Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-skm99 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-26T22:51:43.765Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

14 - The dynamics of knowledge accumulation, regulation, and appropriability in the pharma-biotech sector: policy issues

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 September 2009

Luigi Orsenigo
Affiliation:
Department of Engineering, University of Brescia; Centro di Ricerca sui Processi di Innovazione e Internazionalizzazione, Bocconi University, Milan, Italy
Giovanni Dosi
Affiliation:
Laboratory of Economics and Management, Sant'Anna School of Advanced Studies, Pisa, Italy
Mariana Mazzucato
Affiliation:
Economic and Social Research Council Innogen Centre, Open University, Milton Keynes, United Kingdom
Mariana Mazzucato
Affiliation:
The Open University, Milton Keynes
Giovanni Dosi
Affiliation:
Sant'Anna School of Advanced Studies, Pisa
Get access

Summary

The contributions to this book enrich from a variety of angles our understanding of how the dynamics of knowledge affect the dynamics of firms and industry structures. In this concluding chapter, we discuss some associated policy implications regarding the future of the innovation process in the pharmaceutical industry and the institutional setup supporting it.

Institutions, industry organization, and innovation: a bird's-eye view

The policy debate in this arena has become extremely intense and often bitter in recent years. The issues at stake concern an area – health care – the importance of which for society is fundamental and rapidly increasing; indeed, they are becoming crucial elements in the very definition of notions such as welfare, justice, and democracy in the new century.

Many fundamental issues in the policy debate on the pharmaceutical industry, however, are certainly not new. Ever since its inception the market for drugs has been (almost) always and everywhere regulated, albeit for different reasons and in different ways. At the same time, the extent and the forms of the regulation have most often sparked discussion and conflict. For example, considerations linked to consumer protection led, throughout most of the twentieth century, to increasingly stringent requirements for the approval of new drugs, and implied larger and more costly clinical trials. The presence of significant information asymmetries in the market for drugs coupled with fundamental considerations of social and economic equity have often been used to justify the introduction of various forms of price regulation.

Type
Chapter
Information
Knowledge Accumulation and Industry Evolution
The Case of Pharma-Biotech
, pp. 402 - 431
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2006

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Angell, M. (2004), The Truth About the Drug Companies: How They Deceive Us and What to Do About It, Random House, New York.Google Scholar
Arora, A., Fosfuri, A., and Gambardella, A. (2001), Markets for Technology, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. (1962), “Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for inventions,” in Nelson, R. R. (ed.), The Rate and Direction of Innovative Activity: Economic and Social Factors, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, 609–26.Google Scholar
Comanor, W. S. (1986), “The political economy of the pharmaceutical industry,” Journal of Economic Literature, 24, 1178–217.Google ScholarPubMed
Dasgupta, P., and David, P. A. (1994), “Toward a new economics of science,” Research Policy, 23, 487–521.Google Scholar
David, P. A. (1990), “The dynamo and the computer: an historical perspective on the modern productivity paradox,” American Economic Review, 80 (2), 355–61.Google Scholar
David, P. A.(2004), “Understanding the emergence of open science institutions: functionalist economics in historical context,” Industrial and Corporate Change, 13 (3), 571–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dosi, G., P. Llerena, and M. Sylos Labini (2005), Science–Technology–Industry Links and the “European Paradox”: Some Notes on the Dynamics of Scientific and Technological Research in Europe, Working Paper no. 2005/02, Laboratory of Economics and Management, Sant'Anna School for Advanced Studies, Pisa.
Dosi, G., P. Llerena, and M. Sylos LabiniEconomist (2005), special report on “The drugs industry,” 19–25 March, 89.
Dosi, G., L. Orsenigo, and M. Sylos Labini (2005), “Technology and the economy,” in Smelser, N. J. and Swedberg, R. (eds.), The Handbook of Economic Sociology, 2nd edn., Princeton University Press and Russell Sage Foundation, Princeton, NJ, 678–702.Google Scholar
Freeman, C. (1995), “The national systems of innovation in historical perspective,” Cambridge Journal of Economics, 19, 5–24.Google Scholar
Galambos, L., and Sturchio, J. L. (1998), “Pharmaceutical firms and the transition to biotechnology: a study in strategic innovation,” Business History Review, 72, 250–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gambardella, A. (1995), Science and Innovation: The US Pharmaceutical Industry in the 1980s, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grabowski, H., and Vernon, J. (1983), The Regulation of Pharmaceuticals, American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, Washington, DC, and London.Google Scholar
Heller, M. A., and Eisenberg, R. S. (1998), “Can patents deter innovation? The anticommons in biomedical research,” Science, 280, 698–701.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Harris, G. (2002), “Why drug makers are failing in quest for new blockbusters,” Wall Street Journal, 18 March.Google Scholar
Henderson, R. M., L. Orsenigo, and G. Pisano (1999), “The pharmaceutical industry and the revolution in molecular biology: exploring the interactions between scientific, institutional, and organizational change,” in Mowery, D. C., and Nelson, R. R. (eds.), Sources of Industrial Leadership: Studies of Seven Industries, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 267–311.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kenney, M. (1986), Biotechnology: The Industry–University Complex, Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klepper, S., and Simons, K. (1997), “Technological extinctions of industrial firms: an inquiry into their nature and causes,” Industrial and Corporate Change, 6 (2), 379–460.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kortum, S., and Lerner, J. (1997), Stronger Protection or Technological Revolution: What is Behind the Recent Surge in Patenting?, Working Paper no. 6204, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kumar, N. (1998), “Technology generation and transfers in the world economy: recent trends and prospects for developing countries,” in Kumar, N. (ed.), Globalization, Foreign Direct Investment and Technology Transfer: Impacts on and the Prospects for Developing Countries, Routledge, London and New York, 11–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kumar, N.(2002), Intellectual Property Rights, Technology and Economic Development: Experiences of Asian Countries, paper prepared for the Commission of Intellectual Property Rights, London.Google Scholar
Lacetera, N., and Orsenigo, L. (2002), Political and Technological Regimes in the Evolution of the Pharmaceutical Industry in the USA and in Europe, 2nd draft of paper prepared for the “Conference on Evolutionary Economics,” Johns Hopkins University, Baltimore, 30–31 March 2001.Google Scholar
Lanjouw, J. O. (1998), The Introduction of Pharmaceutical Product Patents in India: Heartless Exploitation of the Poor and Suffering?, Working Paper no. 6366, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Mazzoleni, R., and Nelson, R. R. (1998), “The benefits and costs of strong patent protection: a contribution to the current debate,” Research Policy, 27, 273–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKelvey, M., L. Orsenigo, and F. Pammolli (2005), “Pharmaceuticals analysed through the lens of a sectoral innovation system,” in Malerba, F. (ed.), Sectoral Systems of Innovation, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 11–42.Google Scholar
Merges, R., and Nelson, R. R. (1990), “The complex economics of patent scope,” Columbia Law Review, 839, 890–4.Google Scholar
Mowery, D. C., Nelson, R. R., Sampat, B., and Ziedonis, A. (2001), “The growth of patenting and licensing by US universities: an assessment of the effects of the Bayh–Dole Act of 1980,” Research Policy, 30, 99–119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murmann, J. P. (2003), Knowledge and Competitive Advantage, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, R. R. (1959), “The simple economics of basic scientific research,” Journal of Political Economy, 67, 297–306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, R. R.(2004), “The market economy and the scientific commons,” Research Policy, 33, 455–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nightingale, P., and Martin, P. (2004), “The myth of the biotech revolution,” Trends in Biotechnology, 22 (11), 564–9.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Orsenigo, L., Pammolli, F., and Riccaboni, M. (2001), “Technological change and the dynamics of networks of collaborative relations: the case of the bio-pharmaceutical industry,” Research Policy, 30, 485–508.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pisano, G. (1996), The Development Factory, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Polanyi, M. (1967), The Tacit Dimension, Anchor Books, New York.Google Scholar
Sakakibara, M., and Branstetter, L. (2001), “Do stronger patents induce more innovation? Evidence from the 1988 Japanese patent law reforms,” RAND Journal of Economics, 32, 77–100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scherer, F. M. (2000), “The pharmaceutical industry,” in Culyer, A. J., and Newhouse, J. P. (eds.), Handbook of Health Economics, Vol. I, Elsevier, Amsterdam, 1297–336.Google Scholar
Schweitzer, S. O., and W. S. Comanor (2000), “Pharmaceutical prices and expenditures,” in Andersen, R. M.Rice, T. H. and Kominski, G. F. (eds.), Changing the U.S. Health Care System, 2nd ed., Jossey Bass Publishers, San Francisco, 100–24.Google Scholar
Thomas, L. G. (1994), “Implicit industrial policy: the triumph of Britain and the failure of France in global pharmaceuticals,” Industrial and Corporate Change, 3 (2), 451–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wong, J. F. (2005), “Is biotech in the midst of a fifty-year cycle?,” Genetic Engineering News, 25 (5), 60.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×