
Backhouse, R. E. (2002). The Penguin history of economics. London: Penguin.
Backus, D. and Driffill, J. (1985). “Inflation and reputation.” American Economic Review, 75: 530–538.Google Scholar
Balassa, B. (1964). “The purchasing power parity doctrine: a reappraisal.” Journal of Political Economy, 72: 584–596.Google Scholar
Baldwin, R. and Wyplosz, C. (2006). The economics of European integration (edn). New York: McGraw–Hill.
Barro, R. J. (1974). “Are government bonds net wealth?Journal of Political Economy, 82: 1095–1117.Google Scholar
Barro, R. J. (1995). “Inflation and economic growth.” Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, 95: 39–52.Google Scholar
Barro, R. J. (1996). “Inflation and growth.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 78: 153–169.Google Scholar
Barro, R. J. and Gordon, D. B. (1983a). “Rules, discretion and reputation in a model of monetary policy.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 12: 101–121.Google Scholar
Barro, R. J. and Gordon, D. B. (1983b). “A positive theory of monetary policy in a natural rate model.” Journal of Political Economy, 91: 589–610.Google Scholar
Barry, F. G. and Devereux, M. B. (1995). “The ‘expansionary fiscal contraction’ hypothesis: a Neo-Keynesian analysis.” Oxford Economic Papers, 47: 249–264.Google Scholar
Barth, M. and Ramey, V. (2002). “The cost channel of monetary transmission,” in Bernanke, B. S. and Rogoff, K. (eds.), NBER macroeconomics annual 2001: 199–239. Cambridge MA: MIT Press.
Başar, T. (1989). “Time consistency and robustness of equilibria in non-cooperative dynamic games,” in Ploeg, F. van der and Zeeuw, A. de (eds.), Dynamic policy games in economics: 9–54. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Başar, T. and Olsder, G. J. (1995). Dynamic noncooperative game theory (edn). London: Academic Press Limited.
Bator, F. (1958). “The anatomy of market failure.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 72: 351–379.Google Scholar
Baxter, M. and King, R. (1993). “Fiscal policy in general equilibrium.” American Economic Review, 83: 315–334.Google Scholar
Bayoumi, T. and Masson, P. (1995). “Fiscal flows in the United States and Canada: lessons for monetary union in Europe.” European Economic Review, 39: 253–274.Google Scholar
Bayoumi, T., Eichengreen, B. and Mauro, P. (2000). “On regional monetary arrangements for ASEAN.” Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 14: 121–114.Google Scholar
Bean, C. (1998). “Monetary policy under EMU.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 14: 41–53.Google Scholar
Beetsma, R. and Uhlig, H. (1999). “An analysis of the stability and growth pact.” The Economic Journal, 109: 546–571.Google Scholar
Beetsma, R. M. W. J. and Bovenberg, A. L. (1998). “Monetary union without fiscal coordination may discipline policymakers.” Journal of International Economics, 45: 239–258.Google Scholar
Beetsma, R. M. W. J. and Giuliodori, M. (2010). “The macroeconomic costs and benefits of the EMU and other monetary unions: an overview of recent research.” Journal of Economic Literature, 48: 603–641.Google Scholar
Belot, M. and van Ours, J. (2004). “Does the recent success of some OECD countries in lowering their unemployment rates lie in the clever design of their labor market reforms?Oxford Economic Papers, 56: 621–642.Google Scholar
Benati, L. and Goodhart, C. (2011). “Monetary policy regimes and economic performance: the historical record, 1979–2008,” in Friedman, B. J. and Woodford, M. (eds.), Handbook of monetary economics, Volume 3A: 1159–1236. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Benigno, P. and Woodford, M. (2004). “Optimal monetary and fiscal policy: a linear-quadratic approach,” in Gertler, M. and Rogoff, K. (eds.), NBER macroeconomics annual 2003:271–333. Cambridge MA: MIT Press.
Benigno, P. and Woodford, M. (2012). “Linear-quadratic approximation of optimal policy problems.” Journal of Economic Theory, 147: 1–42.Google Scholar
Berger, H., De Haan, J. and Eijffinger, S. C. W. (2001). “Central bank independence: an update of theory and evidence.” Journal of Economic Surveys, 15: 3–40.Google Scholar
Bernanke, B. (2010). “Central bank independence, transparency, and accountability.” Speech at the Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies International Conference (May 25, 2010). Tokyo: Bank of Japan.
Bernanke, B., and Gertler, M. (1989). “Agency costs, net worth, and business fluctuations.” American Economic Review, 79: 14–31.Google Scholar
Bernanke, B., and Gertler, M. (1995). “Inside the black box: the credit channel of monetary policy transmission.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9: 27–48.Google Scholar
Bernanke, B. and Mihov, I. (1998). “Measuring monetary policy.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 103: 869–902.Google Scholar
Bernanke, B., Gertler, M. and Gilchrist, S. (1996). “The financial accelerator and the flight to quality.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 78: 1–15.Google Scholar
Bernanke, B., Gertler, M. and Gilchrist, S. (1999). “The financial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework,” in Taylor, J. B. and Woodford, M. (eds.), Handbook of macroeconomics, Volume 1C: 1341–1393. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Bernanke, B., Reinhart, V. R. and Sack, B. P. (2004). “Monetary policy alternatives at the zero bound: an empirical assessment.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2: 1–78.Google Scholar
Bernoth, K., Hughes Hallett, A. and Lewis, J. (2015). “The cyclicality of automatic and discretionary fiscal policy: what can real time data tell us?Macroeconomic Dynamics, 19: 221–245.Google Scholar
Beveridge, W. (1942). “Social insurance and allied services.” Cmnd 6404, London: HMSO.
Bilbiie, F. O. (2008). “Limited asset markets participation, monetary policy and (inverted) aggregate demand logic.” Journal of Economic Theory, 140: 162–196.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O. J. (2000). “What do we know about macroeconomics that Fisher and Wicksell did not?Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115: 1375–1409.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O. J. (2006). “Monetary policy science or art,” in An ECB colloquium held in honor of Otmar Issing. Frankfurt: ECB.
Blanchard, O. and Simon, J. (2001). “The long and large decline in US output volatility.” Brooking Papers on Economic Activity, 1: 135–174.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O. J. and Giavazzi, F. (2002). “Current account deficits in the euro area: the end of the Feldstein–Horioka puzzle?Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 33: 147–209.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O. J. and Giavazzi, F. (2003). “Macroeconomic effects of regulation and deregulation in goods and factor markets.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118: 879–907.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O. J. and Philippon, T. (2003). “The decline of rents, and the rise and fall of European unemployment.” MIT, mimeo.
Blanchard, O. and Galí, J. (2007). “Real wage rigidities and the New Keynesian model.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 39: 35–65.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O. J., Erceg, C. and Linde, J. (2015). “Jump-starting the euro-area recovery: would a rise in core fiscal spending help the periphery?” mimeo, Washington DC: IMF.
Blau, F. D. and Kahn, L. M. (2002). At home and abroad. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Blinder, A. S. (1997). “What central bankers could learn from academics and vice versa.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11: 3–20.Google Scholar
Blinder, A. S. (1998). Central banking in theory and practice. Cambridge MA: MIT Press.
Boivin, J. and Giannoni, M. (2006). “Has monetary policy become more effective?Review of Economics and Statistics, 88: 445–462.Google Scholar
Bokan, N., Hughes Hallett, A. and Jensen, S. E. H. (2015). “Growth maximising public debt under changing demographics.” George Mason University, mimeo. Forthcoming in Macroeconomic Dynamics.
Booth, A. (1995). The economics of trade unions. Cambridge University Press.
Bratsiotis, G. J. and Martin, C. (1999). “Stabilisation, policy targets, and unemployment.” Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 101: 241–256.Google Scholar
Brzoza–Brzezina, M., Kolasa, M., Koloch, G., Makarski, K. and Rubaszek, M. (2013a). “Monetary policy in a non-representative agent economy: a survey.” Journal of Economic Surveys, 27: 641–669.Google Scholar
Brzoza–Brzezina, M., Kolasa, M. and Makarski, K. (2013b). “The anatomy of standard DSGE models with financial frictions.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 37: 32–51.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. and Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent, logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Budina, N., Kinda, T., Schaechter, A. and Weber, A. (2012). “Fiscal rules at a glance: country details from a new dataset.” International Monetary Fund Working Paper No. 273. Washington DC: IMF.
Bullard, J. and Singh, A. (2008). “Worldwide macroeconomic stability and monetary policy rules.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 55: S34–S47.Google Scholar
Buti, M., Franco, D. and Ongena, H. (1998). “Fiscal discipline and flexibility in EMU: the implementation of the stability and growth pact.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 14: 81–97.Google Scholar
Caballero, R. J. (2010). “Macroeconomics after the crisis: time to deal with the pretense-of-knowledge syndrome.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 24: 85–102.Google Scholar
Caffè, F. (1976). “Una fase critica della cooperazione economica internazionale.” La Comunità Internazionale, 31: 3–7.Google Scholar
Caffè, F. (1990). Lezioni di politica economica (edn). Turin: Boringhieri.
Calmfors, L. and Driffill, J. (1988). “Bargaining structure, corporatism and macroeconomic performance.” Economic Policy, 3: 13–61.Google Scholar
Calvo, G. (1983). “Staggered prices in a utility maximizing framework.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 12: 383–398.Google Scholar
Cameron, D. R. (1984). “Social democracy, corporatism, and labour quiescence: the representation of economic interest in advanced capitalist society,” in Goldthorpe, J. H. (ed.), Order and conflict in contemporary capitalism: 143–178. Oxford University Press.
Campbell, J. R. (2013). “Odyssean forward guidance in monetary policy: a primer,” in den Haan, W. (ed.), Forward guidance perspectives from central bankers, scholars and market participants:87–106. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research.
Campbell, J. R., Evans, C. L., Fisher, J. D. M. and Justiniano, A. (2012). “Macroeconomic effects of Federal Reserve forward guidance.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 44: 1–80.Google Scholar
Canofari, P., Di Bartolomeo, G. and Piersanti, G. (2015). “Strategic interactions and contagion effects under monetary unions.” The World Economy, 38: 1618–1629.Google Scholar
Canova, F. (2009). “What explains the great moderation in the US? A structural analysis.” Journal of the European Economic Association, 7: 697–721.Google Scholar
Canova, F. and Ferroni, F. (2012). “The dynamics of US inflation: can monetary policy explain the changes?Journal of Econometrics, 167: 47–60.Google Scholar
Canzoneri, M. B. (1985). “Monetary policy games and the role of private information.” American Economic Review, 75: 1056–1070.Google Scholar
Canzoneri, M. B. and Henderson, D. W. (1991). Monetary policy in interdependent economies: a game-theoretic approach. Cambridge MA: MIT Press.
Canzoneri, M. B., Cumby, R. E. and Diba, B. T. (2001). “Is the price level determined by the needs of fiscal solvency?American Economic Review, 91: 1221–1238.Google Scholar
Carlstrom, C. and Fuerst, T. (2001). “Monetary shocks, agency costs, and business cycles.” Carnegie–Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 54: 1–27.Google Scholar
Carpenter, S., Ihrig, J., Klee, E., Quinn, D. and Boote, A. (2013). “The Federal Reserve's balance sheet and earnings: a primer and projections.” Finance and Economics Discussion Series, No. 2013–01.
Cecchetti, S. and Schoenholtz, K. (2011). Money, banking and financial markets (edn). New York: McGraw-Hill.
Cecioni, M., Ferrero, G. and Secchi, A. (2011). “Unconventional monetary policy in theory and in practice.” Bank of Italy Occasional Papers, No. 102.
CESifo (2013). World economic survey, No 12. Munich: CESifo.
Chari, V. and Kehoe, P. J. (2008). “Time inconsistency and free-riding in a monetary union.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 40: 1329–1355.Google Scholar
Checherita-Westphal, C., Hughes Hallett, A. and Rother, P. (2013). “Fiscal sustainability using growth-maximising debt targets.” Applied Economics, 46: 638–647.Google Scholar
Christiano, L. J. (1991). “Modeling the liquidity effect of a money shock.” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 15: 3–34.Google Scholar
Christiano, L. J. and Eichenbaum, M. (1992). “Liquidity effects and the monetary transmission mechanism.” American Economic Review, 82: 346–353.Google Scholar
Christiano, L. J. and Fitzgerald, T. J. (2003). “The band pass filter.” International Economic Review, 44: 435–465.Google Scholar
Christiano, L. J., Eichenbaum, M. and Evans, C. L. (1999). “Monetary policy shocks: what have we learned and to what end?” in Taylor, J. B. and Woodford, M. (eds.), Handbook of monetary economics, Volume 1A: 65–148. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Christiano, L. J., Eichenbaum, M. and Evans, C. L. (2005). “Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy.” Journal of Political Economy, 113: 1–45.Google Scholar
Christiano, L., Motto, R. and Rostagno, M. (2003). “The great depression and the Friedman–Schwartz hypothesis.Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 35: 1119–1198.Google Scholar
Christiano, L., Motto, R. and Rostagno, M. (2007). “Shocks, structures or policies? The euro area and the US after 2001.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 32: 2476–2506.Google Scholar
Christiano, L., Motto, R. and Rostagno, M. (2010). “Financial factors and economic fluctuations.” European Central Bank Working Paper Series, No. 1192.
Christiano, L. J., Eichenbaum, M. and Rebelo, S. (2011). “When is the government spending multiplier large?Journal of Political Economy, 119: 78–121.Google Scholar
Chugh, S. K. (2013). “Costly external finance and labor market dynamics.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 37: 2882–2291.Google Scholar
Ciccarone, G., Di Bartolomeo, G. and Marchetti, E. (2007). “Unions, fiscal policy and central bank transparency.” The Manchester School, 75: 617–633.Google Scholar
Clarida, R., Galì, J. and Gertler, M. (1999). “The science of monetary policy: a New Keynesian perspective.” Journal of Economic Literature, 37: 1661–1707.Google Scholar
Clarida, R., Galì, J. and Gertler, M. (2000). “Monetary policy rules and macroeconomic stability: evidence and some theory.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115: 147–180.Google Scholar
Coenen, G. and Straub, R. (2005). “Does government spending crowd in private consumption? Theory and empirical evidence for the euro area.” International Finance, 8: 435–470.Google Scholar
Coenen, G., Straub, R. and Trabandt, M. (2012). “Fiscal policy and the Great Recession in the euro area.” American Economic Review, 102: 71–76.Google Scholar
Cogan, J. F., Cwik, T., Taylor, J. B. and Wieland, V. (2010). “New Keynesian versus Old Keynesian government spending multipliers.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 34: 281–295.Google Scholar
Cogley, T. and Sargent, T. J. (2002). “Evolving post-World War II US inflation dynamics,” in Bernanke, B. S. and Rogoff, K. (eds.), NBER macroeconomic annual 2001: 331–388. Cambridge MA: MIT Press.
Cogley, T. and Sargent, T. J. (2005). “Drifts and volatilities: monetary policies and outcomes in the post-WWII US.” Review of Economic Dynamics, 8: 262–302.Google Scholar
Colciago, A. (2011). “Rule of thumb consumers meet sticky wages.” Journal of Money Credit and Banking, 43: 325–353.Google Scholar
Coibion, O., Gorodnichenko, Y. and Wieland, J. (2012). “The optimal inflation rate in New Keynesian models: should central banks raise their inflation targets in light of the zero lower bound?Review of Economic Studies, 79: 1371–1406.Google Scholar
Commission of the European Communities (1990). “One market, one money. An evaluation of the potential benefits and costs of forming an economic and monetary union.” European economy, No 44.
Commission of the European Communities (1991). “The economics of EMU.” Background studies for European Economy, No. 44 One market, one money. European economy, Special edition, No. 1.
Coricelli, F., Cukierman, A. and Dalmazzo, A. (2004). “Economic performance and stabilization policy a monetary union with imperfect labor and goods markets,” in Widgren, M. (ed.), Issues of monetary integration in Europe. Cambridge MA: MIT Press.
Coricelli, F., Cukierman, A. and Dalmazzo, A. (2006). “Monetary institutions, monopolistic competition, unionized labor markets and economic performance.” Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 108: 39–63.Google Scholar
Council of Economic Advisers (1962). Economic report of the President. Washington DC: Government Printing Office.
Crowley, P. and Hughes Hallett, A. (2014). “Volatility transfers between cycles: a theory of why the Great Moderation was more mirage than moderation.” Bank of Finland Research Discussion Paper Series, No. 1423.
Crowley, P. and Hughes Hallett, A. (2015). “Great moderation or will o’ the wisp? A time-frequency decomposition of GDP for the US and UK.” Journal of Macroeconomics, 44: 82–97.Google Scholar
Cubitt, R. P. (1992). “Monetary policy games and private sector precommitment.” Oxford Economic Papers, 44: 513–530.Google Scholar
Cubitt, R. P. (1995). “Corporatism, monetary policy and macroeconomic performance: a simple game theoretic analysis.” Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 97: 245–259.Google Scholar
Cukierman, A. (1984). Inflation, stagflation, relative prices, and imperfect information. Cambridge University Press.
Cukierman, A. (1992). Central bank strategy, credibility, and independence. Cambridge MA: MIT Press.
Cukierman, A. (2004). “Monetary institutions, monetary union and unionized labor markets – some recent developments,” in Beetsma, R., Favero, C., Missale, A., Muscatelli, V. A., Natale, P. and Tirelli, P. (eds.), Monetary policy, fiscal policies and labour markets: key aspects of macroeconomic policymaking in EMU: 299–326. Cambridge University Press.
Cukierman, A. and Meltzer, A. H. (1986). “A theory of ambiguity, credibility, and inflation under discretion and asymmetric information.” Econometrica, 54: 1099–1128.Google Scholar
Cukierman, A. and Lippi, F. (1999). “Central bank independence, centralization of wage bargaining, inflation and unemployment: theory and some evidence.” European Economic Review, 43: 1395–1434.Google Scholar
Cukierman, A. and Lippi, F. (2001). “Labor markets and monetary union: a strategic analysis.” The Economic Journal, 111: 541–561.Google Scholar
Cukierman, A. and Gerlach, S. (2003). “The inflation bias revisited: theory and some international evidence.” The Manchester School, 71: 541–565.Google Scholar
Cúrdia, V. and Woodford, M. (2011). “The central-bank balance sheet as an instrument of monetary policy.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 58: 47–74.Google Scholar
Dabla–Norris, E., Guo, S., Haksar, V., Kim, M., Kochhar, K., Wiseman, K. and Zdzienicka, A. (2015). “The new normal: a sector-level perspective on productivity trends in advanced economies.” IMF staff discussion note. Washington DC: IMF.
Davig, T., Leeper, E. and Walker, T. (2010). “Unfunded liabilities and uncertain fiscal financing.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 57: 600–619.Google Scholar
De Bonis, R., Giustiniani, A. and Gomel, G. (1999). “Crises, bail-outs of banks and countries: linkages, analogies, and differences.” The World Economy, 22: 55–86.Google Scholar
De Cecco, M. (1984). The international gold standard. Money and empire (edn). New York: St. Martin's Press.
De Grauwe, P. (2009). “The fragility of Eurozone's institutions.” Open Economies Review, 21: 167–174.Google Scholar
De Grauwe, P. (2010). Economics of the monetary union. Oxford University Press.
Debelle, G. and Fischer, S. (1994). “How independent should a central bank be?” in Furher, J. (ed.), Goals, guidelines, and constraints facing monetary policymakers, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Conference Series, No. 38: 195–225.
Del Negro, M., Giannoni, M. and Patterson, C. (2012). “The forward guidance puzzle.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Staff Report No. 574.
Del, M. Negro, Giannoni, M. and Patterson, C. (2013). “The macroeconomic effects of forward guidance,” in Haan, W. den (ed.), Forward guidance perspectives from central bankers, scholars and market participants:107–114. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research.
Delli Gatti, D., Desiderio, S., Gaffeo, E., Cirillo, P. and Gallegati, M. (2011). Macroeconomics from the bottom-up. Berlin: Springer.
DeLong, J. B. (2000). “The triumph of monetarism.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14: 83–94.Google Scholar
Demertzis, M., Hughes Hallet, A. and Viegi, N. (2004). “An independent central bank faced with elected governments.” European Journal of Political Economy, 20: 907–922.Google Scholar
Demertzis, M. and Hughes Hallett, A. (2007). “Central Bank Transparency in Theory and Practice”, Journal of Macroeconomics, 29, 760–89.Google Scholar
Dennis, R. (2010). “When is discretion superior to timeless perspective policymaking?Journal of Monetary Economics, 57: 266–277.Google Scholar
Detken, C. and Gärtner, M. (1994). “Governments, trade unions and the macroeconomy: an expository analysis of the political business cycle.” Public Choice, 73: 37–53.Google Scholar
Di Bartolomeo, G. (2001). “Partisanship, corporatism and economic performance.” Faculty of Applied Economics Working Papers Series, No. 4. University of Antwerp.
Di Bartolomeo, G. (2002). “Calmfors and Driffill's hump-shaped relationship: a different view,” in Balducci, R. and Staffolani, S. (eds.), Income distribution, unemployment and growth:261–280. Naples: ESI.
Di Bartolomeo, G. (2007). “Interest groups and the monetary policy management.” Journal of Current Issues in Finance, Business and Economics, 1: 71–89.Google Scholar
Di Bartolomeo, G. (2014). “Optimal degree of union centralization.” Studies in Microeconomics, 2: 201–211.Google Scholar
Di Bartolomeo, G. and Giuli, F. (2011). “Fiscal and monetary interaction under monetary policy uncertainty.” European Journal of Political Economy, 27: 369–375.Google Scholar
Di Bartolomeo, G. and Marchetti, E. (2004). “Central banks and information provided to the private sector.” BNL Quarterly Review, 230: 265–297.Google Scholar
Di Bartolomeo, G. and Pauwels, W. (2006). “The issue of instability in a simple policy game between the central bank and a representative union.” Public Choice, 126: 275–298.Google Scholar
Di Bartolomeo, G. and Rossi, L. (2007a). “Efficacy of monetary policy and limited asset market participation.” International Journal of Economic Theory, 3: 213–218.Google Scholar
Di Bartolomeo, G. and Rossi, L. (2007b). “Heterogeneous consumers, demand regimes, monetary policy and equilibrium determinacy.” Rivista Italiana di Politica Economica, 97: 111–142.Google Scholar
Di Bartolomeo, G. and Manzo, M. (2010). “Fiscal policy under balanced budget and indeterminacy: a New Keynesian perspective.” Scottish Journal of Economic Policy, 57: 455–472.Google Scholar
Di Bartolomeo, G. and Giannini, B. (2015). “Near-rational expectations and optimal fiscal and monetary policy under sticky prices.” University of Teramo Working Paper Series No. 120.
Di Bartolomeo, G. and Di Pietro, M. (2015a). “Optimal inflation targeting rule under positive hazard functions for price changes.” Macroeconomic Dynamics, forthcoming.
Di Bartolomeo, G. and Di Pietro, M. (2015b). “Intrinsic persistence of wage inflation in New Keynesian models of the business cycles.” University of Teramo Working Paper Series No. 118.
Di Bartolomeo, G., Giuli, F. and Manzo, M. (2009). “Policy uncertainty, symbiosis, and the optimal fiscal and monetary conservativeness.” Empirica, 36: 446–474.Google Scholar
Di Bartolomeo, G., Rossi, L. and Tancioni, M. (2010). “Monetary policy, rule-of-thumb consumers and external habits: a G7 comparison.” Applied Economics, 43: 2721–2738.Google Scholar
Di Bartolomeo, G., Tirelli, P. and Acocella, N. (2015a). “The comeback of inflation as an optimal public finance tool.” International Journal of Central Banking, 11: 43–70.Google Scholar
Di Bartolomeo, G., Di Pietro, M. and Giannini, B. (2015b). “Optimal monetary policy in a New Keynesian model with heterogeneous expectations.” University of Teramo Working Paper Series No. 119.
Dillard, D. (1984). “Keynes and Marx: a centennial appraisal.” Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 6: 421–432.Google Scholar
Dincer, N. and Eichengreen, B. (2008). “Central bank transparency: where, why and with what effects?” in Touffut, J.–P. (ed.), Central banks as economic institutions. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Dincer, N. and Eichengreen, B. (2010). “Central bank transparency: causes, consequences and updates.” Theoretical Inquires in Law, 11: 75–120.Google Scholar
Dixit, A. and Lambertini, L. (2001). “Monetary–fiscal policy interactions and commitment versus discretion in a monetary union.” European Economic Review, 45: 977–987.Google Scholar
Dixit, A. K. and Lambertini, L. (2003a). “Interactions of commitment and discretion in monetary and fiscal issues.” American Economic Review, 93: 1522–1542.Google Scholar
Dixit, A. and Lambertini, L. (2003b). “Symbiosis of monetary and fiscal policies in a monetary union.” Journal of International Economics, 60: 235–247.Google Scholar
Dolls, M., Fuest, C. and Peichl, A. (2012). “Automatic stabilizers and economic crisis: US vs. Europe.” Journal of Public Economics, 96: 279–294.Google Scholar
Domar, E. D. (1946). “Capital expansion, rate of growth and employment.” Econometrica, 14: 137–147.Google Scholar
Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of good decision-making in democracy. New York: Harper & Row.
Drazen, A. (2000). Political economy in macroeconomics. Princeton University Press.
Driffill, J. (2006). “The centralization of wage bargaining revisited: what have we learnt?Journal of Common Market Studies, 44: 731–756.Google Scholar
Dynan, K. E., Elmendorf, D. W. and Sichel, D. E. (2006). “Can financial innovation help to explain the reduced volatility of economic activity.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 53: 123–150.Google Scholar
EEAG (2011). The EEAG Report on the European economy 2011. Munich: Cesifo.
Eggertsson, G. and Woodford, M. (2003). “The zero bound on interest rates and optimal monetary policy.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1: 139–233.Google Scholar
Eggertsson, G. and Woodford, M. (2004). “Policy options in a liquidity trap.” American Economic Review, 94: 76–79.Google Scholar
Eichenbaum, M. (1992). “Comment on interpreting the macroeconomic time series facts: the effects of monetary policy by Christopher Sims.” European Economic Review, 36: 1001–1012.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, B. (1993). “European monetary unification.” Journal of Economic Literature, 31: 1321–1357.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, B. and Wyplosz, C. (1998). “The stability pact: more than a minor nuisance?Economic Policy, 13: 65–113.Google Scholar
Eijffinger, S. C. W. and Haan, J. D. (2000). European monetary and fiscal policy. Oxford University Press.
Eijffinger, S. C. W., Hoeberichts, M. and Shaling, E. (2000). “Why money talks and wealth whispers: monetary uncertainty and mystique.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 32: 218–235.Google Scholar
Engwerda, J., Boldea, O., Michalak, T., Plasmans, J. and Salmah, A. (2012). “A simulation study of an ASEAN monetary union.” Economic Modelling, 29: 1870–1890.Google Scholar
Evans, P. (2010). “Is it labor's turn to globalize? Twenty-first century opportunities and strategic responses.” Global Labour Journal, 1: 351–379.Google Scholar
Fatás, A., Hughes Hallett, A., Sibert, A., Strauch, R. and Hagen, J. von (2003). “Stability and growth in Europe: towards a better pact.” Monitoring European Integration, CEPR Monitoring European Integration Series, No. 13. London: CEPR.
Fawley, B. W. and Juvenal, L. (2012). “Monetary policy quantitative easing: lessons we've learned.” The Regional Economist (July). Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.
Fellner, W., Gilbert, M., Hansen, B., Kahn, R., Lutz, F. and Wolff, P. De (1961). The problem of rising prices. Paris: OECD.
Fernandez Villaverde, J. and Rubio Ramirez, J. (2008). “How structural are structural parameter values,” in Acemoglu, D., Rogoff, K. and Woodford, M. (eds.), NBER macroeconomic annual 2007:83–137. Cambridge MA: MIT Press.
Fernandez–Villaverde, J., Garicano, L. and Santos, T. (2013). “Political credit cycles: the case of the euro zone.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 27: 145–166.Google Scholar
Fischer, S. (1999). “On the need for an international lender of last resort.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 13: 85–104.Google Scholar
Fisher, I. (1933). “The debt-deflation theory of the Great Depression.” Econometrica, 1: 337–357.Google Scholar
Fleming, I. J. (1962). “Domestic financial policies under fixed and under floating exchange rates.” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, 9: 369–379.Google Scholar
Foreman–Peck, J., Hughes Hallett, A. and Ma, Y. (1992). “The transmission of the Great Depression in the United States, Britain, France and Germany.” European Economic Review, 36: 685–694.Google Scholar
Foucault, M. (2008). The birth of biopolitics: lectures at the Collège de France, 1978–1979. Basingstoke: Palgrave.
Fratianni, M. and von Hagen, J. (1992). The European monetary system and European monetary union. Boulder: Westview Press.
Fratzscher, M., Lo Duca, M. and Straub, R. (2013). “On the international spillovers of US quantitative easing.” European Central Bank Working Paper Series, No. 1557.
Freeman, R. B. (2005). “Labour market institutions without blinders: the debate over flexibility and labour market performance.” International Economic Journal RIEJ, 19: 129–145.Google Scholar
Friedman, B. M. (2013). “The simple analytics of monetary policy: a post-crisis approach,” in AEA Committee on Economic Education at AEA Meetings January 2013. San Diego.
Friedman, M. (1953). Essays in positive economics. Chicago University Press.
Friedman, M. (1960). A program for monetary stability. Fordham University Press.
Friedman, M. (1962). Capitalism and freedom. University of Chicago Press.
Friedman, M. (1968). “The role of monetary policy.” American Economic Review, 58: 1–17.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. (1969). “The optimum quantity of money,” in The optimum quantity of money and other essays. Chicago: Aldine.
Friedman, M. and Schwartz, A. (1963). A monetary history of the United States 1867 to 1960. Princeton University Press.
Frisch, R. (1949). “A memorandum on price–wage–tax subsidy policies as instruments in maintaining optimal employment.” UN Document E (CN1/Dub 2). New York: UN.
Frisch, R. (1961). “A survey of types of economic forecasting and programming and a brief discussion of the Oslo channel model.” Memorandum from the Institute of Economics at the University of Oslo, (May 13, 1961).
Fuerst, T. (1992). “Liquidity, loanable funds and real activity.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 29: 3–24.Google Scholar
Gai, P., Haldane, A. and Kapadia, S. (2011). “Complexity, concentration and contagion.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 58: 453–470.Google Scholar
Galbiati, M. and Soramaki, K. (2011). “An agent-based model of payment systems.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 35: 859–875.Google Scholar
Galbraith, J. K. (1987). Economics in perspective. A critical history. Boston: Houghton Mifflin Co.
Galí, J. (2008). Monetary policy, inflation, and the business cycle. Princeton University Press.
Galí, J. and Gertler, M. (2007). “Macroeconomic modeling for monetary policy evaluation.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21: 25–46.Google Scholar
Galí, J. and Monacelli, T. (2008). “Optimal monetary and fiscal policy in a currency union.” Journal of International Economics, 76: 116–132.Google Scholar
Galí, J. and Gambetti, L. (2009). “On the sources of great moderation.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 1: 26–57.Google Scholar
Galì, J., Lòpez–Salido, D. and Vallés, J. (2004). “Rule-of-thumb consumers and the design of interest rate rules.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 36: 739–764.Google Scholar
Galì, J., López–Salido, D. and Vallés, J. (2007). “Understanding the effects of government spending on consumption.” Journal of the European Economic Association, 5: 227–270.Google Scholar
Gambetti, L., Pappa, E. and Canova, F. (2008). “The structural dynamics of US output and inflation. What explains the changes?Journal of Money Credit and Banking, 40: 369–388.Google Scholar
Gechert, S. and Rannenberg, A. (2014). “Are fiscal multipliers regime-dependent? A meta regression analysis.” IMK Working Paper Series, No. 139.
Gechert, S., Hughes Hallett, A. and Rannenberg, A. (2016). “Fiscal multipliers in downturns and the effects of Eurozone consolidation.” Applied Economic Letters, DOI: 10.1080/13504851.2015.1137545.
Geraats, P. (2002). “Central bank transparency.” The Economic Journal, 112: 532–565.Google Scholar
Gerali, A., Neri, S., Sessa, L. and Signoretti, F. M. (2010). “Credit and banking in a DSGE model of the euro area.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 42: 107–141.Google Scholar
Gertler, M. and Kiyotaki, N. (2011). “Financial intermediation and credit policy in business cycle analysis,” in Friedman, B. M. and Woodford, M. (eds.), Handbook of Monetary Economics, Volume 3A: 547–600. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Gertler, M. and Karadi, P. (2011). “A model of unconventional monetary policy.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 58: 17–34.Google Scholar
Gertler, M. and Karadi, P. (2013). “QE 1 vs. 2 vs. 3…: A framework for analyzing large-scale asset purchases as a monetary policy tool.” International Journal of Central Banking, 9: 5–53.Google Scholar
Gertler, M. and Karadi, P. (2015). “Monetary policy surprises, credit costs, and economic activity.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 7: 44–76.Google Scholar
Giannone, D., Reichlin, L. and Lenza, M. (2008). “Explaining the Great Moderation: it is not the shocks.” Journal of European Economic Association, 6: 621–633.Google Scholar
Giavazzi, F. and Pagano, M. (1990). “Can severe fiscal contraction be expansionary? Tales of two small European countries,” in Blanchard, O. J. and Fischer, S. (eds.), NBER macroeconomics annual 1990:75–111. Cambridge MA: MIT Press.
Giavazzi, F. and Pagano, M. (1996). “Non-Keynesian effects of fiscal policy changes: international evidence and the Swedish experience.” Swedish Economic Policy Review, 3: 67–112.Google Scholar
Gilpin, R. (2001). Global political economy: understanding the international economic order. Princeton University Press.
Girouard, N. and André, C. (2005). “Measuring cyclically-adjusted budget balances for OECD countries.” OECD Economics Department Working Paper Series, No. 434.
Gnocchi, S. (2009). “Non-atomistic wage setters and monetary policy in a New Keynesian framework.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 41: 1613–1630.Google Scholar
Goodfriend, M. (1993). “Interest rate policy and the inflation scare problem: 1979–1992.” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly, 79: 1–24.Google Scholar
Goodfriend, M. and King, R. (1997). “The New Neoclassical Synthesis and the role of monetary policy,” in Bernanke, B. and Rotemberg, J. (eds.), NBER macroeconomics annual 1997:231–296. Cambridge MA: MIT Press.
Goodfriend, M. and McCallum, B. T. (2007). “Banking and interest rates in monetary policy analysis: a quantitative exploration.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 54: 1480–1507.Google Scholar
Goodhart, C. A. E. (1975a). “Monetary relationships: a view from Threadneedle street,” in Papers in monetary economics, Volume I. Canberra: Reserve Bank of Australia.
Goodhart, C. A. E. (1975b). “Problems of monetary management: the UK experience,” in Papers in monetary economics, Volume I. Canberra: Reserve Bank of Australia.
Goodhart, C. E. A. and Illing, G. (eds.) (2002). Financial crises, contagion and the lender of last resort. Oxford University Press.
Ghosh, A. R., Kim, J. I., Mendoza, E. G. and Ostry, J. D. (2013). “Fiscal fatigue, fiscal space and debt sustainability in advanced economies.” The Economic Journal, 123: 4–30.Google Scholar
Grüner, H. P. (2002). “How much should central banks talk? A new argument.” Economics Letters, 77: 195–198.Google Scholar
Grüner, H. P. and Hefeker, G. (1999). “How will EMU affect inflation and employment in Europe?Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 101: 33–47.Google Scholar
Guerron–Quintana, P. A. (2009). “Money demand heterogeneity and the great moderation.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 56: 255–266.Google Scholar
Gürkaynak, R. S., Sack, B. and Swanson, E. T. (2005). “Do actions speak louder than words? The response of asset prices to monetary policy actions and statements.” International Journal of Central Banking, 1: 55–93.Google Scholar
Gylfason, T. and Lindbeck, A. (1994). “The interaction of monetary policy and wages.” Public Choice, 79: 33–46.Google Scholar
Haan, W. den (ed.) (2013). Forward guidance perspectives from central bankers, scholars and market participants. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research.
Hagen, von J., Hughes Hallett, A. and Strauch, R. (2002). “Fiscal consolidation in Europe: quality, durability and composition.” Journal of Japanese and International Economics, 16: 512–535.Google Scholar
Hall, R. (2010). “Why does the economy fall to pieces after a financial crisis?Journal of Economic Perspectives, 24: 3–20.Google Scholar
Hanckè, B. and Rhodes, M. (2005). “EMU and labor market institutions in Europe: the rise and fall of national social pacts.” Work and Occupations, 32: 196–228.Google Scholar
Hansen, B. (1958). The economic theory of fiscal policy. London: Allen & Unwin.
Harrod, R. F. (1939). “An essay in dynamic theory.” The Economic Journal, 49: 14–33.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1976). The constitution of liberty. London: Routledge: 55–56.
Helleiner, E. (2005). “The evolution of the international monetary and financial system,” in Ravenhill, J. (ed.), Global political economy. Oxford University Press.
Henderson, D. W. and McKibbin, W. J. (1993). “A comparison of some basic monetary policy regimes for open economies: implications of different degrees of instrument adjustment and wage persistence.” Carnegie–Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 39: 221–317.Google Scholar
Hendry, D. and Ericsson, N. (1991). “An econometric analysis of UK money demand in monetary trends in the United States and the United Kingdom.” American Economic Review, 81: 8–38.Google Scholar
Hibbs, D. A. (1977). “Political parties and macroeconomic policy.” American Political Science Review, 71: 1467–1487.Google Scholar
Hibbs, D. A. (1986). “Political parties and macroeconomic policies and outcomes in the United States.” American Economic Review, 76: 66–70.Google Scholar
Hibbs, D. A. (1987). The American political economy: macroeconomics and electoral politics in the United States. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press.
Hibbs, D. A. (1992). “Partisan theory after fifteen years.” European Journal of Political Economy, 8: 361–373.Google Scholar
Hicks, J. (1974). The crisis of Keynesian economics. New York: Basic Books.
Hirsch, A. and De Marchi, N. (1986). “Making a case when theory is unfalsifiable: Friedman's monetary history.” Economics and Philosophy, 2: 1–21.Google Scholar
Hughes Hallett, A. (1979). “Computing revealed preferences and limits to the validity of quadratic objective functions for policy optimization.” Economics Letters, 2: 27–32.Google Scholar
Hughes Hallett, A. (1989). “Econometrics and the theory of economic policy: the Tinbergen–Theil contributions 40 years on.” Oxford Economic Papers, 41: 189–214.Google Scholar
Hughes Hallett, A. (2004). “A central bank for all seasons? The ‘lower inflation at no cost’ proposition under political uncertainty.Macroeconomic Dynamics, 8: 207–225.Google Scholar
Hughes Hallett, A. (2015a). “Quantitative easing: lessons for the euro area from the experiences of the US Federal Reserve, the Bank of England and the Bank of Japan,” European Parliament, Policy Department, http://www.europarl.europa.eu/committees/en/econ/monetary-dialogue.html.
Hughes Hallett, A. (2015b). “Quantitative easing: side effects in the financial markets, in inequality and in the risk of secular stagnation,” European Parliament, Policy Department, http://www.europarl.europa.eu/committees/en/econ/monetary-dialogue.html.
Hughes Hallett, A. (2015c). “Is nominal GDP targeting a suitable tool for ECB monetary policy?” European Parliament, Policy Department, http://www.europarl.europa.eu/committees/en/econ/monetary-dialogue.html.
Hughes Hallett, A. (2015d). “Monetary Policy and Sovereign Debt: Does the ECB Take Eurozone Fiscal Imbalances into Account?” in Empirica, 41(3), 499–520.Google Scholar
Hughes Hallett, A. J. and Viegi, N. (2003). “Transparency and the strategic use of private information in monetary policy.” The Manchester School, 71: 498–520.Google Scholar
Hughes Hallett, A. and Weymark, D. (2004). “Independent monetary policies and social equity.” Economics Letters, 85: 103–110.Google Scholar
Hughes Hallett, A. and Martinez Oliva, J. C. (2012). “Global imbalances in a world of inflexible real exchange rates and capital controls.” Global Economic Review, 41: 319–340.Google Scholar
Hughes Hallett, A. and Acocella, N. (2015a). “Stabilization and commitment: forward guidance in economies with rational expectations.” Macroeconomic Dynamics, forthcoming.
Hughes Hallett, A. and Acocella, N. (2015b). “Rational expectations, forward guidance and endogenous policy rules: necessary conditions for stabilisation, especially at the zero lower bound.” St. Andrews University, mimeo.
Hughes Hallett, A., Ma, Y. and Melitz, J. (1996). “Unification and the policy predicament in Germany.” Economic Modelling, 13: 519–544.Google Scholar
Hughes Hallett, A., Lewis, J. and Hagen, J. von (2004). “Fiscal policy in Europe 1991–2003: an evidence based analysis,” Centre for Economic Policy Research, London.
Hughes Hallett, A., Di Bartolomeo, G. and Acocella, N. (2012a). “A general theory of controllability and expectations anchoring for small-open economies.” Journal of International Money and Finance, 31: 397–411.Google Scholar
Hughes Hallett, A., Di Bartolomeo, G. and Acocella, N. (2012b). “Central banks and economic policy after the crisis: what have we learned?” in Baker, H. K., Riddick, L. A. (eds.), Survey of international finance: 158–181. Oxford University Press.
Hughes Hallett, A., Kattai, R. and Lewis, J. (2012c). “How reliable are cyclically adjusted budget balances in real time?.” Contemporary Economic Policy, 30: 75–92.Google Scholar
Hughes Hallett, A., Libich, J. and Stehlik, P. (2014). “Monetary and fiscal policy interaction with various degrees of commitment.” Finance a úvěr – Czech Journal of Economics and Finance, 64: 2–29.Google Scholar
Hughes Hallett, A., Rannenberg, A. and Schreiber, S. (2016). “Contingent fiscal multipliers and monetary policy: New Keynesian vs. Old Keynesian Policy interactions,” in Blüschke, Dmitri and Wohlgemuth, Norbert, Economic policy over time. Peter Lang Verlag, Frankfurt.
Iacoviello, M. (2005). “House prices, borrowing constraints, and monetary policy in the business cycle.” American Economic Review, 95: 739–764.Google Scholar
Iacoviello, M. and Neri, S. (2010). “Housing market spillovers: evidence from an estimated DSGE model.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2: 125–164.Google Scholar
International Monetary Fund (2002). Annual Report 2002. Washington DC: IMF.
International Monetary Fund (2013). World Economic Outlook Database (April). Washington DC: IMF.
Ireland, P. N. (1999). “Does the time-consistency problem explain the behavior of inflation in the United States?Journal of Monetary Economics, 44: 279–291.Google Scholar
Jeanne, O. (1999). “Currency crises: a perspective on recent theoretical development.” CEPR Discussion Paper, No. 2170.
Jensen, C. and McCallum, B. T. (2002). “The non-optimality of proposed monetary policy rules under timeless perspective commitment.” Economics Letters, 77: 163–168.Google Scholar
Johnson, H. G. (1971). “The Keynesian revolution and the monetarist counter-revolution.” American Economic Review, 2: 1–14.Google Scholar
Joyce, M., Tong, M. and Woods, R. (2011). “The United Kingdom's quantitative easing policy: design, operation and impact.” Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, Q3: 200–212.Google Scholar
Kahn, J. A., McConnell, M. M. and Perez–Quiros, G. (2002). “On the causes of the increased stability of the US economy.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review, 8: 183–202.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. (1970). “The new monetarism.” Lloyds Bank Review, 97: 1–18.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. (1976). “Inflation and recession in the world economy.” The Economic Journal, 86: 703–714.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. (1982). The scourge of monetarism. Oxford University Press.
Kalecki, M. (1943). “Political aspects of full employment.” Political Quarterly; reprint in Kalecki, M. (1971). Selected essays on the dynamics of the capitalist economy 1933–1970. Cambridge University Press.
Kehoe, P. J. (1989). “Policy coordination among benevolent governments may be undesirable.” Review of Economic Studies, 56: 289–296.Google Scholar
Kenen, P. (1969). “The theory of optimum currency areas: an eclectic view,” in Mundell, R. M. and Swoboda, A. (eds.), Monetary problems of the international economy. Chicago University Press.
Keynes, J. M. (1919). “The economic consequences of the peace,” reprint in The collected writings of J. M. Keynes, Volume II. London: Macmillan.
Keynes, J. M. (1924). Tract on monetary system. London: Macmillan.
Keynes, J. M. (1936). The general theory of employment, interest and money. London: Macmillan.
Keynes, J. M. (1940). “How to pay for the war,” reprint in Keynes, J. M. (1972). The collected writings of J. M. Keynes, Volume IX. London: Macmillan.
Kim, C., Morley, J. and Piger, J. (2008). “Bayesian counterfactual analysis of the sources of the great moderation.” Journal of Applied Econometrics, 23: 173–191.Google Scholar
Kindleberger, C. P. and Aliber, R. Z. (2005). Manias, panics, and crashes: a history of financial crises (edn). New York: John Wiley & Sons.
Kirman, A. (2010). “The economic crisis is a crisis for economic theory.” CESifo Economic Studies, 56: 498–535.Google Scholar
Kirsanova, T., Stehn, S. J. and Vines, D. (2006). “The interactions between fiscal policy and monetary policy.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 21: 532–564.Google Scholar
Kiyotaki, N. and Moore, J. (1997). “Credit cycles.” Journal of Political Economy, 105: 211–248.Google Scholar
Klenow, P. and Malin, B. (2011). “Microeconomic evidence on price-setting,” in Friedman, B. M. and Woodford, M. (eds.), Handbook of monetary economics, Volume 3B: 231–284. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Kotlikoff, L. (2006). “Is the US bankrupt?Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Review, 88: 235–249.Google Scholar
Krugman, P. (1998). “It's Baaaack! Japan's slump and the return of the liquidity trap.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2: 137–187.Google Scholar
Krugman, P. (2012). “Revenge of the optimum currency area,” in Acemoglu, D., Parker, J. and Woodford, M. (eds.), NBER macroeconomics annual 2012:439–448. University of Chicago Press.
Kuo–Chun, Y. (2013). “An Asian currency unit: simulations for its effects on East Asia.” The World Economy, 36: 1611–1631.Google Scholar
Kydland, F. E and Prescott, E. C. (1977). “Rules rather than discretion: the inconsistency of optimal plans.” Journal of Political Economy, 85: 473–491.Google Scholar
Kydland, F. E. and Prescott, E. C. (1982). “Time to build and aggregate fluctuations.” Econometrica, 50: 1345–1370.Google Scholar
Lall, S. (1994). “Does the bell toll for industrial strategy?World Development, 22: 645–654.Google Scholar
Lane, P. R. and Perotti, R. (1998). “The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD.” European Economic Review, 42: 887–895.Google Scholar
Lane, P. R. and McQuade, P. (2014). “Domestic credit growth and international capital flows.” Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 116: 218–252.Google Scholar
Lawler, P. (2000). “Centralised wage setting, inflation contracts, and the optimal choice of central banker.” The Economic Journal, 110: 559–575.Google Scholar
Lawler, P. (2001). “Monetary policy, central bank objectives, and social welfare with strategic wage setting.” Oxford Economic Papers, 53: 94–113.Google Scholar
Layard, R., Nickell, S. J. and Jackman, R. (1991). Unemployment: macroeconomic performance and the labour market. Oxford University Press.
Leduc, S. and Sill, K. (2007). “Monetary policy, oil shocks, and TFP: accounting for the decline in US volatility.” Review of Economic Dynamics, 10: 595–614.Google Scholar
Leeper, E. M. and Zha, T. (2003). “Modest policy interventions.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 50: 1673–1700.Google Scholar
Leith, C. and Wren–Lewis, S. (2000). “Interactions between monetary and fiscal rules.” The Economic Journal, 110: C93–C108.Google Scholar
Leith, C. and Wren–Lewis, S. (2011). “Discretionary policy in a monetary union with sovereign debt.” European Economic Review, 55: 57–74.Google Scholar
Leith, C. and Wren–Lewis, S. (2013). “Fiscal sustainability in a New Keynesian model.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 45: 1477–1516.Google Scholar
Levin, A., Lopez–Salido, D., Nelson, E. and Yun, T. (2010). “Limitations on the effectiveness of forward guidance at the zero lower bound.” International Journal of Central Banking, 6: 143–189.Google Scholar
Levine, R. (1997). “Financial development and economic growth: views and agenda.” Journal of Economic Literature, 35: 688–726.Google Scholar
Linnemann, L. and Schabert, A. (2003). “Fiscal policy in the new neoclassical synthesis.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 35: 911–929.Google Scholar
Lippi, F. (2003). “Strategic monetary policy with non-atomistic wage setters.” Review of Economic Studies, 70: 909–919.Google Scholar
Lipsey, R. G. and Parkin, J. M. (1970). “Incomes policy: a re-appraisal.” Economica, 37: 115–138.Google Scholar
Lombardo, G. and Vestin, D. (2008). “Welfare implications of Calvo vs. Rotemberg pricing assumptions.” Economics Letters, 100: 275–279.Google Scholar
Lubik, T. and Schorfheide, F. (2004). “Testing for indeterminacy: with an application to US monetary policy.” American Economic Review, 94: 190–217.Google Scholar
Lucas, R. E. Jr. (1972). “Econometric testing of the natural rate hypothesis,” in Eckstein, O. (ed.), The econometrics of price determination. Washington DC: Board of Governors of Federal Reserve System.
Lucas, R. E. Jr. (1973). “Some international evidence on output–inflation tradeoffs.” American Economic Review, 63: 326–334.Google Scholar
Lucas, R. E. Jr. (1976). “Econometric policy evaluation: a critique,” in Brunner, K. and Meltzer, A. (eds.), The Phillips curve and labor markets, Carnegie–Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Volume 1: 19–46. Amsterdam: North Holland.
Lucas, R. E. Jr. (1980). “Methods and problems in business cycle theory.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 12: 696–715.Google Scholar
Mahadeva, L. and Sterne, G. (2000). Monetary policy frameworks in a global context. New York: Routledge.
Mankiw, N. G. (1985). “Small menu costs and large business cycles: a macroeconomic model of monopoly.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100: 529–538.Google Scholar
Mankiw, N. G. (2000). “The saver–spenders theory of fiscal policy.” American Economic Review, 90: 120–125.Google Scholar
Marimon, R. (2000). “Review of Sargent's the conquest of the American inflation.” Journal of Economic Literature, 38: 405–411.Google Scholar
McCallum, B. T. (1995). “Two fallacies concerning central bank independence.” American Economic Review, 85: 207–211.Google Scholar
McCallum, B. T. (2002). “The use of policy rules in monetary policy analysis.” (Shadow Open Market Committee) Carnegie Mellon University, mimeo.
McConnell, M. M. and Perez–Quiros, G. (2000). “Output fluctuations in the United States: what has changed since the early 1980s?American Economic Review, 90: 1464–1476.Google Scholar
McKinnon, R. I. (1963). “Optimum currency areas.” American Economic Review, 53: 717–725.Google Scholar
McKinnon, R. I. (1973). Money and capital in economic development. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
McKinnon, R. I. (1979). Money in international exchange. The convertible currency system. Oxford University Press.
McKinnon, R. I. (1993). “The rules of the game: international money in historical perspective.” Journal of Economic Literature, 31: 1–44.Google Scholar
Meade, J. (1978). “The meaning of internal balance.” The Economic Journal, 88: 423–435.Google Scholar
Mélitz, J. (1997). “Some cross-country evidence about debt, deficits, and the behaviour of monetary and fiscal authorities.” CEPR Discussion Paper Series, No. 1653.
Milani, F. (2010). “Political business cycles in the New Keynesian model.” Economic Inquiry, 48: 896–915.Google Scholar
Miller, M. H. and Stiglitz, J. E. (2010). “Leverage and asset bubbles.” The Economic Journal, 120: 500–518.Google Scholar
Milone, L. M. (2012). “The roots of the International Monetary Fund's difficulties: the pioneering contribution of Federico Caffè.” History of Economic Ideas, 1: 109–130.Google Scholar
Minsky, H. (1982). Can “It” happen again?: essays on instability and finance. New York: Sharpe ME.
Mirrlees, J., Adam, S., Besley, T., Blundell, R., Bond, S., Chote, R., Gammie, M., Johnson, P., Myles, G. and Poterba, J. (2011). “Tax by design,” in mirrlees review, Volume II. Oxford University Press.
Modigliani, F. and Miller, M. (1958). “The cost of capital, corporation finance, and the theory of investment.” American Economic Review, 48: 261–297.Google Scholar
Modigliani, F. and Papademos, L. (1975). “Targets for monetary policy in the coming year.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 6: 141–165.Google Scholar
Motta, G. and Tirelli, P. (2012). “Optimal simple monetary and fiscal rules under limited asset market participation.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 44: 1351–1374.Google Scholar
Motta, G. and Tirelli, P. (2014). Limited asset market participation, income inequality and macroeconomic volatility. Lancaster University, Department of Economics, mimeo.
Motta, G. and Tirelli, P. (2015). “Money targeting, heterogeneous agents, and dynamic instability.” Macroeconomic Dynamics, 19: 288–310.Google Scholar
Mundell, R. A. (1961). “The theory of optimum currency areas.” American Economic Review, 51: 657–664.Google Scholar
Mussa, M. L., Volcker, P. A. and Tobin, J. (1994). “Monetary policy,” in Feldstein, M. (ed.), American economic policy in the 1980s. University of Chicago Press.
Muth, J. F. (1961). “Rational expectations and the theory of price movements.” Econometrica, 29: 315–355.Google Scholar
Nickell, S. (1997). “Unemployment and labor market rigidities: Europe versus North America.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11: 55–74.Google Scholar
Nickell, S. and Layard, R. (1999). “Labour market institutions and economic performance,” in Ashenfelter, O. and Card, D. (eds.), Handbook of labor economics, Volume 3: 3029–3084. Amsterdam: North Holland Press.
Niskanen, W. A. (1992). “Reaganomics,” in Henderson, D. R. (ed.), Concise encyclopedia of economics. Indianapolis: Library of Economics and Liberty.
Nordhaus, W. D. (1975). “The political business cycle.” Review of Economic Studies, 42: 169–190.Google Scholar
Obstfeld, M. and Taylor, A. M. (2004). Global capital markets. Integration, crisis and growth. Cambridge University Press.
OECD (2006). Employment outlook. Paris: OECD.
Okun, A. M. and Perry, G. L. (1970). “Notes and numbers on the profits squeeze.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1: 466–473.Google Scholar
Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action: public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press.
Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Orphanides, A. (2001). “Monetary policy rules based on real-time data.” American Economic Review, 91: 964–985.Google Scholar
Orphanides, A. (2003). “The quest for prosperity without inflation.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 50: 633–663.Google Scholar
Orphanides, A. (2004). “Monetary policy rules, macroeconomic stability, and inflation: a view from the trenches.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 36: 151–175.Google Scholar
Ostry, J. D., Ghosh, A. R., Habermeier, K., Chamon, M., Qureshi, M. S. and Reinhardt, D. B. S. (2010). Capital inflows: the role of controls. Washington DC: International Monetary Fund.
Patnaik, P. and Chandrasekhar, C. P. (1998). “India, dirigisme, structural adjustment, and the radical alternative,” in Baker, D., Epstein, G. and Pollin, R. (eds.), Globalization and progressive economic policy. Cambridge University Press.
Paulu, B. (1981). Television and radio in the United Kingdom. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.
Pecchi, L. and Piga, G. (1999). “The politics of index-linked bonds.” Economics and Politics, 11: 201–212.Google Scholar
Perry, G. L. (1978). “Slowing the wage–price spiral: the macroeconomic view.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 9: 259–299.Google Scholar
Persson, T. and Tabellini, G. (1993). “Designing institutions for monetary stability.” Carnegie–Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 39: 53–84.Google Scholar
Persson, M., Persson, T. and Svensson, L. E. O. (2006). “Time consistency of fiscal and monetary policy.” Econometrica, 74: 193–212.Google Scholar
Petrosky-Nadeau, N. and Wasmer, E. (2013). “The cyclical volatility of labor markets under frictional financial markets.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 5: 193–221.Google Scholar
Phelps, E. S. (1967). “Phillips curves, expectations of inflation and optimal unemployment over time.” Economica, 34: 254–281.Google Scholar
Phelps, E. S. (1968). “Money wage dynamics.” Journal of Political Economy, 76: 678–711.Google Scholar
Phelps, E. S. (1973). “Inflation in the theory of public finance.” The Swedish Journal of Economics, 75: 67–82.Google Scholar
Phelps, E. S. (2009). “Capitalism vs. corporatism.”Critical Review, 21 (4): 401–414.Google Scholar
Phillips, A. W. (1958). “The relationship between unemployment and the rate of change of money wages in the United Kingdom 1861–1957.” Economica, 25: 283–299.Google Scholar
Pieper, U. and Taylor, L. (1998). “The revival of the liberal creed: the IMF, the World Bank and inequality in a globalized economy,” in Baker, D., Epstein, G. and Pollin, R. (eds.), Globalization and progressive economic policy. Cambridge University Press.
Plasmans, J., Aarle, B. van, Bartolomeo, G. Di and Engwerda, J. (2006a). “Staying together or breaking apart: policy-makers’ endogenous coalitions in the European Monetary Union.” Computers & Operations Research, 33: 438–463.Google Scholar
Plasmans, J., van Aarle, B., Bartolomeo, G. Di, Engwerda, J. and Michalak, T. (2006b). Dynamic modeling of monetary and fiscal cooperation among nations. Berlin: Springer.
Plasmans, J., Aarle, B. van, Bartolomeo, G. Di, Engwerda, J. and Michalak, T. (2006c). “Macroeconomic Stabilization policies in the EMU: spillovers, asymmetries and institutions.” Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 53: 461–483.Google Scholar
Posen, A. S. (1995). “Declarations are not enough: financial sector sources of central bank independence,” in Bernanke, B. and Rotemberg, J. (eds.), NBER macroeconomics annual 1995: 253–274. Cambridge MA: MIT Press.
Posen, A. S. (1998). “Central bank independence and disinflationary credibility: a missing link?Oxford Economic Papers, 50: 335–359.Google Scholar
Plosser, C. I. (2013). “Forward guidance.” Speech at Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research's (SIEPR) Associates Meeting. Stanford, CA, February 12, 2013.
Primiceri, G. E. (2005). “Time varying structural vector autoregressions and monetary policy.” Review of Economic Studies, 72: 821–852.Google Scholar
Ravenna, F. and Walsh, C. E. (2006). “Optimal monetary policy with the cost channel.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 53: 199–216.Google Scholar
Regini, M. (1997). “Still engaging in corporatism? Recent Italian experience in a comparative perspective.” European Journal of Industrial Relations, 3: 259–278.Google Scholar
Regini, M. (2001). “Social pacts in the EC report on industrial relations in Europe?,” in Biagi, M. (ed.), Towards a European model of industrial relations?The Hague: Kluwer Law International.
Reinhart, C. M. and Rogoff, K. S. (2009). This time is different: eight centuries of financial folly. Princeton University Press.
Rhodes, M. (1998). “Globalization, labor markets and welfare state: a future of ‘competitive corporatism’?” in Rhodes, M. and Mény, Y. (eds.), The future of European welfare: a new social contract?London: Macmillan.
Ricardo, D. (1820[1888]). “Essay on the funding system,” in McCullock, J. R. (ed.), The works of David Ricardo. London: John Murray.
Ricardo, D. (1824). “Plan for the establishment of a national bank,” reprinted in McCulloch, J. R. (ed.), The works of David Ricardo. London: John Murray, 1888.
Ritschl, A. (2008). “The Anglo–German industrial productivity paradox, 1895–1938: a restatement and a possible resolution.” Journal of Economic History, 68: 535–565.Google Scholar
Robinson, J. (1937). Essays in the theory of employment. London: Blackwell.
Rogoff, K. (1985a). “The optimal degree of commitment to an intermediate monetary target.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100: 1169–1189.Google Scholar
Rogoff, K. (1985b). “Can international monetary policy cooperation be counterproductive?Journal of International Economics, 18: 199–217.Google Scholar
Rogoff, K. and Sibert, A. (1988). “Elections and macroeconomic policy cycles.” Review of Economic Studies, 55: 1–16.Google Scholar
Rotemberg, J. and Woodford, M. (1999). “Interest rate rules in an estimated sticky price model,” in Taylor, J. B. (ed.), Monetary policy rules. University of Chicago Press.
Ruggie, J. G. (1982). “International regimes, transactions, and change: embedded liberalism in the postwar economic order.” International Organization, 36: 379–415.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. (1961). Economics: an introductory analysis (edn). New York: McGraw–Hill.
Samuelson, P. A. (1964). “Theoretical notes on trade problems.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 46: 245–154.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. and Solow, R. M. (1960). “Analytical aspects of anti-inflation policy.” American Economic Review, 50: 177–194.Google Scholar
Santor, E. and Suchanek, L. (2013). “Unconventional monetary policies: evolving practices, their effects and potential costs.” Bank of Canada Review, Spring: 1–15.
Sargent, T. J. (1987). Dynamic macroeconomic theory. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press.
Sargent, T. J. (1999). The conquest of American inflation. Princeton University Press.
Sargent, T. J. and Wallace, N. (1975). “Rational expectations, the optimal monetary instrument, and the optimal money supply rule.” Journal of Political Economy, 83: 241–254.Google Scholar
Sargent, T. J. and Wallace, N. (1976). “Rational expectations and the theory of economic policy.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 2: 169–183.Google Scholar
Sargent, T. J. and Söderström, U. (2000). “The conquest of American: a summary.” Sveriges Riksbank Economic Review, 3: 12–45.Google Scholar
Schmitt–Grohe, S. and Uribe, M. (2004). “Optimal fiscal and monetary policy under sticky prices.” Journal of Economic Theory, 114: 198–230.Google Scholar
Schmitt–Grohe, S. and Uribe, M. (2011). “The optimal rate of inflation,” in Friedman, B. M. and Woodford, M. (eds.), Handbook of monetary economics:723–828. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Schmitt–Grohe, S. and Uribe, M. (2012). “Foreign demand for domestic currency and the optimal rate of inflation.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 44: 1307–1324.Google Scholar
Schumacher, E. F. (1943). “Multilateral clearing.” Economica, 10: 150–165.Google Scholar
Seater, J. J. (1993). “Ricardian equivalence.” Journal of Economic Literature, 31: 142–190.Google Scholar
Sims, C. A. (1980). “Macroeconomics and reality.” Econometrica, 48: 1–48.Google Scholar
Sims, C. A. (1982). “Policy analysis with econometric models.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1: 107–152.Google Scholar
Sims, C. A. and Zha, T. (2006). “Were there regime switches in US monetary policy?American Economic Review, 96: 54–81.Google Scholar
Skidelsky, R. (2005). “Keynes, globalisation and the Bretton Woods institutions in the light of changing ideas about markets.” World Economics, 6: 15–30.Google Scholar
Smets, F. and Wouters, R. (2003). “An estimated DSGE model for the euro area.” Journal of the European Economic Association, 1: 1123–1175.Google Scholar
Smets, F. and Wouters, R. (2007). “Shocks and frictions in US business cycles: a Bayesian DSGE approach.” American Economic Review, 97: 586–606.Google Scholar
Smith, A. (1776). An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. London: Straham & Cadell.
Solow, R. (1956). “A contribution to the theory of economic growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70: 65–94.Google Scholar
Soros, G. (1998). The crisis of global capitalism. New York: Public Affairs.
Soskice, D. and Iversen, T. (2000). “The non-neutrality of monetary policy with large price or wage setters.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115: 265–284.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, J. E. (1986). Economics of the public sector. New York: Norton & Co.
Stiglitz, J. E. (2002). Globalization and its discontents. London: Penguin Books.
Stiglitz, J. E. (2010). The Stiglitz report. Reforming the international monetary and financial systems in the wake of the global crisis. New York: The New Press.
Stiglitz, J. E. (2012). “Macroeocnomic, monetary policy, and the crisis,” in Blanchard, O. J., Romer, D., Spence, M. and Stiglitz, J. E. (eds.), In the wake of the crisis: leading economists reassess economic policy: 30–23. Cambridge CA: MIT Press.
Stiroh, J. K. (2009). “Volatility accounting: a production perspective on increased economic stability.” Journal of European Economic Association, 7: 671–696.Google Scholar
Stock, J. H. and Watson, M. W. (2003). “Has the business cycle changed and why?” in Gertler, M. and Rogoff, K. (eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2002: 159–218. Cambridge MA: MIT Press.
Streeck, W. (1998). “The internationalization of industrial relations in Europe: prospects and problems.” Politics & Society, 26: 239–259.Google Scholar
Streeck, W. (2006). “The study of organized interests: before ‘the Century’ and after,” in Crouch, C. and Streeck, W. (eds.), The diversity of democracy: corporatism, social order and political conflict. London: Edward Elgar.
Summers, L. (2013). “IMF economic forum: policy responses to crises.” Speech at the IMF Fourteenth Annual Research Conference (November 9, 2013). Washington DC: IMF.
Summers, L. (2014). “US economic prospects: secular stagnation, hysteresis and the zero lower bound.” Speech delivered to the National Association for Business Economics’ Economic Policy Conference (February 24, 2014).
Summers, P. M. (2005). “What caused the great moderation? Some cross-country evidence.” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review, 3: 5–32.Google Scholar
Summers, S. B. (2014). “Nominal GDP targeting: a simple rule to improve fed performance.” Cato Journal, 34: 315–337.Google Scholar
Summers, L., Carroll, C. and Blinder, A. S. (1987). “Why is US national saving so low?Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1987: 607–642.Google Scholar
Svensson, L. E. O. (1997). “Optimal inflation targets, ‘conservative’ central banks and linear inflation contracts.” American Economic Review, 87: 98–114.Google Scholar
Svensson, L. E. O. (1999). “Inflation targeting as a monetary policy rule.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 43: 607–654.Google Scholar
Svensson, L. E. O. (2007). “Optimal inflation targeting: further developments of inflation targeting,” in Mishkin, F. and Schmidt–Hebbel, K. (eds.), Monetary policy under inflation targeting, Volume 11 of Central Banking, Analysis, and Economic Policies: 187–225. Santiago de Chile: Central Bank of Chile.
Svensson, L. E. O. (2008). “Inflation targeting,” in Durlauf, S. N. and Blume, L. E. (eds.), The new Palgrave dictionary of economics (edn). London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Swan, T. W. (1956). “Economic growth and capital accumulation.” Economic Record, 32: 334–361.Google Scholar
Tarantelli, E. (1983). “The regulation of inflation in western countries and the degree of neocorporatism.” Economia, 7: 199–238.Google Scholar
Tarantelli, E. (1986). “The regulation of inflation and unemployment.” Industrial Relations, 25: 1–15.Google Scholar
Tarantelli, E. (1987). “Monetary policy and the regulation of inflation and unemployment,” in Gunderson, M., Meltz, N. M. and Ostry, S. (eds.), Unemployment: international perspectives: 94–102. University of Toronto Press.
Taylor, J. B. (1993). “Discretion versus policy rules in practice.” Carnegie–Rochester Series on Public Policy, 39: 195–214.Google Scholar
Taylor, J. B. (1996). “How should monetary policy respond to shocks while maintaining long-run price stability? Conceptual issues,” in Achieving price stability:181–195. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.
Taylor, J. B. (1998). “Monetary policy and long boom.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 80: 3–12.Google Scholar
Taylor, J. B. (1999). “A historical analysis of monetary policy rules,” in Taylor, J. B. (ed.), Monetary policy rules. University of Chicago Press.
Taylor, J. B. (2000). “Remarks for the panel discussion on recent changes in trend and cycle.” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Conference on “Structural change and monetary policy.”
Temin, P. (1976). Did monetary forces cause the Great Depression?New York: Norton.
Teulings, C. and Baldwin, R. (2014). Secular stagnation: facts, causes and cures. CEPR e-book, 15 August (www.cepr.org).
Theil, H. (1956). “On the theory of economic policy.” American Economic Review, 46: 360–366.Google Scholar
Theil, H. (1964). Optimal decision rules for government and industry. Amsterdam: North Holland.
Tinbergen, J. (1952). On the theory of economic policy. Amsterdam: North Holland.
Tinbergen, J. (1956). Economic policies principles and design. Amsterdam: North Holland.
Tirelli, P., Di Bartolomeo, G. and Acocella, N. (2015). “US trend inflation reinterpreted: the role of fiscal policies and time-varying nominal rigidities.” Macroeconomic Dynamics, 19: 1294–1308.Google Scholar
Tobin, J. (1958). “Liquidity preference as behavior towards risk.” The Review of Economic Studies, 25: 65–86.Google Scholar
Tobin, J. (1965). “The monetary interpretation of history.” American Economic Review, 55: 645–684.Google Scholar
Tobin, J. (1970). “Money and income: post hoc ergo propter hoc?Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84: 301–317.Google Scholar
Tobin, J. (1972). “Inflation and unemployment.” American Economic Review, 62: 1–18.Google Scholar
Tobin, J. (1980a). “Stabilization policy ten years after.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 11: 19–90.Google Scholar
Tobin, J. (1980b). “Tobin, James, stabilization policy ten years after.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1: 19–72.Google Scholar
Tobin, J., (1994). “Monetary policy,” in Feldstein, M. (ed.), American economic policy in the 1980s: 151–164. University of Chicago Press.
Triffin, R. (1960). Gold and the dollar crisis. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Tufte, E. (1978). Political control of the economy. Princeton University Press.
Van Houtven, L. (2002). “Governance of the IMF: decision making, institutional oversight, transparency, and accountability.” IMF Pamphlet Series, No. 35. Washington: IMF.
Vines, D. and Gilbert, C. L. (2003). The IMF and its critics: reform of global financial architecture. Cambridge University Press.
Visser, J. (2002). “Unions, wage bargaining and co-ordination in European labour markets,” in Pochet, P. (ed.), Wage policy in the Eurozone. Brussels: P.I.E. Peter Lang.
Walsh, C. E. (1995). “Optimal contracts for central bankers.” American Economic Review, 85: 150–167.Google Scholar
Walsh, C. E. (2003). Monetary theory and policy (edn). Cambridge CA: The MIT Press.
Williamson, S. (1987). “Financial intermediation, business failures, and real business cycles.” Journal of Political Economy, 95: 1196–1216.Google Scholar
Williamson, S. (2012). “Liquidity, monetary policy, and the financial crisis: a New Monetarist approach.” American Economic Review, 102: 2570–2605.Google Scholar
Williamson, J. (2000). “What should the bank think about the Washington Consensus?World Bank Research Observer, 15: 251–264.Google Scholar
Williamson, S. and Wright, R. (2010). “New Monetarist economics: methods.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 92: 265–302.Google Scholar
Williamson, S. and Wright, R. (2011). “New Monetarist economics: models,” in Friedman, B. and Woodford, M. (eds.), Handbook of monetary economics, Volume 3A: 25–96. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Wittman, D. (1977). “Platforms with policy preferences: a dynamic model.” Journal of Economic Theory, 14: 180–189.Google Scholar
Woodford, M. (1999). “Commentary: how should monetary policy be conducted in an era of price stability?” in Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City (ed.), New challenges for monetary policy. Kansas City: Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.
Woodford, M. (2003). Interest and prices: foundations of a theory of monetary policy. Princeton University Press.
Woodford, M. (2011a). “Optimal monetary stabilization policy,” in Friedman, B. M. and Woodford, M. (eds.), Handbook of monetary economics, Volume 3B: 723–828. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Woodford, M. (2011b). “Simple analytics of the government expenditure multiplier.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 3: 1–35.Google Scholar
Woodford, M. (2013). “Forward guidance by inflation-targeting central banks.” Penning–Och Valutapolitik, Sveriges Riksbank, 3 (Jubileumsnummer): 81–120.Google Scholar
World Bank (1993). The East-Asian miracle. Economic growth and public policy. Oxford University Press.
Wyplosz, C. (1999). “International financial instability,” in Kaul, I., Grunberg, I. and Stern, M. A. (eds.), Global public goods: international cooperation in the 21st century. Oxford University Press.
Yun, T. (2005). “Optimal monetary policy with relative price distortions.” American Economic Review, 95: 89–109.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Bibliography
  • Nicola Acocella, Università degli Studi di Roma 'La Sapienza', Italy, Giovanni Di Bartolomeo, Università degli Studi di Roma 'La Sapienza', Italy, Andrew Hughes Hallett, University of St Andrews, Scotland
  • Book: Macroeconomic Paradigms and Economic Policy
  • Online publication: 05 June 2016
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781316338841.016
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Bibliography
  • Nicola Acocella, Università degli Studi di Roma 'La Sapienza', Italy, Giovanni Di Bartolomeo, Università degli Studi di Roma 'La Sapienza', Italy, Andrew Hughes Hallett, University of St Andrews, Scotland
  • Book: Macroeconomic Paradigms and Economic Policy
  • Online publication: 05 June 2016
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781316338841.016
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Bibliography
  • Nicola Acocella, Università degli Studi di Roma 'La Sapienza', Italy, Giovanni Di Bartolomeo, Università degli Studi di Roma 'La Sapienza', Italy, Andrew Hughes Hallett, University of St Andrews, Scotland
  • Book: Macroeconomic Paradigms and Economic Policy
  • Online publication: 05 June 2016
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781316338841.016
Available formats
×