Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-22dnz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-27T00:24:00.805Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 June 2012

Sarah Lichtenstein
Affiliation:
Decision Research. Oregon
Paul Slovic
Affiliation:
Decision Research, Oregon
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2006

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aaker, D. A. (1991). Managing brand equity. New York: The Free Press. [10, 34]
Abdellaoui, M. (2000). Parameter-free elicitation of utility and probability weighting functions. Management Science, 46, 1497–1512. [32]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abelson, R. P., & Levi, A. (1985). Decision making and decision theory. In G. Lindzey & E. Aronson (Eds.), Handbook of social psychology (pp. 231–309). New York: Random House. [7, 19]
Ackerman, F., & Heinzerling, L. (2004). Priceless: On knowing the price of everything and the value of nothing. New York: The New Press. [36]
Ainslie, G. (1975). Specious reward: A behavioral theory of impulsiveness and impulse control. Psychological Bulletin, 82, 463–496. [20]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ainslie, G. (1992). Picoeconomics: The strategic interaction of successive motivational states within the person. New York: Cambridge University Press. [20]
Ainslie, G., & Haslam, N. (1992). Self-control. In Loewenstein, G. & Elster, J. (Eds.), Choice over time (pp. 177–209). New York: Russell Sage Foundation. [20]
Ajzen, I., & Peterson, G. L. (1988). Contingent value measurement: The price of everything and the value of nothing? In Peterson, G. L., Driver, B. L., & Gregory, R. (Eds.), Amenity resource valuation: Integrating economics with other disciplines (pp. 65–76). State College, PA: Venture. [33]
Alba, J. W., & Chattopadhyay, A. (1985). Effects of context and part-category cues on recall of competing brands. Journal of Marketing Research, 22, 340–349. [34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alba, J. W., & Hutchinson, J. W. (1987). Dimensions of expertise. Journal of Consumer Research, 13, 411–454. [15, 17]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alba, J. W., Hutchinson, J. W., & Lynch, J. G., Jr. (1991). Memory and decision making. In Robertson, T. S. & Kassarjian, H. H. (Eds.), Handbook of consumer behavior (pp. 1–49). Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. [10]
Alba, J. W., Lynch, J. G., Weitz, B., Janiszweki, C., Lutz, R. J., Sawyer, A. G., et al. (1997). Interactive home shopping: Consumer, retailer, and manufacturer incentives to participate in electronic marketplaces. Journal of Marketing, 61, 38–53. [17]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alba, J. W., & Marmorstein, H. (1987). The effects of frequency knowledge on consumer decision making. Journal of Consumer Research, 14, 14–26. [17]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alhakami, A. S., & Slovic, P. (1994). A psychological study of the inverse relationship between perceived risk and perceived benefit. Risk Analysis, 14, 1085–1096. [23, 24]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Allais, M. (1953). Le comportement de l'homme rationnel devant le risque: Critique des postulate et axioms de l'école americaine [The behavior of rational man in risk situations: A critique of the axioms and postulates of the American school]. Econometrica, 21, 503–546. [1, 2, 9, 19, 27]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allison, G. T. (1971). Essence of decision: Explaining the Cuban missile crisis. Boston: Little Brown. [22]
American Medical Association. (1993). Strategies for cadaveric organ procurement: Mandated choice and presumed consent. Chicago: American Medical Association. [37]
Ames, D. R., Flynn, F. J., & Weber, E. U. (2004). It's the thought that counts: On perceiving how helpers decide to lend a hand. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 30, 461–474. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amiel, Y., Cowell, F. A., Davidovitz, L., & Plovin, A. (2003). Preference reversals and the analysis of income distributions (No. DARP 66). Retrieved April 20, 2005, from London School of Economics, Suntory and Toyota International Centres for Economics and Related Disciplines Web site: http://sticerd.lse.ac.uk/publications/darp.asp. [1]
Amir, O., & Ariely, D. (in press). Decisions by rules: The case of unwillingness to pay for beneficial delays. Journal of Marketing Research. [28, 29]
Anderson, J. R. (1983). The architecture of cognition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. [21]
Anderson, J. R., & Reder, L. M. (1999). The fan effect: New results and new theories. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 128, 186–197. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, M. C., & Neely, J. H. (1996). Interference and inhibition in memory retrieval. In Bjork, E. L. & Bjork, R. A. (Eds.), Memory (2nd ed., pp. 237–313). San Diego, CA: Academic Press. [21]
Anderson, M. C., & Spellman, B. A. (1995). On the status of inhibitory mechanisms in cognition: Memory retrieval as a model case. Psychological Review, 102, 68–100. [21]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Anderson, N. (1996). A functional theory of cognition. Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [31]
Anderson, N. D., & Craik, F. I. M. (2000). Memory in the aging brain. In Tulving, E. & Craik, F. I. M. (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of memory (pp. 411–425). Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. [21]
Argyle, M. (1987). The psychology of happiness. London: Methuen. [28]
Ariely, D. (1998). Combining experiences over time: The effects of duration, intensity changes and on-line measurements on retrospective pain evaluations. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 11, 19–45. [9, 13, 29]3.0.CO;2-B>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ariely, D., & Carmon, Z. (2003). Summary assessment of experiences: The whole is different from the sum of its parts. In Loewenstein, G., Read, D., & Baumeister, R. F. (Eds.), Time and decision: Economic and psychological perspectives on intertemporal choice (pp. 323–349). New York: Russell Sage Foundation. [14]
Ariely, D., & Levav, J. (2000). Sequential choice in group settings: Taking the road less traveled and less enjoyed. Journal of Consumer Research, 27, 279–290. [29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ariely, D., & Loewenstein, G. (2000). The importance of duration in ratings of and choices between sequences of outcomes. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 129, 508–523. [13]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ariely, D., Loewenstein, G., & Prelec, D. (2002). Determinants of anchoring effects (Working paper). [13]
Ariely, D., Loewenstein, G., & Prelec, D. (2003). Coherent arbitrariness: Stable demand curves without stable preferences. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, 73–105. [1, 13, 14, 21, 35]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ariely, D., Loewenstein, G., & Prelec, D. (2006). Tom Sawyer and the myth of fundamental value. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 60, 1–10. [1, 14]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ariely, D., & Wallsten, T. (1995). Seeking subjective dominance in multidimensional space: An explanation of the asymmetric dominance effect. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 63, 223–232. [18]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ariely, D., & Zauberman, G. (2000). On the making of an experience: The effects of breaking and combining experiences on their overall evaluation. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 13, 219–232. [13]3.0.CO;2-P>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arkes, H. R. (2001). The attribution of cues, implicit memory, and human judgment. Columbus, OH: Department of Psychology, Ohio State University. [21]
Arkes, H. R., & Ayton, P. (1999). The sunk cost and Concorde effects: Are humans less rational than lower animals?Psychological Bulletin, 125, 591–600. [29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arkes, H. R., & Blumer, C. (1985). The psychology of sunk cost. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 35, 124–140. [29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, K. J. (1982). Risk perception in psychology and economics. Economic Inquiry, 20, 1–9. [6, 27, 31, 34, 36]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, K. J., Solow, R., Portney, P. R., Leamer, E. E., Radner, R., & Schuman, H. (1993). Report of the NOAA Panel on Contingent Valuation.Washington, DC: National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration. [31, 33, 34]Google Scholar
Axelrod, P. (1976). Structure of decision: The cognitive maps of political elites. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University. [18]
Ayres, I., & Gertner, R. (1989). Filling gaps in incomplete contracts: An economic theory of default rules. Yale Law Journal, 99, 87–130. [38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baddeley, A. D. (1986). Working memory. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. [20]
Bandura, A. (1997). Self-efficacy: The exercise of control. New York: W. H. Freeman. [35]
Barber, B., Heath, C., & Odean, T. (2002). Good rationales sell: Reason-based choice among group and individual investors in the stock market. (Working paper). Stanford, CA: Stanford University. [29]
Bar-Gad, I., & Bergman, H. (2001). Stepping out of the box: Information processing in the neural networks of the basal ganglia. Current Opinion in Neurobiology, 11, 689–695. [11]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bargh, J. A., Chen, M., & Burrows, L. (1996). Automaticity of social behavior: Direct effects of trait construct and stereotype activation on action. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 71, 230–244. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, J. (1988). Thinking and deciding. New York: Cambridge University Press. [9, 34]
Baron, J. (1997a). Biases in the quantitative measurement of values for public decisions. Psychological Bulletin, 122, 72–88. [34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, J. (1997b). Confusion of relative and absolute risk in valuation. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 14, 301–309. [9, 23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, J. (2000). Thinking and deciding (3rd ed.). New York: Cambridge University Press. [12]
Baron, J., & Greene, J. (1996). Determinants of insensitivity to quantity in valuation of public goods: Contribution, warm glow, budget constraints, availability, and prominence. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Applied, 2, 107–125. [31, 32, 34]Google Scholar
Baron, J., & Ritov, I. (1994). Reference points and omission bias. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 59, 475–498. [37]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, J., & Spranca, M. (1997). Protected values. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 70, 1–16. [34]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Baron, R. M., & Kenny, D. A. (1986). The moderator-mediator variable distinction in social-psychological research: Conceptual, strategic, and statistical considerations. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 51, 1173–1182. [15]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Barsalou, L. W. (1992). Cognitive psychology: An overview for cognitive scientists. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [31]
Bartels, L. M. (1998, September). Democracy with attitudes. Paper presented at the annual meeting of American Political Science Association, Boston. [31]
Bartlett, F. C. (1932). A study in experimental and social psychology. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. [1]
Bateman, I. A., Carson, R., Day, R., Hanemann, M., Hanley, N., Hett, T., et al. (2002). Economic valuation with stated preference techniques: A manual.Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bateman, I. A., Dent, S., Peters, E., Starmer, C., & Slovic, P. (2006). The affect heuristic and the attractiveness of simple gambles. (Report No. 06-06). Eugene, OR: Decision Research. [1, 23]
Bateman, I. A., & Willis, K. G. (1999). Valuing environmental preferences.New York: Oxford University Press. [38]Google Scholar
Bazerman, M. H., Loewenstein, G., & White, S. B. (1992). Reversals of preference in allocation decisions: Judging an alternative versus choosing among alternatives. Administrative Science Quarterly, 37, 220–240. [9, 10, 28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bazerman, M. H., Moore, D. A., Tenbrunsel, A. E., Wade-Benzoni, K. A., & Blount, S. (1999). Explaining how preferences change across joint versus separate evaluation. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 39, 41–58. [29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bazerman, M. H., & Neale, M. A. (1992). Negotiating rationally.New York: The Free Press. [34]Google Scholar
Bazerman, M. H., Schroth, H. A., Shah, P. P., Diekmann, K. A., & Tenbrunsel, A. E. (1994). The inconsistent role of comparison others and procedural justice in reactions to hypothetical job descriptions: Implications for job acceptance procedures. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 60, 326–352. [9]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bazerman, M. H., Tenbrunsel, A. E., & Wade-Benzoni, K. A. (1998). Negotiating with yourself and losing: Understanding and managing competing internal preferences. Academy of Management Review, 23, 225–241. [9]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bazerman, M. H., White, S. B., & Loewenstein, G. (1995). Perceptions of fairness in interpersonal and individual choice situations. Current Directions in Psychological Science, 4, 39–43. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beach, L. R. (1990). Image theory: Decision making in personal and organizational contexts.Chichester, UK: Wiley. [17, 18, 19]Google Scholar
Beach, L. R., & Lipshitz, R. (1993). Why classical decision theory is an appropriate standard for evaluating and aiding most human decision making. In Klein, G. A., Orasanu, J., Calderwood, R., & Zsambok, C. E. (Eds.), Decision making in action: Models and methods (pp. 21–35). Norwood, NJ: Ables. [18]
Beach, L. R., & Mitchell, T. R. (1978). A contingency model for the selection of decision strategies. Academy of Management Review, 3, 439–449. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beach, L. R., & Mitchell, T. R. (1987). Image theory: Principles, goals, and plans in decision making. Acta Psychologica, 66, 201–308. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beattie, J., & Baron, J. (1991). Investigating the effect of stimulus range on attribute weight. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance, 17, 571–585. [9]Google ScholarPubMed
Beattie, J., Baron, J., Hershey, J. C., & Spranca, M. D. (1994). Psychological determinants of decision attitude. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 7, 129–144. [16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beattie, J., Covey, J., Dolan, P., Hopkins, L., Jones-Lee, M., Loomes, G., et al. (1998). On the contingent valuation of safety and the safety of contingent valuation. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 17, 5–25. [35]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bechara, A., Damasio, A. R., Damasio, H., & Anderson, S. W. (1994). Insensitivity to future consequences following damage to human prefrontal cortex. Cognition, 50, 7–15. [24]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Becker, G. M., DeGroot, D. H., & Marschak, J. (1963). An experimental study of some stochastic models for wagers. Behavioral Science, 8, 41–55. [13]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. M., DeGroot, M. H., & Marschak, J. (1964). Measuring utility by a single-response sequential method. Behavioral Science, 9, 226–232. [1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 8]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Becker, G. S. (1962). Irrational behavior and economic theory. Journal of Political Economy, 70, 1–13. [13]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1968). Crime and punishment: An economic approach. Journal of Political Economy, 76, 169–217. [5]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1973). A theory of marriage: Part I. Journal of Political Economy, 81, 813–846. [5]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1974). A theory of marriage: Part II. Journal of Political Economy, 82, 511–526. [5]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beckmann, J., & Kuhl, J. (1984). Altering information to gain action control: Functional aspects of human information processing in decision making. Journal of Research in Personality, 18, 224–237. [18]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belk, R. W. (1988). Possessions and the extended self. Journal of Consumer Research, 15, 139–168. [17]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bell, B. E., & Loftus, E. F. (1989). Trivial persuasion in the courtroom: The power of (a few) minor details. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 56, 669–679. [21]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bell, D. E. (1982). Regret in decision making under uncertainty. Operations Research, 30, 961–981. [36]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bellah, R., Madsen, R., Sullivan, W., Swindler, A., & Tipton, S. (1985). Habits of the heart.Los Angeles: University of California Press. [16]Google Scholar
Bellman, S., Johnson, E. J., & Lohse, G. L. (2001). To opt-in or opt-out? It depends on the question. Communications of the ACM, 44(2), 25–27. [37]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bellman, S., Lohse, G. L., & Johnson, E. J. (1999). Predictors of online buying behavior. Communications of the ACM, 42(12), 32–38. [15]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bem, D. J. (1972). Self-perception theory. In Berkowitz, L. (Ed.), Advances in experimental social psychology (Vol. 6, pp. 2–62). New York: Academic Press. [22]
Benartzi, S., & Thaler, R. H. (1995). Myopic loss aversion and the equity premium puzzle. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 73–92. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benartzi, S., & Thaler, R. H. (1999). Risk aversion or myopia? Choices in repeated gambles and retirement investments. Management Science, 45, 364–381. [38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benartzi, S., & Thaler, R. H. (2002). How much is investor autonomy worth?Journal of Finance, 57, 1593–1616. [38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benson, L. (1993). Studies in human decision making: On the effects of experimental instructions, framing, and time constraints. Unpublished doctoral dissertation, Lund University, Lund, Sweden. [19]
Benson, L., & Svenson, O. (1992). Post-decision consolidation following the debriefing of subjects about experimental manipulations affecting their prior decisions. Lund University, Psychological Research Bulletin, 32 (3). [19]Google Scholar
Bentham, J. (1996). An introduction to the principles of morals and legislation (J. H. Burns & H. L. A. Hart, Eds.). New York: Oxford University Press (Original work published in 1823). [27]Google Scholar
Benthin, A., Slovic, P., Moran, P., Severson, H., Mertz, C. K., & Gerrard, M. (1995). Adolescent health-threatening and health-enhancing behaviors: A study of word association and imagery. Journal of Adolescent Health, 17, 143–152. [23]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Benthorn, L. (1994). On post-decision processes. Unpublished doctoral dissertation, Lund University, Lund, Sweden. [19]
Berg, J. E., Dickhaut, J. W., & O'Brien, J. R. (1985). Preference reversal and arbitrage. In Smith, V. L. (Ed.), Research in experimental economics (pp. 31–72). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press. [8]
Berg, J. E., Dickhaut, J. W., & Rietz, T. A. (2003). Preference reversals and induced risk preferences: Evidence for noisy maximization. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 27, 139–170. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berman, L. (1982). Planning a tragedy.New York: Norton. [22]Google Scholar
Bernoulli, D. (1954). Exposition of a new theory on the measurement of risk (L. Sommer, Trans.). Econometrica, 22, 23–36 (Reprinted from Commentarii Academiae Scientiarum Imperialis Petropolitanae, 1738, 5, 175–192). [2]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bettman, J. R. (1979). An information processing theory of consumer choice.Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley. [1, 17]Google Scholar
Bettman, J. R., Johnson, E. J., & Payne, J. W. (1991). Consumer decision making. In Robertson, T. S. & Kassarjian, H. H. (Eds.), Handbook of consumer behavior (pp. 50–84). Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. [19]
Bettman, J. R., & Kakkar, P. (1977). Effects of information presentation format on consumer information acquisition strategies. Journal of Consumer Research, 3, 233–240. [7]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bettman, J. R., Luce, M. F., & Payne, J. W. (1998). Constructive consumer choice processes. Journal of Consumer Research, 25, 187–217. [1, 17, 29, 34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bettman, J. R., & Park, C. W. (1980). Effects of prior knowledge and experience and phase of the choice process on consumer decision processes: A protocol analysis. Journal of Consumer Research, 7, 234–248. [17]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bettman, J. R., Payne, J. W., & Staelin, R. (1986). Cognitive considerations in designing effective labels for presenting risk information. Journal of Marketing and Public Policy, 5, 1–28. [34]Google Scholar
Bettman, J. R., & Sujan, M. (1987). Effects of framing on evaluation of comparable and noncomparable alternatives by expert and novice consumers. Journal of Consumer Research, 14, 141–154. [15, 17]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bettman, J. R., & Zins, M. A. (1979). Information format and choice task effects in decision making. Journal of Consumer Research, 6, 141–153. [7]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Betts, R., & Gelb, L. (1979). The irony of Vietnam: The system worked.Washington, DC: Brookings Institution. [22]Google Scholar
Bewley, T. F. (1998). Why not cut pay?European Economic Review, 62, 459–490. [13]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beyth-Marom, R., & Fischhoff, B. (1997). Adolescent decisions about risk. In Schulenberg, J., Maggs, J., & Hurnelmans, K. (Eds.), Health risks and developmental transactions during adolescence (pp. 110–135). New York: Cambridge University Press. [35]
Biehal, G., & Chakravarti, D. (1983). Information accessibility as a moderator of consumer choice. Journal of Consumer Research, 10, 1–14. [10]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Biehal, G., & Chakravarti, D. (1986). Consumers' use of memory and external information on choice: Macro and micro perspectives. Journal of Consumer Research, 12, 382–405. [15]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Biel, A., & Montgomery, H. (1986). Scenarios in energy planning. In Brehmer, B., Jungermann, H., Lourens, P., & Sevon, G. (Eds.), New directions in research on decision making (pp. 205–218). Amsterdam: North-Holland. [18]
Bigelow, J. (Ed.). (1887). The complete works of Benjamin Franklin (Vol. 4). New York: Putnam. [22]Google Scholar
Billig, M. (1987). Arguing and thinking: A rhetorical approach to social psychology.New York: Cambridge University Press. [22]Google Scholar
Billig, M. (1991). Ideology and opinions. London: Sage. [18]
Billings, R. S., & Scherer, L. L. (1988). The effect of response mode and importance on decision-making strategies: Judgment versus choice. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 41, 1–19. [10]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Birnbaum, M. H. (1982). Controversies in psychological measurement. In Wegener, B. (Ed.), Social attitudes and psychophysical measurement (pp. 401–485). Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [1]
Birnbaum, M. H. (1992). Issues in utility measurement. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 52, 319–330. [9]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Birnbaum, M. H., & Mellers, B. A. (1979). Stimulus recognition may mediate exposure effects. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 37, 1090–1096. [25]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Birnbaum, M. H., & Stegner, S. E. (1979). Source credibility in social judgment: Bias, expertise, and the judge's point of view. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 37, 48–74. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Birnbaum, M. H., & Sutton, S. E. (1992). Scale convergence and utility measurement. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 52, 183–215. [1, 11]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bishop, R. C. (1986). Resource valuation under uncertainty: Theoretical principles for empirical research. In Smith, V. K. (Ed.), Advances in applied micro-economics (Vol. 4, pp. 133–152). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press. [33]
Bishop, R. C., & Heberlein, T. A. (1979). Measuring values of extramarket goods: Are indirect measures biased?American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 61, 926–930. [33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bizer, G. Y., & Krosnick, J. A. (2001). Exploring the structure of strength-related attitude features: The relation between attitude importance and attitude accessibility. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 81, 566–586. [15]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Blattberg, R. C., & Neslin, S. A. (1990). Sales promotion: Concepts, methods, and strategies.Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. [22]Google Scholar
Bleichrodt, H., & Pinto, J. (2000). A parameter-free elicitation of the probability weighting function in medical decision analysis. Management Science, 46, 1485–1497. [32]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blom Kemdal, A., & Montgomery, H. (1997). Perspectives and emotions in personal decision making. In Ranyard, R., Crozier, W. R., & Svenson, O. (Eds.), Decision making: Cognitive models and explanations (pp. 72–89). London: Routledge. [18]
Blount, S., & Bazerman, M. H. (1996). The inconsistent evaluation of absolute versus comparative payoffs in labor supply and bargaining. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 30, 227–240. [9]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bockenholt, U., Albert, D., Aschenbrenner, M., & Schmalhofer, F. (1991). The effects of attractiveness, dominance, and attribute differences on information acquisition in multiattribute binary choice. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 49, 258–281. [18]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bohm, P. (1994). Behavior under uncertainty without preference reversals: A field experiment. Empirical Economics, 19, 185–200. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bohm, P., & Lind, H. (1993). Preference reversal, real-world lotteries, and lottery-interested subjects. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 22, 327–348. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bornstein, R. F. (1989). Exposure and affect: Overview and meta-analysis of research, 1968–1987. Psychological Bulletin, 106, 265–289. [23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bostic, R., Herrnstein, R. J., & Luce, R. D. (1990). The effect on the preference-reversal phenomenon of using choice indifferences. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 13, 193–212. [1, 8]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bovie, P. (Ed.). (1992). Terence: The comedies.Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. [16]Google Scholar
Bower, G. (1981). Mood and memory. American Psychologist, 36, 129–148. [24]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Boyle, K., Desvousges, W., Johnson, F., Dunford, R., & Hudson, S. (1994). An investigation of part-whole biases in contingent valuation studies. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 27, 64–83. [32]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bradley, M. M., & Lang, P. J. (1994). Measuring emotion: The Self-Assessment Manikin and the semantic differential. Journal of Behavior Therapy and Experimental Psychiatry, 25, 49–59. [24]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Braga, J., & Starmer, C. (2004). Does market experience eliminate preference reversal? Unpublished manuscript. [1]
Brandstätter, E., Kühberger, A., & Schneider, F. (2002). A cognitive-emotional account of the shape of the probability weighting function. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 15, 79–100. [32]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brehm, J. W. (1956). Post-decision changes in desirability of alternatives. Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology, 52, 384–389. [19, 26]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brehm, J. W. (1966). A theory of psychological reactance.New York: Academic Press. [16]Google Scholar
Brehmer, B. (1990). Strategies in real-time dynamic decision making. In Hogarth, R. (Ed.), Insights in decision making: A tribute to Hillel J. Einhorn (pp. 262–279). Chicago: University of Chicago Press. [18]
Brickman, P., Coates, D., & Janoff-Bulman, R. J. (1978). Lottery winners and accident victims: Is happiness relative?Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 36, 917–927. [27, 28, 30]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bromley, D. (Ed.). (1986). National resource economics: Policy problems and contemporary analysis.Boston: Kluwer/Nijhoff Publishing. [33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brookshire, D. S., & Coursey, D. (1987). Measuring the value of a public good: An empirical comparison of elicitation procedures. American Economic Review, 77(4), 554–566. [33]Google Scholar
Brookshire, D. S., Thayer, M. A., Schulze, W. D., & D'Arge, R. C. (1982). Valuing public goods: A comparison of survey and hedonic approaches. American Economic Review, 72(1), 165–177. [33]Google Scholar
Brown & Williamson Tobacco Company. (1999). Kool Natural Lights [Advertisement]. [23]
Brown, C., & Feinberg, F. (2002). How does choice affect evaluations?Advances in Consumer Research, 29, 331–332. [28]Google Scholar
Brown, T. C. (1984). The concept of value in resource allocation. Land Economics, 60, 231–246. [33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, T. C., & Slovic, P. (1988). Effects of context on economic measures of value. In Peterson, G. L., Driver, B. L., & Gregory, R. (Eds.), Integrating economic and psychological knowledge in valuations of public amenity resources (pp. 23–30). State College, PA: Venture. [33]
Brownstein, A. (2003). Biased pre-decision processing. Psychological Bulletin, 129, 545–568. [12, 19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brucks, M. (1985). The effects of product class knowledge on information search behavior. Journal of Consumer Research, 11, 1–16. [15]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brucks, M. (1988). Search monitor: An approach for computer-controlled experiments involving consumer information search. Journal of Consumer Research, 15, 117–121. [15]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bruner, J. S. (1957). On perceptual readiness. Psychological Review, 64, 123–152. [15]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bruner, J. S., Goodnow, J. J., & Austin, G. A. (1956). A study of thinking.New York: Wiley. [2]Google Scholar
Busemeyer, J. R., & Diederich, A. (2002). Survey of decision field theory. Mathematical Social Sciences, 43, 345–370. [11]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Busemeyer, J. R., & Goldstein, D. G. (1992). Linking together different measures of preference: A dynamic model of matching derived from decision field theory. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 52, 370–396. [11]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Busemeyer, J. R., Hastie, R., & Medin, D. L. (1995). Decision making from a cognitive perspective.San Diego, CA: Academic. [23]Google Scholar
Busemeyer, J. R., & Townsend, J. T. (1992). Fundamental derivations for decision field theory. Mathematical Social Sciences, 23, 255–282. [11]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Busemeyer, J. R., & Townsend, J. T. (1993). Decision field theory: A dynamic cognition approach to decision making. Psychological Review, 100, 432–459. [11, 12, 19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Busemeyer, J. R., Townsend, J. T., & Stout, J. C. (2002). Motivational underpinnings of utility in decision making: Decision Field Theory analysis of deprivation and satiation. In Moore, S. C. & Oaksford, M. (Eds.), Advances in consciousness research: Vol. 44. Emotional cognition: From brain to behaviour (pp. 197–219). Amsterdam: John Benjamins. [11]
Cabanac, M. (1992). Pleasure: The common currency. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 155, 173–200. [24]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Calabresi, G., & Melamed, A. D. (1972). Property rules, liability rules, and inalienability: One view of the cathedral. Harvard Law Review, 85, 1089–1128. [38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caldwell, C. (2004, March 1). Select all: Can we have too many choices?The New Yorker, pp. 91–93. [1]Google Scholar
Calle, E. E., Thun, M. J., Petrelli, J. M., Rodriguez, C., & Heath, C. W., Jr. (1999). Body-mass index and mortality in a prospective cohort of U.S. adults. New England Journal of Medicine, 341, 1097–1105. [38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C. F. (2000). Prospect theory in the wild: Evidence from the field. In Kahneman, D. & Tversky, A. (Eds.), Choices, values, and frames (pp. 288–300). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. [38]
Camerer, C. F., Babcock, L., Loewenstein, G., & Thaler, R. H. (1997). Labor supply of New York City cab drivers: One day at a time. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 407–441. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C. F., & Ho, T. (1994). Violations of the betweenness axiom and nonlinearity in probabilities. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 8, 167–196. [32]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C. F., & Hogarth, R. M. (1999). The effects of financial incentives in experiments: A review and capital-labor-production framework. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 19, 1–3, 7–42. [38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C. F., Issacharoff, S., Loewenstein, G., O'Donoghue, T., & Rabin, M. (2003). Regulation for conservatives: Behavioral economics and the case for “asymmetric paternalism.”University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 151, 2111–2154. [37]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C. F., Loewenstein, G., & Weber, M. (1989). The curse of knowledge in economic settings: An experimental analysis. Journal of Political Economy, 117, 1232–1254. [13]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caplan, A. L. (1994). Current ethical issues in organ procurement and transplantation. Journal of the American Medical Association, 272, 1708–1709. [37]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Card, S. K., Moran, T. P., & Newell, A. (1983). The psychology of human computer interaction.Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [7]Google Scholar
Carlson, K. A., & Klein Pearo, L. (2004). Limiting predecisional distortion by prior valuation of attribute components. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 94, 48–59. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlson, K. A., & Russo, J. E. (2001). Biased interpretation of evidence by mock jurors. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Applied, 7, 91–103. [21]Google ScholarPubMed
Carroll, J. D. (1972). Individual differences and multidimensional scaling. In Shepard, R. N., Romney, A. K., & Neriove, S. (Eds.), Multidimensional scaling: Theory and applications in the behavioral sciences: Vol. 1. Theory (pp. 105–155). New York: Seminar Press. [6]
Carson, R. T., Hanemann, M., Kopp, R., Krosnick, J., Mitchell, R., Presser, S., et al. (1994). Prospective interim lost use value due to DDT and PCB contamination in the Southern California Bight.La Jolla, CA: Natural Resource Damage Assessment. [31]Google Scholar
Carson, R. T., & Mitchell, R. C. (1993). The issue of scope in contingent valuation studies. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 75, 1263–1267. [31, 32]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carson, R. T., & Mitchell, R. C. (1995). Sequencing and nesting in contingent valuation surveys. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 28, 155–173. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Casey, J. T. (1991). Reversal of the preference reversal phenomenon. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 48, 224–251. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Centers for Disease Control and Prevention. (2003). 1991–2001 prevalence of obesity among U.S. adults, by characteristics. Retrieved May 6, 2004, from http://www.cdc.gov/nccdphp/dnpa/obesity/trend/prev_char.htm. [38]
Chaiken, S., & Trope, Y. (1999). Dual-process theories in social psychology.New York: Guilford Press. [1, 32]Google Scholar
Chapman, G. B., & Bornstein, B. (1996). The more you ask the more you get: Anchoring in personal injury verdicts. Applied Cognitive Psychology, 10, 519–540. [31]3.0.CO;2-5>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chapman, G. B., & Johnson, E. J. (1994). The limits of anchoring. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 7, 223–242. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chapman, G. B., & Johnson, E. J. (1999). Anchoring, activation, and the construction of values. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 79, 115–153. [13, 14, 15, 21]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Chapman, G. B., & Johnson, E. J. (2002). Incorporating the irrelevant: Anchors in judgments of belief and value. In Gilovich, T., Griffin, D., & Kahneman, D. (Eds.), Intuitive judgment: Heuristics and biases (pp. 120–138). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. [21]
Chen, M., & Bargh, J. A. (1999). Consequences of automatic evaluation: Immediate behavioral predispositions to approach or avoid the stimulus. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 25, 215–224. [24]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cherry, T. L., Crocker, T. D., & Shogren, J. F. (2003). Rationality spillovers. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 45, 63–84. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chitturi, R., Raghunathan, R., & Mahajan, V. (2003). Form vs. function: Emotional and behavioral consequences of trading off hedonic vs. utilitarian attributes (Working paper).University of Texas, Austin. [29]Google Scholar
Choi, J. J., Laibson, D., Madrian, B. C., & Metrick, A. (2002). Defined contribution pensions: Plan rules, participant decisions, and the path of least resistance. In Poterba, J. M. (Ed.), Tax policy and the economy (Vol. 16, pp. 67–113). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. [38]
Choi, J. J., Laibson, D., Madrian, B. C., & Metrick, A. (2004). For better or for worse: Default effects and 401(k) savings behavior. In Wise, D. (Ed.), Perspectives in the economics of aging (pp. 81–121). University of Chicago. [37]
Christensen-Szalanski, J. J. J. (1978). Problem-solving strategies: A selection mechanism, some implications, and some data. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 22, 307–323. [16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christensen-Szalanski, J. J. J. (1980). A further examination of the selection of problem-solving strategies: The effects of deadlines and analytic aptitudes. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 25, 107–122. [16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christensen-Szalanski, J. J. J. (1984). Discount functions and the measurement of patients' values: Women's values during childbirth. Medical Decision Making, 4, 47–58. [27]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Chu, Y. P., & Chu, R. L. (1990). The subsidence of preference reversals in simplified and marketlike experimental settings: A note. American Economic Review, 80(4), 902–911. [1]Google Scholar
Cicchetti, C., & Dubin, J. (1994). A microeconomic analysis of risk aversion and the decision to self-insure. Journal of Political Economy, 102, 169–186. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clay, M., & Block, W. (2002). A free market for human organs. Journal of Social, Political, and Economic Studies, 27, 227–236. [37]Google Scholar
Clemen, R. T. (1996). Making hard decisions: An introduction to decision analysis.Belmont, CA: Duxbury. [34]Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44. [37]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, M. S. (1993). The naturalistic basis of decision biases. In Klein, G. A., Orasanu, J., Calderwood, R., & Zsambok, C. E. (Eds.), Decision making in action: Models and methods (pp. 51–99). Norwood, NJ: Ables. [18]
Cohen, M. S., Freeman, J. P., & Wolf, S. (1996). Metarecognition in time-stressed decision making: Recognizing, critiquing, and correcting. Human Factors, 38, 206–219. [18]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collins, A. M., & Loftus, E. F. (1975). A spreading activation theory of semantic processing. Psychological Review, 82, 407–428. [15, 21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collins, B. E., & Hoyt, M. G. (1972). Personal responsibility for consequences: An integration and extension of the “forced compliance” literature. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 8, 558–593. [16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Connolly, T., & Zeelenberg, M. (2002). Regret in decision making. Current Directions in Psychological Science, 11, 212–215. [24]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Constans, J. I., & Mathews, A. M. (1993). Mood and the subjective risk of future events. Cognition & Emotion, 7, 545–560. [24]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coombs, C. H. (1958). On the use of inconsistency of preference in psychological measurement. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 55, 1–7. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coombs, C. H., Bezembinder, T. G., & Goode, F. M. (1967). Testing expectation theories of decision making without measuring utility or subjective probability. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 4, 72–103. [2, 3, 6]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coombs, C. H., & Pruitt, D. G. (1960). Components of risk in decision making: Probability and variance preferences. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 60, 265–277. [1, 2]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, J., & Fazio, R. H. (1984). A new look at dissonance theory. In Berkowitz, L. (Ed.), Advances in experimental social psychology (Vol. 17, pp. 229–266). Orlando, FL: Academic Press. [16]
Cordova, D. I., & Lepper, M. R. (1996). Intrinsic motivation and the process of learning: Beneficial effects of contextualization, personalization, and choice. Journal of Educational Psychology, 88, 715–730. [16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cortese, A. E., & Stepanek, M. (1998, May 4). Goodbye to fixed pricing? How electronic commerce could create the most efficient market of them all. Business Week, pp. 70–71. [15]Google Scholar
Coupey, E. (1994). Restructuring: Constructive processing of information displays in consumer choice. Journal of Consumer Research, 21, 83–99. [17, 19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coupey, E., Irwin, J. R., & Payne, J. W. (1998). Product category familiarity and preference construction. Journal of Consumer Research, 24, 459–467. [9, 15]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coursey, D. L., Hovis, J. J., & Schulze, W. D. (1987). The disparity between willingness to accept and willingness to pay measures of value. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102, 679–690. [9]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, J. C., & Epstein, S. (1989). Preference reversals without the independence axiom. American Economic Review, 79(3), 408–426. [1, 8]Google Scholar
Cox, J. C., & Grether, D. M. (1996). The preference reversal phenomenon: Response mode, markets, and incentives. Economic Theory, 7, 381–405. [1, 13]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cronbach, L. J., & Meehl, P. M. (1955). Construct validity in psychological tests. Psychological Bulletin, 52, 281–302. [33]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Cropper, M. L., Aydede, S. K., & Portney, P. R. (1994). Preferences for life-saving programs: How the public discounts time and age. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 8, 243–265. [38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cubitt, R. P., Munro, A., & Starmer, C. (2004). Testing explanations of preference reversal. The Economic Journal, 114, 709–726. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cummings, R. G., Brookshire, D. S., & Schulze, W. D. (1986). Valuing environmental goods: Assessment of the contingent valuation method.Totowa, NJ: Rowman and Allanheld. [1, 33]Google Scholar
Cummings, R. G., Harrison, G. W., & Rutstrom, E. E. (1995). Homegrown values and hypothetical surveys: Is the dichotomous choice approach incentive-compatible?American Economic Review, 85(1), 260–266. [31]Google Scholar
Dahlstrand, U., & Montgomery, H. (1984). Information search and evaluative processes in decision making: A computer-based process tracing study. Acta Psychologica, 56, 113–123. [18]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dale, H. C. A. (1959). A priori probabilities in gambling. Nature, 183, 842–843. [2]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Damasio, A. R. (1994). Descartes' error: Emotion, reason, and the human brain.New York: Avon. [1, 23, 24]Google Scholar
Damasio, A. R., Tranel, D., & Damasio, H. (1990). Individuals with sociopathic behavior caused by frontal damage fail to respond autonomically to social stimuli. Behavioural Brain Research, 41, 81–94. [23]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Darley, J. M., & Berscheid, E. (1967). Increased liking caused by the anticipation of interpersonal contact. Human Relations, 10, 29–40. [30]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davidson, A. R., Yantis, S., Norwood, M., & Montano, D. E. (1985). Amount of information about the attitude object and attitude-behavior consistency. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 49, 1184–1198. [26]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Davidson, D., & Marschak, J. (1959). Experimental tests of a stochastic decision theory. In Churchman, C. W. & Ratoosh, P. (Eds.), Measurement: Definitions and theories (pp. 233–269). New York: Wiley. [2]
Dawes, R. M. (1977). Predictive models as a guide to preference. IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man and Cybernetics, SMC-7, 355–358. [33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dawes, R. M. (1979). The robust beauty of improper linear models in decision making. American Psychologist, 34, 571–582. [17]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dawes, R. M. (1998). Behavioral decision making, judgment, and inference. In Gilbert, D., Fiske, S., & Lindzey, G. (Eds.), Handbook of social psychology (pp. 589–597). Boston: McGraw-Hill. [19]
Bondt, W. F. M., & Thaler, R. H. (1990). Do security analysts overreact?American Economic Review, 80(2), 52–57. [38]Google Scholar
Charms, R. (1968). Personal causation.New York: Academic Press. [16]Google Scholar
Tocqueville, A. (1969). Democracy in America.New York: Harper & Row (Original work published 1830). [16]Google Scholar
Deci, E. L. (1975). Intrinsic motivation.New York: Plenum Press. [16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deci, E. L. (1981). The psychology of self-determination.Lexington, MA: Heath. [16]Google Scholar
Deci, E. L., & Ryan, R. M. (1985). Intrinsic motivation and self-determination in human behavior.New York: Plenum Press. [16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeKay, M., & McClelland, G. (1996). Probability and utility components of endangered species preservation programs. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Applied, 2, 60–83. [31, 34]Google Scholar
Delucchi, K. L. (1983). The use and misuse of chi-square: Lewis and Burke revisited. Psychological Bulletin, 94, 166–176. [16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeMaio, T. J., & Rothgeb, J. M. (1996). Cognitive interviewing techniques: In the lab and in the field. In Schwarz, N. & Sudman, S. (Eds.), Answering questions: Methodology for determining cognitive and communication processes in survey research (pp. 177–195). San Francisco: Jossey-Bass. [34]
Dember, W. N., Galinsky, T. L., & Warm, J. S. (1992). The role of choice in vigilance performance. Bulletin of the Psychonomic Society, 30, 201–204. [16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dembo, T. (1931). Der Ärger als dynamisches Problem [Anger as a dynamic problem]. Psychologische Forschung, 15, 1–144. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Denes-Raj, V., & Epstein, S. (1994). Conflict between intuitive and rational processing: When people behave against their better judgment. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 66, 819–829. [23]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Desvousges, W. H., Johnson, F. R., Dunford, R. W., Boyle, K. J., Hudson, S. P., & Wilson, K. N. (1992). Measuring nonuse damages using contingent valuation: An experimental evaluation of accuracy (Research Triangle Institute Monograph 92–1).Research Triangle Park, NC: Research Triangle Institute. [1, 9, 31]Google Scholar
Desvousges, W. H., Johnson, F. R., Dunford, R. W., Boyle, K. J., Hudson, S. P., & Wilson, K. N. (1993). Measuring natural resource damages with contingent valuation: Tests of validity and reliability. In Hausman, J. A. (Ed.), Contingent valuation: A critical assessment (pp. 91–164). Amsterdam: North-Holland. [32]
Desvousges, W. H., Smith, V. K., & Fisher, A. (1987). Option price estimates for water quality improvements: A contingent valuation study for the Monongahela River. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 14, 248–267. [33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Devine, P. C. (1989). Stereotypes and prejudice: Their automatic and controlled components. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 56, 5–18. [15]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dhar, R. (1997). Consumer preference for a no-choice option. Journal of Consumer Research, 24, 215–231. [10, 16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dhar, R., & Nowlis, S. M. (1999). The effect of time pressure on consumer choice deferral. Journal of Consumer Research, 25, 369–384. [16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dhar, R., Nowlis, S. M., & Sherman, S. J. (1999). Comparison effects on preference construction. Journal of Consumer Research, 26, 293–306. [28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dhar, R., Nowlis, S. M., & Sherman, S. J. (2000). Trying hard or hardly trying: An analysis of context effects in choice. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 9, 189–200. [11]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dhar, R., & Simonson, I. (2003). The effect of forced choice on choice. Journal of Marketing Research, 40, 146–160. [11]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dhar, R., & Wertenbroch, K. (2000). Consumer choice between hedonic and utilitarian goods. Journal of Marketing Research, 27, 60–71. [32]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamond, P. A. (1996). Testing the internal consistency of contingent valuation surveys. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 30, 337–347. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamond, P. A., & Hausman, J. A. (1994). Contingent valuation: Is some number better than no number?The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8(4), 45–64. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamond, P. A., Hausman, J. A., Leonard, G., & Denning, M. (1993). Does contingent valuation measure preferences? Experimental evidence. In Hausman, J. A. (Ed.), Contingent valuation: A critical assessment (pp. 41–85). Amsterdam: North-Holland. [31]
Dickens, W. T., & Katz, L. F. (1987). Inter-industry wage differences and industry characteristics. In Lang, K. & Leonard, J. S. (Eds.), Unemployment and the structure of labor markets (pp. 48–89). Oxford, UK: Basil Blackwell. [13]
Dickie, M., Fisher, A., & Gerking, S. (1987). Market transactions and hypothetical demand data: A comparative study. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 82, 69–75. [33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diederich, A. (1997). Dynamic stochastic models for decision making under time constraints. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 41, 260–274. [11]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Diederich, A., & Busemeyer, J. R. (2003). Simple matrix methods for analyzing diffusion models of choice probability, choice response time, and simple response time. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 47, 304–322. [11]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diener, E. (2000). Subjective well-being: The science of happiness and a proposal for a national index. American Psychologist, 55, 34–43. [28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diener, E., Scollon, C. N., & Lucas, R. E. (2003). The evolving concept of subjective well-being: The multifaceted nature of happiness. In Costa, P. T. & Siegler, I. C. (Eds.), Advances in cell aging and gerontology: Vol. 15. Relevant advances in psychology and aging (pp. 187–219). Amsterdam: Elsevier. [28]
Diener, E., Suh, E. M., Lucas, R. E., & Smith, H. L. (1999). Subjective well-being: Three decades of progress. Psychological Bulletin, 125, 276–302. [28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dougherty, M. R. P., Gettys, C. F., & Ogden, E. E. (1999). MINERVA-DM: A memory processes model for judgments of likelihood. Psychological Review, 106, 180–209. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dougherty, M. R. P., Gronlund, S. D., & Gettys, C. F. (2003). Memory as a fundamental heuristic for decision making. In Schneider, S. L. & Shanteau, J. (Eds.), Emerging perspectives on judgment and decision making (pp. 125–164). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. [21]
Downs, J. S., Murray, P. J., Bruine de Bruin, W., White, J. P., Palmgren, C., & Fischhoff, B. (2004). An interactive video program to reduce adolescent females' STD risk: A randomized controlled trial. Social Science and Medicine, 59, 1561–1572. [35]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doyle, J. R., O'Connor, D. J., Reynolds, G. M., & Bottomley, P. A. (1999). The robustness of the asymmetrically dominated effect: Buying frames, phantom alternatives, and in-store purchases. Psychology & Marketing, 16, 225–243. [1]3.0.CO;2-X>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drolet, A. (1997). Generic preferences. Unpublished doctoral dissertation, Stanford University, Stanford, CA. [17]
Drolet, A., Simonson, I., & Tversky, A. (2000). Indifference curves that travel with the choice set. Marketing Letters, 11, 199–209. [13]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dunn, E. W., Wilson, T. D., & Gilbert, D. T. (2003). Location, location, location: The misprediction of satisfaction in housing lotteries. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 29, 1421–1432. [28]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Dunning, D., Griffin, D. W., Milojkovoc, J., & Ross, L. (1990). The overconfidence effect in social predication. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 58, 568–581. [30]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dutton, D. G., & Aron, A. P. (1974). Some evidence for heightened sexual attraction under conditions of high anxiety. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 30, 510–517. [30]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Dworkin, G. (1988). The theory and practice of autonomy.Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. [38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eagly, A. H., & Chaiken, S. (1993). The psychology of attitudes.Fort Worth, TX: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich College. [31]Google Scholar
Eagly, A. H., & Chaiken, S. (1998). Attitude structure and function. In Gilbert, D. T., Fiske, S. T., & Lindzey, G. (Eds.), The handbook of social psychology (4th ed., Vol. 1, pp. 269–322). Boston: McGraw-Hill. [31]
Easterlin, R. A. (1974). Does economic growth improve the human lot? In David, P. A. & Reder, M. W. (Eds.), Nations and households in economic growth: Essays in honor of Moses Abramovitz (pp. 89–125). New York: Academic Press. [28]
Easterlin, R. A. (2001). Income and happiness: Towards a unified theory. The Economic Journal, 111, 465–484. [28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Easterlin, R. A. (2003). Building a better theory of well-being (IZA discussion paper).Bonn, Germany: Institute for the Study of Labor. [28]Google Scholar
Edwards, A. L. (1957). Techniques of attitude scale construction.New York: Appleton-Century-Croft. [23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edwards, W. (1953). Probability-preferences in gambling. American Journal of Psychology, 66, 349–364. [1, 2]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Edwards, W. (1954a). Probability-preferences among bets with differing expected values. American Journal of Psychology, 67, 56–67. [1, 2]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edwards, W. (1954b). The reliability of probability-preferences. American Journal of Psychology, 67, 68–95. [1, 2]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edwards, W. (1954c). The theory of decision making. Psychological Bulletin, 51, 380–417. [1, 18, 19, 33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edwards, W. (1954d). Variance preferences in gambling. American Journal of Psychology, 67, 441–452. [2]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edwards, W. (1955). The prediction of decisions among bets. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 51, 201–214. [2, 3]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edwards, W. (1961). Behavioral decision theory. Annual Review of Psychology, 12, 473–498. [1, 33]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Edwards, W. (1962). Subjective probabilities inferred from decisions. Psychological Review, 69, 109–135. [2]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Edwards, W., & Fasolo, B. (2001). Decision technology. Annual Review of Psychology, 52, 581–606. [12]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Edwards, W., & Newman, J. R. (1982). Multiattribute evaluation.Beverly Hills, CA: Sage. [12]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edwards, W., & Winterfeldt, D. (1987). Public values in risk debates. Risk Analysis, 7, 141–158. [33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Einhorn, H. J. (1972). Expert measurement and mechanical combination. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 7, 86–106. [34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Einhorn, H. J. (1980). Learning from experience and suboptimal rules in decision making. In Wallsten, T. S. (Ed.), Cognitive processes in choice and decision behavior (pp. 1–20). Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [17]
Einhorn, H. J., & Hogarth, R. M. (1981). Behavioral decision theory: Processes of judgment and choice. Annual Review of Psychology, 32, 53–88. [19, 33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eisele, P. (2000). Post-decision consolidation: Group members in different social settings compared to individual decision makers. Scandinavian Journal of Psychology, 41, 275–282. [19]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Eisenhardt, K. M. (1989). Making fast strategic decisions in high velocity environments. Academy of Management Journal, 32, 543–576. [34]Google Scholar
Ellickson, R. C. (1989). Bringing culture and human frailty to rational actors: A critique of classical law and economics. Chicago-Kent Law Review, 65, 23–55. [27]Google Scholar
Elliott, R., & Dolan, R. J. (1998). Neural response during preference and memory judgments for subliminally presented stimuli: A functional neuro-imaging study. Journal of Neuroscience, 18, 4697–4704. [1, 25]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ellsberg, D. (1961). Risk ambiguity and the Savage axioms. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 75, 643–669. [27]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, J., & Loewenstein, G. (1992). Utility from memory and anticipation. In Elster, J. & Loewenstein, G. (Eds.), Choice over time (pp. 213–224). New York: Russell Sage Foundation. [27, 32]
Emanuel, E. E., & Emanuel, L. L. (1992). Four models of the physician-patient relationship. Journal of the American Medical Association, 267, 2221–2226. [36]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Epley, N., & Gilovich, T. (2001). Putting adjustment back in the anchoring and adjustment heuristic: Differential processing of self-generated and experimenter-provided anchors. Psychological Science, 12, 391–396. [13, 21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, S. (1994). Integration of the cognitive and the psychodynamic unconscious. American Psychologist, 49, 709–724. [1, 23, 32]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Erber, M. W., Hodges, S. D., & Wilson, T. D. (1995). Attitude strength and attitude stability. In Petty, R. E. & Krosnick, J. A. (Eds.), Attitude strength: Antecedents and consequences (pp. 433–454). Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [26]
Ericsson, K. A., & Simon, H. A. (1980). Verbal reports as data. Psychological Review, 87, 215–251. [10, 18]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eriksen, C. W. (1980). Discrimination and learning without awareness: A methodological survey and evaluation. Psychological Review, 67, 279–300. [25]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Erwin, P. G., & Calev, A. (1984). The influence of Christian name stereotypes on the marking of children's essays. British Journal of Educational Psychology, 54, 223–227. [23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Estes, W. K. (1994). Classification and cognition.New York: Oxford University Press. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
An ethically defensible market in organs [Editorial]. (2002). British Medical Journal, 325, 114–115. [37]CrossRef
Fair, R. C. (1978). A theory of extramarital affairs. Journal of Political Economy, 86, 45–61. [5]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falmagne, J.-C. (1985). Elements of psychophysical theory.New York: Oxford University Press. [6]Google Scholar
Fazio, R. H. (1995). Attitudes as object-evaluation associations: Determinants, consequences, and correlates of attitude accessibility. In Petty, R. E. & Krosnick, J. A. (Eds.), Attitude strength: Antecedents and consequences (pp. 247–282). Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [23]
Fazio, R. H., Sanbonmatsu, D. M., Powell, M. C., & Kardes, F. R. (1986). On the automatic activation of attitudes. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 50, 229–238. [31]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Feldman, J. M., & Lynch, J. G. Jr. (1988). Self-generated validity and other effects of measurement on belief, attitude, intention, and behavior. Journal of Applied Psychology, 73, 421–435. [17, 32, 34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feldman-Stewart, D., Brundage, M. D., Manen, L., & Svenson, O. (2004). Patient-focused decision making in early-stage prostate cancer: Insights from a cognitively based decision aid. Health Expectations, 7, 126–141. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Festinger, L. (1957). A theory of cognitive dissonance.Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. [18, 19, 30]Google Scholar
Festinger, L. (1964). Conflict, decision, and dissonance.Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. [12, 19]Google Scholar
Fetherstonhaugh, D., Slovic, P., Johnson, S. M., & Friedrich, J. (1997). Insensitivity to the value of human life: A study of psychophysical numbing. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 14, 283–300. [9, 23, 32]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Finucane, M. L., Alhakami, A., Slovic, P., & Johnson, S. M. (2000). The affect heuristic in judgments of risks and benefits. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 13, 1–17. [23, 32]3.0.CO;2-S>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischer, G. W. (1995). Range sensitivity to attribute weights in multiattribute value models. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 63, 252–266. [10]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischer, G. W., Carmon, Z., Ariely, D., & Zauberman, G. (1999). Goal-based construction of preferences: Task goals and the prominence effect. Management Science, 45, 1057–1075. [1, 21, 28, 29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischer, G. W., Damodaran, N., Laskey, K. B., & Lincoln, D. (1987). Preferences for proxy attributes. Management Science, 33, 198–214. [6, 9]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischer, G. W., & Hawkins, S. (1993). Strategy compatibility, scale compatibility, and the prominence effect. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance, 19, 580–597. [1, 9, 10, 18, 29]Google Scholar
Fischer, G. W., Jia, J., & Luce, M. F. (2000). Attribute conflict and preference uncertainty: The Rand MAU model. Management Science, 46, 669–684. [11]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischer, P. M. (1991). Brand logo recognition by children ages 3 to 6 years: Mickey Mouse and Old Joe the Camel. Journal of the American Medical Association, 266, 3145. [23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischhoff, B. (1975). Hindsight ≢ foresight: The effect of outcome knowledge on judgment under uncertainty. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance, 1, 288–299. [19]Google Scholar
Fischhoff, B. (1980). Clinical decision analysis. Operations Research, 28, 28–43. [35]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischhoff, B. (1983). Predicting frames. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 9, 113–116. [1, 21, 35]Google Scholar
Fischhoff, B. (1991). Value elicitation: Is there anything in there?American Psychologist, 46, 835–847. [15, 19, 21, 31, 34, 35]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischhoff, B. (1993). Transaction analysis: A framework and an application to insurance decisions. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 7, 53–69. [35]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischhoff, B. (1996). The real world: What good is it?Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 65, 232–248. [19, 35]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischhoff, B. (1997). What do psychologists want? Contingent valuation as a special case of asking questions. In Kopp, R. J., Pommerehne, W. W., & Schwartz, N. (Eds.), Determining the value of non-marketed goods: Economic, psychological, and policy relevant aspects of contingent valuation methods (pp. 189–217). Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishing. [34]
Fischhoff, B. (2005). Cognitive issues in stated preference methods. In Mäler, K.-G. & Vincent, J. R. (Eds.), Handbook of environmental economics: Vol. 2. Valuing environmental changes (pp. 937–968). Amsterdam: Elsevier. [35]
Fischhoff, B., & Furby, L. (1988). Measuring values: A conceptual framework for interpreting transactions with special reference to contingent valuation of visibility. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 1, 147–184. [33, 34, 35]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischhoff, B., Quadrel, M. J., Kamlet, M., Loewenstein, G., Dawes, R. M., Fischbeck, P., et al. (1993). Embedding effects: Stimulus representation and response mode. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 6, 211–234. [33, 34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischhoff, B., Slovic, P., & Lichtenstein, S. (1978). Fault trees: Sensitivity of estimated failure probabilities to problem representation. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance, 4, 330–344. [33]Google Scholar
Fischhoff, B., Slovic, P., & Lichtenstein, S. (1980). Knowing what you want: Measuring labile values. In Wallstein, T. (Ed.), Cognitive processes in choice and decision behavior (pp. 117–141). Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [6, 19, 34, 35]
Fischhoff, B., Slovic, P., Lichtenstein, S., Read, S., & Combs, B. (1978). How safe is safe enough? A psychometric study of attitudes toward technological risks and benefits. Policy Sciences, 9, 127–152. [23, 35]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischhoff, B., Watson, S., & Hope, C. (1984). Defining risk. Policy Sciences, 17, 123–139. [35]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischhoff, B., Welch, N., & Frederick, S. (1999). Construal processes in preference assessment. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 19, 139–176. [34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fishburn, P. C. (1984). SSB utility theory: An economic perspective. Mathematical Social Sciences, 8, 63–94. [6, 8]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fishburn, P. C. (1985). Nontransitive preference theory and the preference reversal phenomenon. Rivista Internazionale di Scienze Economiche e Commerciali, 32, 39–50. [1, 6, 8]Google Scholar
Fisher, I. (1906). The nature of capital and income.New York: Macmillan. [2]Google Scholar
Fisher, I. (1968). Is ‘utility’ the most suitable term for the concept it is used to denote? In Page, A. N. (Ed.), Utility theory: A book of readings (pp. 49–51). New York: Wiley (Reprinted from American Economic Review, 8, 335–337, 1918). [27]
Fisher, R. (1969). Basic negotiating strategy: International conflict for beginners.London: Allen Lane. [20]Google Scholar
Fiske, S. T. (1980). Attention and weight in person perception: The impact of negative and extreme behavior. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 38, 889–906. [7]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiske, S. T., & Pavelchak, M. A. (1986). Category-based versus piecemeal-based affective responses: Developments in schema-triggered affect. In Sorrentino, R. M. & Higgins, E. T. (Eds.), The handbook of motivation and cognition: Foundations of social behavior (pp. 167–203). New York: Guilford Press. [19]
Fitts, P. M., & Seeger, C. M. (1953). S-R compatibility: Spatial characteristics of stimulus and response codes. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 46, 199–210. [6]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fitzsimons, G. J., & Morwitz, V. G. (1996). The effect of measuring intent on brand-level purchasing behavior. Journal of Consumer Research, 23, 1–11. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Florig, H. K., Morgan, M. G., Morgan, K. M., Jenni, K. E., Fischhoff, B., & Fischbeck, P. S., et al. (2001). A test bed for studies of risk taking. Risk Analysis, 21, 913–922. [35]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ford, J. K., Schmitt, N., Schechtman, S. L., Hults, B. M., & Doherty, M. L. (1986). Process tracing methods: Contribution, problems, and neglected research questions. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 43, 75–117. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Forgas, J. P. (1995). Mood and judgment: The affect infusion model (AIM). Psychological Bulletin, 117, 39–66. [21, 30]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foster, V., Bateman, I. J., & Harley, D. (1997). Real and hypothetical willingness to pay for environmental preservation: A non-experimental comparison. Journal of Agricultural Economics, 48, 123–138. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fox, C. R., & Tversky, A. (1995). Ambiguity aversion and comparative ignorance. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 585–603. [9, 13, 14]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Franciosi, R., Kujal, P., Michelitsch, R., & Smith, V. (1993). Experimental tests of the endowment effect (Working paper).Tucson: University of Arizona, Department of Economics. [27]Google Scholar
Frank, R. H. (1992). The role of moral sentiments in the theory of intertemporal choice. In Elster, J. & Loewenstein, G. (Eds.), Choice over time (pp. 265–286). New York: Russell Sage Foundation. [27]
Frank, R. H. (1997). The frame of reference as public good. Economic Journal, 107, 1832–1847. [28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Franklin, B. (1950). The autobiography of Benjamin Franklin.New York: Pocket Books. [26]Google Scholar
Frederick, S. (2002). Automated choice heuristics. In Gilovich, T., Griffin, D., & Kahneman, D. (Eds.), Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment (pp. 548–558). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. [29, 32]
Frederick, S. (2003). Measuring intergenerational time preference: Are future lives valued less?Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 26, 39–53. [35, 38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frederick, S., & Fischhoff, B. (1998). Scope (in)sensitivity in elicited valuations. Risk Decision and Policy, 3, 109–123. [9, 13, 14, 31, 32]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frederick, S., & Loewenstein, G. (1999). Hedonic adaptation. In Kahneman, D., Diener, E., & Schwarz, N. (Eds.), Well-being: The foundations of hedonic psychology (pp. 302–329). New York: Russell Sage Foundation. [28]
Frederick, S., Loewenstein, G., & O'Donoghue, T. (2002). Time discounting and time preference: A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature, 40, 351–401.[38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fredrickson, B. L., & Kahneman, D. (1993). Duration neglect in retrospective evaluations of affective episodes. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 65, 45–55. [27]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Freeman, A. M. III. (1993a). The measurement of environmental and resource values: Theory and methods.Washington, DC: Resources for the Future. [34]Google Scholar
Freeman, A. M., III. (1993b). Nonuse values in natural resource damage assessments. In Kopp, R. & Smith, V. K. (Eds.), Valuing natural assets: The economics of natural resource damage assessment (pp. 264–303). Washington, DC: Resources for the Future. [33]
Freeman, A. M. III. (2003). The measurement of environmental and resource values: Theory and methods (2nd ed.).Washington, DC: Resources for the Future. [36]Google Scholar
Freud, A. (1937). The ego and the mechanisms of defense.London: Hogarth Press. [30]Google Scholar
Frey, B. S., & Stutzer, A. (2000). Happiness, economy, and institutions. Economic Journal, 110, 918–938. [28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, B. S., & Stutzer, A. (2002a). Happiness and economics.Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. [28]Google Scholar
Frey, B. S., & Stutzer, A. (2002b). What can economists learn from happiness research?Journal of Economic Literature, 40, 402–435. [28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, B. S., & Stutzer, A. (2003). Economic consequences of mispredicting utility. Unpublished manuscript. [28]
Frey, D. (1981). Postdecisional preference for decision-relevant information as a function of its source and the degree of familiarity with its information. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 17, 51–67. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, D. (1986). Recent research on selective exposure to information. Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, 19, 41–80. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, M., & Friedman, R. (1980). Free to choose: A personal statement.New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich. [38]Google Scholar
Friedrich, J., Barnes, P., Chapin, K., Dawson, I., Garst, V., & Kerr, D. (1999). Psycho-physical numbing: When lives are valued less as the lives at risk increase. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 8, 277–299. [23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frijda, N. H. (1986). The emotions: Studies in emotion and social interaction.New York: Cambridge University Press. [24]Google Scholar
Frisch, D., & Clemen, R. T. (1994). Beyond expected utility: Rethinking behavioral decision research. Psychological Bulletin, 116, 46–54. [17, 34]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Frisch, D., & Jones, S. K. (1993). Assessing the accuracy of decisions. Theory and Psychology, 3, 115–135. [9]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gäbel, H. (2002). Donor and non-donor registries in Europe.Stockholm, Sweden: On behalf of the committee of experts on the Organizational Aspects of Co-operation in Organ Transplantation of the Council of Europe. [37]Google Scholar
Gaeth, G. J., & Shanteau, J. (1984). Reducing the influence of irrelevant information on experienced decision makers. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 33, 263–282. [33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gallhofer, L., & Saris, W. (1989). Decision trees and decision rules: The empirical decision analysis procedure. In Montgomery, H. & Svenson, O. (Eds.), Process and structure in human decision making (pp. 293–311). Chichester, UK: Wiley. [18]
The Gallup Organization, Inc. (1993). The American public's attitude toward organ donation and transplantation.Boston: Author. [37]
Ganzach, Y. (1995). Attribute scatter and decision outcome: Judgment versus choice. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 62, 113–122. [10]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ganzach, Y. (1996). Preference reversals in equal-probability gambles: A case for anchoring and adjustment. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 9, 95–109. [11]3.0.CO;2-W>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gardiner, P. C., & Edwards, W. (1975). Public values: Multiattribute-utility measurement for social decision making. In Kaplan, M. F. & Schwartz, S. (Eds.), Human judgment and decision processes (pp. 1–37). New York: Academic Press. [33]
Garvil, J., Gärling, T., Lindberg, E., & Montgomery, H. (1991, August). In search of evidence for dominance structuring in decision making. Paper presented at the 13th European Research Conference of Subjective Probability, Utility, and Decision Making, Fribourg, Switzerland. [18]
Gertner, J. (2003, September 7). The futile pursuit of happiness. The New York Times, Sec. 6, p. 44. [1]Google Scholar
Gettys, C. F., Pliske, R. M., Manning, C., & Casey, J. T. (1987). An evaluation of human act generation performance. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 39, 23–51. [9]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gigerenzer, G., & Selten, R. (2001). Rethinking rationality. In Gigerenzer, G. & Selten, R. (Eds.), Bounded rationality: The adaptive toolbox (pp. 1–12). Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press. [1]
Gigerenzer, G., Todd, P. M., & The ABC Group. (1999). Simple heuristics that make us smart.New York: Oxford University Press. [21]Google Scholar
Gilbert, D. T., Driver-Linn, E., & Wilson, T. D. (2002). The trouble with Vronsky: Impact bias in the forecasting of future affective states. In Barrett, L. F. & Salovey, P. (Eds.), The wisdom in feeling: Psychological processes in emotional intelligence (pp. 114–143). New York: Guilford Press. [28]
Gilbert, D. T., & Ebert, J. E. J. (2002). Decisions and revisions: The affective forecasting of changeable outcomes. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 82, 503–514. [30]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gilbert, D. T., Gill, M. J., & Wilson, T. D. (2002). The future is now: Temporal correction in affective forecasting. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 88, 430–444. [28, 29, 30, 32]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilbert, D. T., Lieberman, M. D., Morewedge, C. K., & Wilson, T. D. (2004). The peculiar longevity of things not so bad. Psychological Science, 15, 14–19. [30]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gilbert, D. T., Pinel, E. C., Wilson, T. D., Blumberg, S. J., & Wheatley, T. P. (1998). Immune neglect: A source of durability bias in affective forecasting. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 75, 617–638. [28, 30]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gilbert, D. T., Pinel, E. C., Wilson, T. D., Blumberg, S. J., & Wheatley, T. P. (2002). Durability bias in affective forecasting. In Gilovich, T., Griffin, D., & Kahneman, D. (Eds.), Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment (pp. 292–312). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. [28]
Gilbert, D. T., & Wilson, T. D. (2000). Miswanting: Some problems in the forecasting of future affective states. In Forgas, J. P. (Ed.), Feeling and thinking: The role of affect in social cognition (pp. 178–197). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. [1, 28, 30]
Gilboa, I., & Schmeidler, D. (1995). Case-based decision theory. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 605–639. [13]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilovich, T., & Medvec, V. H. (1995). The experience of regret: What, when, and why. Psychological Review, 102, 379–395. [16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gimbel, R. W., Strosberg, M. A., Lehrman, S. E., Gefenas, E., & Taft, F. (2003). Presumed consent and other predictors of cadaveric organ donation in Europe. Progress in Transplantation, 13, 5–15. [37]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glass, D. C., & Singer, J. E. (1972a). Stress and adaptation: Experimental studies of behavioral effects of exposure to aversive events.New York: Academic Press. [16]Google Scholar
Glass, D. C., & Singer, J. E. (1972b). Urban stress.New York: Academic Press. [16]Google Scholar
Glimcher, P. W., & Rustichini, A. (2004). Neuroeconomics: The consilience of brain and decision. Science, 306, 447–452. [1]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gneezy, U., & Potters, J. (1997). An experiment on risk taking and evaluation periods. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 631–645. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gold, J. I. (2003). Linking reward expectation to behavior in the basal ganglia. Trends in Neurosciences, 26, 12–14. [11]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gold, J. I., & Shadlen, M. N. (2001). Neural computations that underlie decisions about sensory stimuli. Trends in Cognitive Science, 5, 10–16. [11]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Goldstein, W. M. (1984). The relationship between judgment and choice. Dissertation Abstracts International, 45(07B), 2341. [7]
Goldstein, W. M., & Einhorn, H. J. (1987). Expression theory and the preference reversal phenomena. Psychological Review, 94, 236–254. [1, 6, 7, 8, 9, 10, 11]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gollwitzer, P. M. (1990). Action phases and mind-sets. In Higgins, E. T. & Sorrentiono, R. M. (Eds.), Handbook of motivation and cognition: Foundations of social behavior (Vol. 2, pp. 53–92). New York: Guilford Press. [18]
Gollwitzer, P. M., & Bayer, U. (1999). Deliberative versus implementational mindsets in the control of action. In Chaiken, S. & Trope, Y. (Eds.), Dual-process theories in social psychology (pp. 403–422). New York: Guilford Press. [12]
Gollwitzer, P. M., Heckhausen, H., & Ratajczak, H. (1990). From weighting to willing: Approaching a change decision through pre- or postdecisional mentation. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 45, 41–65. [18]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gollwitzer, P. M., Heckhausen, H., & Steller, B. (1990). Deliberative and implementational mind mind-sets: Cognitive turning toward congruous thoughts and information. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 59, 1119–1127. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gonzalez, R., & Wu, G. (1999). On the shape of the probability weighting function. Cognitive Psychology, 38, 129–166. [32]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
González-Vallejo, C., Erev, I., & Wallsten, T. S. (1994). Do decision quality and preference order depend on whether probabilities are verbal or numerical?American Journal of Psychology, 107, 157–172. [29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
González-Vallejo, C., & Moran, E. (2001). The evaluability hypothesis revisited: Joint and separate preference reversal as a function of attribute importance. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 86, 216–233. [28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gorovitz, S. (1982). Doctors' dilemmas: Moral conflict and medical care.New York: Macmillan. [36]Google Scholar
Gourville, J. T. (1998). Pennies-a-day: The effect of temporal re-framing on transaction evaluation. Journal of Consumer Research, 24, 395–408. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Green, D., Jacowitz, K., Kahneman, D., & McFadden, D. (1998). Referendum contingent valuation, anchoring, and willingness to pay for public goods. Resource and Energy Economics, 20, 85–116. [13, 31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Green, P. E., & Srinivasan, V. (1990). Conjoint analysis in marketing: New developments with implications for research and practice. Journal of Marketing, 45, 33–41. [34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenwald, A. G. (1980). The totalitarian ego: Fabrication and revision of personal history. American Psychologist, 35, 603–618. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenwald, A. G., Carnot, C. G., Beach, R., & Young, B. (1987). Increasing voting behavior by asking people if they expect to vote. Journal of Applied Psychology, 72, 315–318. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gregory, R., Flynn, J., Johnson, S. M., Satterfield, T. A., Slovic, P., & Wagner, R. (1997). Decision pathway surveys: A tool for resource managers. Land Economics, 73, 240–254. [34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gregory, R., Keeney, R., & Winterfeldt, D. (1992). Adapting the environmental impact statement process to inform decision makers. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 1, 58–75. [33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gregory, R., Lichtenstein, S., Brown, T. C., Peterson, G. L., & Slovic, P. (1995). How precise are monetary representations of environmental improvements?Land Economics, 71, 462–473. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gregory, R., Lichtenstein, S., & Slovic, P. (1993). Valuing environmental resources: A constructive approach. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 7, 177–197. [1, 17, 33, 34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gregory, R., MacGregor, D. G., & Lichtenstein, S. (1992). Assessing the quality of expressed preference measures of value. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 17, 277–292. [33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gregory, R., & McDaniels, T. (1987). Valuing environmental losses: What promise does the right measure hold?Policy Sciences, 20, 11–26. [33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grether, D. M. (1980). Bayes rules as a descriptive model: The representativeness heuristic. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 95, 537–557. [38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grether, D. M., & Plott, C. R. (1979). Economic theory of choice and the preference reversal phenomenon. American Economic Review, 69(4), 623–638. [1, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9, 11, 33, 34]Google Scholar
Grice, H. P. (1975). Logic and conversation. In Davidson, D. & Harman, G. (Eds.), The logic of grammar (pp. 64–75). Encino, CA: Dickenson. [35]
Griffin, D. W., Dunning, D., & Ross, L. (1990). The role of construal processes in overconfident predictions about the self and others. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 59, 1128–1139. [30]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Griffin, D. W., & Ross, L. (1991). Subjective construal, social interference, and human misunderstanding. In Zanna, M. (Ed.), Advances in experimental social psychology (Vol. 24, pp. 319–356). New York: Academic Press. [30]
Griffin, D. W., & Tversky, A. (1992). The weighing of evidence and the determinants of confidence. Cognitive Psychology, 24, 411–435. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossberg, S. (1982). Associative and competitive principles of learning and development: The temporal unfolding and stability of STM and LTM patterns. In Amari, S. I. & Arbib, M. (Eds.), Competition and cooperation in neural networks (pp. 448–485). New York: Springer-Verlag. [11]
Grossberg, S. (1988). Neural networks and natural intelligence.Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. [11]Google Scholar
Grossberg, S., & Gutowski, W. E. (1987). Neural dynamics of decision making under risk: Affective balance and cognitive-emotional interactions. Psychological Review, 94, 300–318. [11]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Guadagni, P. M., & Little, J. D. C. (1983). A logit model of brand choice calibrated on scanner data. Marketing Science, 2, 203–238. [10]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guala, F. (2000). Artefacts in experimental economics: Preference reversals and the Becker-deGroot-Marschak mechanism. Economics and Philosophy, 16, 47–75. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guo, F. Y., & Holyoak, K. J. (2002, August). Understanding similarity in choice behavior: A connectionist model. Poster presented at the Cognitive Science Society Meeting, Fairfax, VA. [11]
Hamm, R. M. (1984). The conditions of occurrence of the preference reversal phenomenon (ICS Publication #90–11).Boulder: University of Colorado, Center for Research on Judgment and Policy. [8]Google Scholar
Hammarberg, A., & Svenson, O. (2000). Individual postdecisional processes in group settings. Scandinavian Journal of Psychology, 41, 145–158. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hammermesh, D., & Soss, D. (1978). An economic theory of suicide. Journal of Political Economy, 82, 83–98. [5]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hammond, J. S., Keeney, R. L., & Raiffa, H. (1999). Smart choices: A practical guide to making better decisions.Boston: Harvard Business School Press. [1]Google Scholar
Hammond, K. R. (1990). Functionalism and illusionism: Can integration be usefully achieved? In Hogarth, R. M. (Ed.), Insights in decision making: A tribute to Hillel J. Einhorn (pp. 227–261). Chicago: University of Chicago Press. [21]
Hammond, K. R. (1996a). How convergence of research paradigms can improve research on diagnostic judgment. Medical Decision Making, 16, 216–233. [28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hammond, K. R. (1996b). Human judgment and social policy: Irreducible uncertainty, inevitable error, unavoidable injustice.New York: Oxford University Press. [34]Google Scholar
Hammond, K. R., Hursch, C., & Todd, F. J. (1964). Analyzing the components of clinical inference. Psychological Review, 72, 215–224. [1, 2]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hammond, K. R., McClelland, G. H., & Mumpower, J. (1980). Human judgment and decision making: Theories, methods, and procedures.New York: Praeger. [33]Google Scholar
Hammond, K. R., Stewart, T. R., Brehmer, B., & Steinmann, D. O. (1975). Social judgment theory. In Kaplan, M. F. & Schwartz, S. (Eds.), Human judgment and decision processes.New York: Academic Press. [34]Google Scholar
Hammond, P. (1985). Consequential behavior in decision trees and expected utility (Working Paper No. 112).Stanford, CA: Stanford University, Institute for Mathematical Studies in the Social Sciences. [27]Google Scholar
Hanemann, W. M. (1994). Valuing the environment through contingent valuation. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8(4), 19–43. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansen, F. (1972). Consumer choice behavior: A cognitive theory.New York: The Free Press. [17]Google Scholar
Hanson, J. D., & Kysar, D. A. (1999a). Taking behavioralism seriously: Some evidence of market manipulation. Harvard Law Review, 112(7), 1420–1572. [1, 23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hanson, J. D., & Kysar, D. A. (1999b). Taking behavioralism seriously: The problem of market manipulation. New York University Law Review, 74(3), 630–749. [1, 23]Google Scholar
Hanson, J. D., & Kysar, D. A. (2001). The joint failure of economic theory and legal regulation. In Slovic, P. (Ed.), Smoking: Risk, perception, & policy (pp. 229–276). Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. [23]
Harari, H., & McDavid, J. W. (1973). Name stereotypes and teachers' expectations. Journal of Educational Psychology, 65, 222–225. [23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hardie, B. G. S., Johnson, E. J., & Fader, P. S. (1993). Modeling loss aversion and reference dependence effects on brand choice. Marketing Science, 12, 378–394. [27]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hare, R. D. (1965). Psychopathy, fear arousal, and anticipated pain. Psychological Reports, 16, 499–502. [23]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Harris, C. C., Tinsley, H. E. A., & Donnelly, D. M. (1988). Research methods for public amenity resource valuation: Issues and recommendations. In Peterson, G. L., Driver, B. L., & Gregory, R. (Eds.), Amenity resource valuation: Integrating economics with other disciplines (pp. 201–218). State College, PA: Venture. [34]
Harris, C. E., & Alcorn, S. P. (2001). To solve a deadly shortage: Economic incentives for human organ donation. Issues in Law and Medicine, 3, 213–233. [37]Google Scholar
Harris, J. (2003). Organ procurement: Dead interests, living needs. Journal of Medical Ethics, 29, 130–134. [37]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Harte, J. M., Westenberg, R. M., & Someren, M. (1994). Process models in decision making. Acta Psychologica, 87, 95–120. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hastie, R., & Dawes, R. M. (2002). Rational choice in an uncertain world (2nd ed.).Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. [35]Google Scholar
Hastie, R., & Park, B. (1986). The relationship between memory and judgment depends on whether the judgment task is memory-based or on-line. Psychological Review, 93, 258–268. [15]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hastie, R., Schkade, D., & Payne, J. (1999). Juror judgments in civil cases: Effects of plaintiff's request and plaintiff's identity on punitive damage awards. Law and Human Behavior, 23, 445–470. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hauser, J. R., Simester, D. I., & Wernerfelt, B. (1994). Customer satisfaction incentives. Marketing Science, 13, 327–350. [10]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hauser, J. R., & Wernerfelt, B. (1990). An evaluation cost model of consideration sets. Journal of Consumer Research, 16, 393–408. [16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausman, D. M. (1991). On dogmatism in economics: The case of preference reversals. Journal of Socio-Economics, 20, 205–225. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hays, W. L. (1963). Statistics for psychologists.New York: Holt, Rinehart & Winston. [2]Google Scholar
Heath, C., & Soll, J. (1996). Mental budgeting and consumer decisions. Journal of Consumer Research, 23, 40–52. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heeler, R. M., Okechuku, C., & Reid, S. (1979). Attribute importance: Contrasting measurements. Journal of Marketing Research, 16, 60–63. [10]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heider, F. (1980). The psychology of interpersonal relations.New York: Wiley. [22]Google Scholar
Helson, H. (1933). The fundamental functions of gestalt psychology. Psychological Review, 40, 13–22. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hendrick, C., Mills, M., & Kiesler, C. A. (1968). Decision time as a function of number and complexity of equally attractive alternatives. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 8, 313–318. [16]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hendrickx, L., Vlek, C., & Oppewal, H. (1989). Relative importance of scenario information and frequency information in the judgment of risk. Acta Psychologica, 72, 41–63. [23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herman, L. M., & Bahrick, H. P. (1966). Information encoding and decision time as variables in human choice behavior. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 71, 718–724. [2]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Herr, P. M. (1986). Consequences of priming: Judgment and behavior. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 19, 323–340. [15]Google Scholar
Herr, P. M. (1989). Priming price: Prior knowledge and context effects. Journal of Consumer Research, 16, 67–75. [15]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herr, P. M., Sherman, S. J., & Fazio, R. H. (1983). On the consequences of priming: Assimilation and contrast effects. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 19, 323–340. [15]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herrnstein, R. J. (1982). Stimuli and the texture of experience. Neuroscience & Biobehavioral Reviews, 6, 105–117. [20]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Herrnstein, R. J., Loewenstein, G., Prelec, D., & Vaughan, W. (1993). Utility maximization and melioration: Internalities in individual choices. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 6, 149–185. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herrnstein, R. J., & Prelec, D. (1992a). Melioration. In Loewenstein, G. & Elster, J. (Eds.), Choice over time (pp. 235–263). New York: Russell Sage Foundation. [20]
Herrnstein, R. J., & Prelec, D. (1992b). A theory of addiction. In Loewenstein, G. & Elster, J. (Eds.), Choice over time (pp. 331–360). New York: Russell Sage Foundation. [20]
Hershey, J., & Schoemaker, P. J. (1985). Probability vs. certainty equivalence methods in utility measurement: Are they equivalent?Management Science, 31, 1213–1231. [1, 6]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heyman, G. M. (1996). Resolving the contradictions of addiction. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 19, 561–610. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Higgins, E. T. (1996). Knowledge activation: Accessibility, applicability, and salience. In Higgins, E. T. & Kruglanski, A. W. (Eds.), Social psychology: Handbook of basic principles (pp. 133–168). New York: Guilford Press. [15]
Higgins, E. T., & Kruglanski, A. W. (1996). Social psychology: Handbook of basic principles.New York: Guilford Press. [21]Google Scholar
Hirt, E. R., & Markman, K. D. (1995). Multiple explanations: A consider-an-alternative strategy for debiasing judgments. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 69, 1069–1086. [28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirt, E. R., & Sherman, S. J. (1985). The role of prior knowledge in explaining hypothetical events. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 21, 519–543. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
HM Treasury, . (2004). Managing risks to the public: Appraisal guidance. London: Author. [35]Google Scholar
Hoch, S. J. (1984). Availability and interference in predictive judgment. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 10, 649–662. [21]Google Scholar
Hoch, S. J. (1985). Counterfactual reasoning and accuracy in predicting personal events. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 11, 719–731. [21]Google Scholar
Hoch, S. J., & Loewenstein, G. (1991). Time-inconsistent preferences and consumer self-control. Journal of Consumer Research, 17, 492–507. [17]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoeffler, S., & Ariely, D. (1999). Constructing stable preferences: A look into dimensions of experience and their impact of preference stability. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 11, 113–139. [13]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoehn, J. P., & Randall, A. (1989). Too many proposals pass the benefit cost test. American Economic Review, 79(3), 544–551. [31]Google Scholar
Hoffman, D. L., & Novak, T. P. (1996). Marketing in hypermedia computer-mediated environments: Conceptual foundations. Journal of Marketing, 60, 50–68. [15]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, P. J. (1960). The paramorphic representation of clinical judgment. Psychological Bulletin, 57, 116–131. [1, 2]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hogarth, R. M. (Ed.). (1982). New directions for methodology of social and behavioral science: No. 11. Question framing and response consistency.San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass. [33]Google Scholar
Hogarth, R. M. (1987). Judgment and choice. New York: Wiley. [34]
Hollerman, J. R., & Shultz, W. (1998). Dopamine neurons report an error in the temporal prediction of reward during learning. Nature Neuroscience, 1, 304–309. [11]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Holt, C. A. (1986). Preference reversals and the independence axiom. American Economic Review, 76(3), 508–515. [1, 8]Google Scholar
Holyoak, K. J., & Simon, D. (1999). Bidirectional reasoning in decision making by constraint satisfaction. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 128, 3–31. [11, 12, 19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holyoak, K. J., & Thagard, P. (1989). Analogical mapping by constraint satisfaction. Cognitive Science, 13, 295–355. [12]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holzberg, J. D. (1957). The clinical and scientific method: Synthesis or antithesis?Journal of Projective Techniques, 21, 227–242. [2]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hong, S.-T., & Wyer, R. S. (1990). Determinants of product evaluation: Effects of the time interval between knowledge of products' country of origin and information about its specific attributes. Journal of Consumer Research, 17, 277–288. [10]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Horsky, D., & Nelson, P. (1992). New brand positioning and pricing in an oligopolistic market. Marketing Science, 11, 133–153. [10]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Houston, D. A., & Sherman, S. J. (1995). Cancellation and focus: The role of shared and unique features in the choice process. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 31, 357–378. [28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hovenkamp, H. (1991). Legal policy and the endowment effect. Journal of Legal Studies, 20, 225–247. [27]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Howard, J. A., & Sheth, J. N. (1969). The theory of buyer behavior.Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley. [17]Google Scholar
Hsee, C. K. (1993). When trend of monetary outcomes matters: Separate versus joint evaluation and judgment of feelings versus choice. Unpublished manuscript, The University of Chicago. [9]
Hsee, C. K. (1995). Elastic justification: How tempting but task-irrelevant factors influence decisions. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 62, 330–337. [9, 29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsee, C. K. (1996a). The evaluability hypothesis: An explanation for preference reversals between joint and separate evaluations of alternatives. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 67, 247–257. [1, 9, 10, 20, 23, 28, 29, 31, 32]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsee, C. K. (1996b). Elastic justification: How unjustifiable factors influence judgments. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 66, 122–129. [9, 23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsee, C. K. (1998). Less is better: When low-value options are valued more highly than high-value options. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 11, 107–121. [1, 9, 23, 28]3.0.CO;2-Y>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsee, C. K. (1999). Value-seeking and prediction-decision inconsistency: Why don't people take what they predict they'll like the most?Psychonomic Bulletin and Review, 6, 555–561. [29]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hsee, C. K. (2000). Attribute evaluability and its implications for joint-separate evaluation reversals and beyond. In Kahneman, D. & Tversky, A. (Eds.), Choices, values and frames (pp. 543–563). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. [28]
Hsee, C. K., & Abelson, R. P. (1991). Velocity relation: Satisfaction as a function of the first derivative of outcome over time. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 60, 341–347. [9, 29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsee, C. K., Abelson, R. P., & Salovey, P. (1991). The relative weighting of position and velocity in satisfaction. Psychological Science, 2, 263–266. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsee, C. K., & Kunreuther, H. (2000). The affection effect in insurance decisions. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 20, 141–159. [23, 29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsee, C. K., & Leclerc, F. (1998). Will products look more attractive when evaluated jointly or when evaluated separately?Journal of Consumer Research, 25, 175–186. [9, 28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsee, C. K., Loewenstein, G., Blount, S., & Bazerman, M. H. (1999). Preference reversals between joint and separate evaluations of options: A review and theoretical analysis. Psychological Bulletin, 125, 576–590. [1, 9, 10, 13, 14, 20, 28, 29, 32, 34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsee, C. K., & Menon, S. (1999). Affection effect in consumer choices. Unpublished study, University of Chicago. [23]
Hsee, C. K., & Rottenstreich, Y. (2004). Music, pandas, and muggers: On the affective psychology of value. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 133, 23–30. [1, 28, 29, 32]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hsee, C. K., Salovey, P., & Abelson, R. P. (1994). The quasi-acceleration relation: Satisfaction as a function of the change in velocity of outcome over time. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 30, 96–111. [9]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsee, C. K., & Weber, E. U. (1997). A fundamental prediction error: Self-other discrepancies in risk preference. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 126, 45–53. [28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsee, C. K., Yu, F., Zhang, J., & Zhang, Y. (2003). Medium maximization. Journal of Consumer Research, 30, 1–14. [28, 29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsee, C. K., & Zhang, J. (2003). Inconsistency between choice and consumption experience. Unpublished manuscript. [28]
Hsee, C. K., & Zhang, J. (2004). Distinction bias: Misprediction and mischoice due to joint evaluation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 86, 680–695. [1, 28, 32]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hsee, C. K., Zhang, J., & Chen, J. (2004). Internal and substantive inconsistencies in decision-making. In Koehler, D. J. & Harvey, N. (Eds.), Blackwell handbook of judgment and decision making (pp. 360–378). Oxford, UK: Blackwell. [1, 28]
Hsee, C. K., Zhang, J., Yu, F., & Xi, Y. (2003). Lay rationalism and inconsistency between predicted experience and decision. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 16, 257–272. [1, 28, 29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, J. (1997). What we have learned from 20 years of conjoint research: When to use self-explicated, graded pairs, full profiles, or choice experiments. In 1997 Sawtooth Conference Proceedings.Sequim, WA: Sawtooth Software. [34]Google Scholar
Huber, J., Lynch, J. G., Corfman, K. P., Feldman, J., Holbrook, M. C., Lehman, D. R., et al. (1997). Thinking about values in prospect and retrospect: Maximizing experienced utility. Marketing Letters, 8, 323–334. [34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, J., Payne, J. W., & Puto, C. (1982). Adding asymmetrically dominated alternatives: Violations of regularity and the similarity hypothesis. Journal of Consumer Research, 9, 90–98. [1, 10, 11, 17, 18, 22]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, J., Wittink, D. R., Fiedler, J. A., & Miller, R. (1993). The effectiveness of alternative preference elicitation procedures in predicting choice. Journal of Marketing Research, 30, 105–114. [10, 17, 34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, O. (1980). The influence of some task variables on cognitive operations in an information-processing decision model. Acta Psychologica, 45, 187–196. [10, 33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, O. (1989). Information-processing operators in decision making. In Montgomery, H. & Svenson, O. (Eds.), Process and structure in human decision making (pp. 3–21). Chichester, UK: Wiley. [19]
Irwin, J. R. (1994). Buying/selling price preference reversals: Preference for environmental changes in buying versus selling modes. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 60, 431–457. [9, 28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Irwin, J. R., Schenk, D., McClelland, G. H., Schulze, W. D., Stewart, T., & Thayer, M. (1990). Urban visibility: Some experiments on the contingent valuation method. In Mathei, C. V. (Ed.), Visibility and fine particles (pp. 647–658). Pittsburgh, PA: Air and Waste Management Association. [33, 34]
Irwin, J. R., Slovic, P., Lichtenstein, S., & McClelland, G. H. (1993). Preference reversals and the measurement of environmental values. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 6, 5–18. [1, 9, 33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isen, A. M. (1993). Positive affect and decision making. In Lewis, M. & Haviland, J. M. (Eds.), Handbook of emotions (pp. 261–277). New York: Guilford Press. [23]Google Scholar
Isen, A. M. (2000). Some perspectives on positive affect and self-regulation. Psychological Inquiry, 11, 184–187. [24]Google Scholar
Iyengar, S. S., & Lepper, M. R. (2000). When choice is demotivating: Can one desire too much of a good thing?Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 79, 995–1006. [1, 16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacowitz, K., & Kahneman, D. (1995). Measures of anchoring in estimation tasks. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 21, 1161–1166. [13, 31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jako, R. A., & Murphy, K. R. (1990). Distributional ratings, judgment decomposition, and their impact on interrater agreement and rating accuracy. Journal of Applied Psychology, 75, 500–505. [34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
James, W. (1981). The principles of psychology (Vol. 2). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press (Original work published 1890). [22]Google Scholar
Janis, I. L., & Mann, L. (1977). Decision making: A psychological analysis of conflict, choice, and commitment. New York: The Free Press. [9, 12, 19, 26, 28, 34]Google Scholar
Jenni, K., & Loewenstein, G. (1997). Explaining the “identifiable victim effect.”Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 14, 235–257. [9, 23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
John, D. R., & Whitney, J. C. (1986). The development of consumer knowledge in children: A cognitive structure approach. Journal of Consumer Research, 12, 406–417. [17]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, E. J. (2001). Digitizing consumer research. Journal of Consumer Research, 28, 331–336. [15]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, E. J., Bellman, S., & Lohse, G. L. (2002). Defaults, framing and privacy: Why opting in-opting out. Marketing Letters, 13, 5–15. [37]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, E. J., & Goldstein, D. G. (2003). Do defaults save lives?Science, 302, 1338–1139. [1, 37]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Johnson, E. J., Hershey, J., Meszaros, J., & Kunreuther, H. (1993). Framing, probability distortions, and insurance decisions. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 7, 35–51. [37, 38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, E. J., Meyer, R. M., & Ghose, S. (1989). When choice models fail: Compensatory representations in negatively correlated environments. Journal of Marketing Research, 26, 255–270. [33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, E. J., Payne, J. W., & Bettman, J. R. (1988). Information displays and preference reversals. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 42, 1–21. [7]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, E. J., Payne, J. W., & Bettman, J. R. (1993). Adapting to time constraints. In Svenson, O. & Maule, A. J. (Eds.), Time pressure and stress in human judgment and decision making (pp. 103–116). New York: Plenum. [15]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, E. J., Payne, J. W., Schkade, D. A., & Bettman, J. R. (1988). Monitoring information acquisitions and decisions: Mouse decision laboratory software [Mouselab users manual]. Durham, NC: Duke University, Fuqua School of Business. [7]Google Scholar
Johnson, E. J., & Russo, J. E. (1984). Product familiarity and learning new information. Journal of Consumer Research, 11, 542–550. [15]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, E. J., & Schkade, D. A. (1989). Bias in utility assessments: Further evidence and explanations. Management Science, 35, 406–424. [7, 13, 14]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, E. J., & Tversky, A. (1983). Affect, generalization, and the perception of risk. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 45, 20–31. [21, 23, 24]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, E. J., & Weber, E. U. (2000, November). Preferences as memory. Paper presented at the meetings of the Judgment and Decision Making Society, New Orleans, LA. [21]
Johnson, J. G., & Busemeyer, J. R. (2005). A dynamic, stochastic, computational model of preference reversal phenomena. Psychological Review, 112, 841–861. [1, 11]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Johnson, M. D. (1984). Consumer choice strategies for comparing noncomparable alternatives. Journal of Consumer Research, 11, 741–753. [10, 17]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jolls, C., Sunstein, C. R., & Thaler, R. H. (1998). A behavioral approach to law and economics. Stanford Law Review, 50, 1471–1550. [38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones-Lee, M., Hammerton, M., & Phillips, R. (1985). The value of safety: Results from a national survey. Economic Journal, 95, 49–72. [33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones-Lee, M., & Loomes, G. (2001). Private values and public policy. In Weber, E. U., Baron, J., & Loomes, G. (Eds.), Conflict and tradeoffs in decision making (pp. 205–230). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. [38]Google Scholar
Jones-Lee, M., Loomes, G., & Philips, P. (1995). Valuing the prevention of non-fatal road injuries: Contingent valuation vs. standard gambles. Oxford Economic Papers, 47, 676–695. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joseph, R. A., Larrick, R. F., Steele, C. M., & Nisbett, R. E. (1992). Protecting the self from negative consequences of risky decisions. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 62, 26–37. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Just, M. A., & Carpenter, P. A. (1976). Eye fixations and cognitive processes. Cognitive Psychology, 8, 441–480. [7]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kagel, J. H., & Battalio, R. C. (1975). Experimental studies of consumer demand behavior using laboratory animals. Economic Inquiry, 13, 22–38. [5]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kagel, J. H., & Battalio, R. C. (1976). Demand curves for animal consumers [Mimeo]. St. Louis, MO: Washington University. [5]Google Scholar
Kahneman, D. (1973). Attention and effort. Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. [17, 20]Google Scholar
Kahneman, D. (1986). Valuing environmental goods: An assessment of the contingent valuation method. In Cummings, R., Brookshire, D., & Schulze, W. (Eds.), Valuing environmental goods: An assessment of the contingent valuation method (pp. 185–194). Totowa, NJ. [31]Google Scholar
Kahneman, D. (1994). New challenges to the rationality assumption. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 150, 18–36. [1, 17, 23, 27, 28, 29, 34, 36]Google Scholar
Kahneman, D. (1995). Varieties of counterfactual thinking. In Roese, N. J. & Olson, J. M. (Eds.), What might have been: The social psychology of counterfactual thinking (pp. 375–396). Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [28]Google Scholar
Kahneman, D. (2000). Experienced utility and objective happiness: A moment-based approach. In Kahneman, D. & Tversky, A. (Eds.), Choices, values and frames (pp. 673–692). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. [28]Google Scholar
Kahneman, D. (2003a). Experiences of collaborative research. American Psychologist, 58, 723–730. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D. (2003b). Maps of bounded reality. American Economic Review, 93(5), 1449–1475. [35]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D. (2003c). A perspective on judgment and choice: Mapping bounded rationality. American Psychologist, 58, 697–720. [24, 31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., Diener, E., & Schwarz, N. (Eds.). (1999). Well-being: The foundations of hedonic psychology. New York: Russell Sage Foundation. [28]Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., & Frederick, S. (2002). Representativeness revisited: Attribute substitution in intuitive judgment. In Gilovich, T., Griffin, D., & Kahneman, D. (Eds.), Heuristics of intuitive judgment: Extensions and applications (pp. 49–81). New York: Cambridge University Press. [32, 38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., Fredrickson, B. L., Schreiber, C. A., & Redelmeier, D. (1993). When more pain is preferred to less: Adding a better end. Psychological Science, 4, 401–405. [9, 27, 29, 31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., & Knetsch, J. L. (1992). Valuing public goods: The purchase of moral satisfaction. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 22, 57–70. [1, 13, 20, 31, 32, 33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., & Knetsch, J. L. (1993). Anchoring or shallow inferences: The effect of format. University of California, Berkeley. [13]Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., & Thaler, R. H. (1986). Fairness and the assumptions of economics. Journal of Business, 59, 285–300. [28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., & Thaler, R. H. (1990). Experimental tests of the endowment effect and the Coase theorem. Journal of Political Economy, 98, 1325–1348. [1, 9, 19, 27, 33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., & Thaler, R. H. (1991). Anomalies: The endowment effect, loss aversion, and status quo bias. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1), 193–206. [27, 31, 38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., & Lovallo, D. (1993). Timid choices and bold forecasts: A cognitive perspective on risk taking. Management Science, 39, 17–31. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., & Miller, D. T. (1986). Norm theory: Comparing reality with its alternatives. Psychological Review, 93, 136–153. [9, 13, 31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., & Ritov, I. (1994). Determinants of stated willingness to pay for public goods: A study in the headline method. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 9, 5–38. [9, 13, 20, 23, 31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., Ritov, I., & Schkade, D. (1999). Economic preferences or attitude expressions? An analysis of dollar responses to public issues. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 19, 203–235. [1, 9, 13, 14, 28, 31, 32, 34, 35]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., Schkade, D., Ritov, I., & Sunstein, C. R. (1999). Reversals of judgement: The effect of cross-category comparisons on intendedly absolute scales. Unpublished manuscript. [31]
Kahneman, D., Schkade, D., & Sunstein, C. R. (1998). Shared outrage and erratic awards: The psychology of punitive damages. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 16, 49–86. [13, 23, 24, 29, 31, 34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., Slovic, P., & Tversky, A. (Eds.). (1982). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. New York: Cambridge University Press. [1, 23, 33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., & Snell, J. (1990). Predicting utility. In Hogarth, R. M. (Ed.), Insights in decision making: A tribute to Hillel J. Einhorn (pp. 295–311). Chicago: University of Chicago Press. [1, 9, 21, 27, 28, 29]Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., & Snell, J. (1992). Predicting a change in taste. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 5, 187–200. [9, 19, 23, 27, 28, 29, 30]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1972). Subjective probability: A judgment of representativeness. Cognitive Psychology, 3, 430–454. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1973). On the psychology of prediction. Psychological Review, 80, 237–251. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47, 263–291. [1, 8, 17, 18, 19, 20, 21, 22, 27, 28, 32, 35, 36]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1982). The simulation heuristic. In Kahneman, D., Slovic, P., & Tversky, A. (Eds.), Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases (pp. 509–520). New York: Cambridge University Press. [28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1984). Choices, values, and frames. American Psychologist, 39, 341–350. [1, 6, 17]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (Eds.). (2000). Choices, values, and frames. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. [36, 37]Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., & Varey, C. A. (1991). Notes on the psychology of utility. In Roemer, J. & Elster, J. (Eds.), Interpersonal comparisons of well-being (pp. 127–163). New York: Cambridge University Press. [27]Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., Wakker, P. P., & Sarin, R. (1997). Back to Bentham? Explorations of experienced utility. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 375–405. [13, 20, 28, 31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kant, I. (1785/1959). Foundations of the metaphysics of morals. New York: Bobbs-Merrill. [18]Google Scholar
Karni, E., & Safra, Z. (1987). “Preference reversal” and the observability of preferences by experimental methods. Econometrica, 55, 675–685. [1, 8]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keeney, R. L. (1980). Siting energy facilities. New York: Academic. [33]Google Scholar
Keeney, R. L. (1982). Decision analysis: An overview. Operations Research, 30, 803–838. [33]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Keeney, R. L. (1984). Ethics, decision analysis, and public risk. Risk Analysis, 4, 117–129. [36]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keeney, R. L. (1992). Value-focused thinking: A path to creative decisionmaking. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University. [19, 34, 35]Google Scholar
Keeney, R. L. (1996). Valuing billions of dollars. In Zeckhauser, R. J., Keeney, R. L., & Sebenius, J. K. (Eds.), Wise choices: Decisions, games, and negotiations (pp. 63–80). Boston: Harvard Business School Press. [34]Google Scholar
Keeney, R. L., & Raiffa, H. (1976). Decisions with multiple objectives: Preferences and value tradeoffs. New York: Wiley. [12, 33]Google Scholar
Keller, K. (1993). Conceptualizing, measuring, and managing customer-based brand equity. Journal of Marketing, 57, 1–22. [10]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keller, L. R., & Ho, J. L. (1988). Decision problem structuring: Generating options. IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man and Cybernetics, 18, 715–728. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kelley, H. H. (1967). Attribution theory in social psychology. In Levine, D. (Ed.), Nebraska Symposium on Motivation (Vol. 15, pp. 192–240). Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press. [16]Google Scholar
Kelley, H. H. (1973). The process of causal attribution. American Psychologist, 28, 107–128. [16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kemp, M., & Maxwell, C. (1993). Exploring a budget context for contingent valuation. In Hausman, J. A. (Ed.), Contingent valuation: A critical assessment (pp. 217–265). Amsterdam: North-Holland. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keren, G. (1991a). Additional tests of utility theory under unique and repeated conditions. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 4, 297–304. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keren, G. (1991b). Calibration and probability judgments: Conceptualization and methodological issues. Acta Psychologica, 77, 217–273. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keren, G. (1999). The explanatory power of choice bracketing: A commentary on Read et al., “Choice bracketing.”Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 19, 199–200. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keren, G., & Raaijmakers, J. B. (1988). On between-subjects versus within-subjects comparisons in testing utility theory. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 4, 233–247. [13, 14]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keren, G., & Wagenaar, W. A. (1987). Violation of utility theory in unique and repeated gambles. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 13, 387–391. [19, 20]Google Scholar
Keselman, H. J., Lix, L. M., & Kowalchuk, R. K. (1998). Multiple comparison procedures for trimmed means. Psychological Methods, 3, 123–141. [15]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kiesler, C. A. (1966). Conflict and number of choice alternatives. Psychological Reports, 18, 603–610. [16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kiesler, C. A. (1971). The psychology of commitment: Experiments linking behavior to belief. New York: Academic Press. [12]Google Scholar
Kilka, M., & Weber, M. (2001). What determines the shape of the probability weighting function?Management Science, 47, 1712–1726. [32]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim-Prieto, C., Diener, E., Tamir, M., Scollon, C., & Diener, M. (2005). Integrating the diverse definitions of happiness: A timesequential framework of subjective wellbeing. Journal of Happiness Studies, 6, 261–300. [28]
Kirby, K. N. (1997). Bidding on the future: Evidence against normative discounting of delayed rewards. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 126, 54–70. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klassen, A. C., & Klassen, D. K. (1996). Who are the donors in organ donation? The family's perspective in mandated choice. Annals of Internal Medicine, 125, 70–73. [37]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Klayman, J., & Brown, K. (1993). Debias the environment instead of the judge: An alternative approach to improving diagnostic (and other) judgment. Cognition, 49, 97–122. [29]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Klein, G. A. (1989). Recognition-primed decisions. In Rouse, W. B. (Ed.), Advances in man-machine system research (Vol. 5, pp. 47–92). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press. [19]Google Scholar
Klein, G. A. (1993a). A recognition primed decision (RPD) model of rapid decision making. In Klein, G. A., Orasanu, J., Calderwood, R., & Zsambok, C. E. (Eds.), Decision making in action: Models and methods (pp. 138–147). Norwood, NJ: Ablex. [18]Google Scholar
Klein, G. A. (1993b). Twenty questions: Suggestions for research in naturalistic decision making. In Klein, G. A., Orasanu, J., Calderwood, R., & Zsambok, C. E. (Eds.), Decision making in action: Models and methods (pp. 389–403). Norwood, NJ: Ablex. [18]Google Scholar
Klein, G. A., Orasanu, J., Calderwood, R., & Zsambok, C. E. (Eds.). (1993). Decision making in action: Models and methods. Norwood, NJ: Ablex. [18, 21]Google Scholar
Kleindorfer, P. R., Kunreuther, H. C., & Schoemaker, P. J. H. (1993). Decision sciences: An integrative perspective. New York: Cambridge University Press. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kleinmuntz, B. (1963). Profile analysis revisited: A heuristic approach. Journal of Counseling Psychology, 70, 315–324. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kleinmuntz, D. N. (1990). Decomposition and the control of error in decision-analytic models. In Hogarth, R. M. (Ed.), Insights in decision making: A tribute to Hillel J. Einhorn (pp. 107–126). Chicago: University of Chicago Press. [34]Google Scholar
Kleinmuntz, D. N., & Schkade, D. A. (1993). Information displays and decision processes. Psychological Science, 4, 221–227. [28, 34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knetsch, J. L., & Sinden, J. A. (1984). Willingness to pay and compensation demanded: Experimental evidence of an unexpected disparity in measures of value. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 99, 507–521. [9, 33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knez, M., & Smith, V. L. (1991). Hypothetical valuations and preference reversals in the context of asset trading. In Smith, V. L. (Ed.), Papers in experimental economics (pp. 315–338). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. [8]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koehler, J. (1996). The base-rate fallacy reconsidered: Descriptive, normative, and methodological challenges. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 19, 1–53. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kopp, R., Portney, P., & Smith, V. K. (1990). Natural resource damages: The economics have shifted after Ohio v. United States Department of the Interior. Environmental Law Reporter, 4, 10127–10131. [33]Google Scholar
Koriat, A., Lichtenstein, S., & Fischhoff, B. (1980). Reasons for confidence. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Learning and Memory, 6, 107–118. [21, 26]Google Scholar
Korobkin, R. (1998). The status quo bias and contract default rules. Cornell Law Review, 83, 608–687. [38]Google Scholar
Krantz, D. H. (1991). From indices to mappings: The representational approach to measurement. In Brown, D. R. & Smith, J. E. K. (Eds.), Frontiers of mathematical psychology (pp. 1–52). New York: Springer-Verlag. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krantz, D. H., Luce, R. D., Suppes, P., & Tversky, A. (1971). Foundations of measurement (Vol. 1). New York: Academic Press. [6]Google Scholar
Kray, L. (2000). Contingent weighting in self-other decision making. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 83, 82–106. [29]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kray, L., & Gonzales, R. (1999). Differential weighting in decision versus advice: I'll do this, you do that. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 12, 207–217. [29]3.0.CO;2-P>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreuger, J., & Rothbart, M. (1990). Contrast and accentuation effects in category learning. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 59, 651–663. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krosnick, J. A., & Schuman, H. (1988). Attitude intensity, importance, and certainty and susceptibility to response effects. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 54, 940–952. [34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krueger, A. B., & Summers, L. H. (1988). Efficiency wages and inter-industry wage structure. Econometrica, 56, 259–293. [13]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kudajie-Gyambi, E., & Rachlin, H. (1996). Temporal patterning choice among delayed outcomes. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 65, 61–67. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuhl, J. (1992). A theory of self-regulation: Action versus state orientation, self-discrimination, and some applications. Applied Psychology: An International Review, 41, 97–129. [18]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuhl, J., & Beckmann, J. (1994). Volition and personality: Action versus state orientation. Seattle, WA: Hogrefe and Huber. [19]Google Scholar
Kunda, Z. (1990). The case for motivated reasoning. Psychological Bulletin, 108, 480–498. [17, 19, 29]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kunreuther, H. (1996). Mitigating disaster losses through insurance. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 12, 171–187. [38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kunreuther, H., & Hogarth, R. (1993, August). Decision making under ignorance: Arguing with yourself (Center for Decision Research Report). University of Chicago, Graduate School of Business. [19]Google Scholar
France, M., & Hecht, M. A. (1995). Why smiles generate leniency. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 21, 207–214. [23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laibson, D. (1994). Hyperbolic discounting and consumption. Unpublished doctoral dissertation, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge. [20]
Laibson, D. (1997). Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 443–477. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laibson, D. (1999). Commentary on “Choice bracketing” by Read, Loewenstein and Rabin. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 19, 201–202. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lancaster, K. (1966). A new approach to consumer theory. Journal of Political Economy, 74, 132–157. [33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Langer, E. J. (1975). The illusion of control. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 32, 311–328. [16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Langer, E. J. (1978). Rethinking the role of thought in social interaction. In Harvey, J. H., Ickes, W. J., & Kidd, R. F. (Eds.), New directions in attribution research (Vol. 2, pp. 35–58). Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [26]Google Scholar
Langer, E. J. (1989). Minding matters: The consequences of mindlessness-mindfulness. In Berkowitz, L. (Ed.), Advances in experimental social psychology (Vol. 22, pp. 137–173). San Diego, CA: Academic Press. [26]Google Scholar
Langer, E. J., & Rodin, J. (1976). The effects of choice and enhanced personal responsibility for the aged: A field experiment in an institutional setting. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 34, 191–198. [16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lazarus, R. S. (1982). Thoughts on the relations between emotion and cognition. American Psychologist, 46, 352–367. [25]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
LeDoux, J. E. (1996). The emotional brain: The mysterious underpinnings of emotional life. New York: Simon & Schuster. [1, 25]Google Scholar
Lefcourt, H. M. (1973). The function of the illusions of control and freedom. American Psychologist, 28, 417–425. [16]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Legrenzi, P., Girotto, V., & Johnson-Laird, P. N. (1993). Focusing in reasoning and decision making. Cognition, 49, 37–66. [9, 17, 34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lehman, D. R., Davis, C. G., Delongis, A., Wortman, C. B., Bluck, S., Mandel, D. R., et al. (1993). Positive and negative life changes following bereavement and their relations to adjustment. Journal of Social and Clinical Psychology, 12, 90–112. [30]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lepper, M. R. (1983). Social control processes and the internalization of social values: An attributional perspective. In Higgins, E. T., Ruble, D. N., & Hartup, W. W. (Eds.), Social cognition and social development (pp. 294–330). New York: Cambridge University Press. [16]Google Scholar
Lerner, J. S., Gonzalez, R. M., Small, D. A., & Fischhoff, B. (2003). Effects of fear and anger on perceived risks of terrorism: A national field experiment. Psychological Science, 14, 144–150. [24]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lerner, J. S., & Keltner, D. (2000). Beyond valence: Toward a model of emotion-specific influences on judgment and choice. Cognition & Emotion, 14, 473–493. [24]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lerner, J. S., Small, D. A., & Loewenstein, G. (2004). Heart strings and purse strings: Carryover effects of emotions on economic decisions. Psychological Science, 15, 337–341. [21, 24]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lerner, J. S., & Tetlock, P. E. (1999). Accounting for the effects of accountability. Psychological Bulletin, 125, 255–275. [29]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Levav, J. (1996). Questioning contingent valuation: Maximality and violations of monotonicity in willingness-to-pay for public goods. Unpublished undergraduate thesis, Princeton University, Princeton, NJ. [31]
Levin, I. P. (1999, November). Why do you and I make different decisions? Tracking individual differences in decision making. Presidential address to the Society for Judgment and Decision Making, Los Angeles, CA. [1]
Levin, I. P., & Gaeth, G. J. (1988). How consumers are affected by the framing of attribute information before and after consuming the product. Journal of Consumer Research, 15, 374–378. [17, 21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levin, I. P., & Hart, S. S. (2003). Risk preferences in young children: Early evidence of individual differences in reaction to potential gains and losses. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 16, 397–413. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levin, I. P., & Jasper, J. D. (1993, November). Identifying compensatory and non-compensatory processes in phased decision making. Paper presented at the meeting of the Judgment and Decision Making Society, Washington, DC. [19]
Levin, S. J., & Levine, D. S. (1996). Multiattribute decision making in context: A dynamic neural network methodology. Cognitive Science, 20, 271–299. [11]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewicka, M. (1997). Rational or uncommitted? Depression and indecisiveness in interpersonal decision making. Scandinavian Journal of Psychology, 38, 227–236. [18]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lewin, K. (1952). Group decision and social change. In Swanson, G. E., Newcomb, T. M., & Hartley, E. L. (Eds.), Readings in social psychology (pp. 459–473). New York: Henry Holt. [16]Google Scholar
Lewin, K., Dembo, T., Festinger, L. A., & Sears, P. S. (1944). Levels of aspiration. In Hunt, J. M. (Ed.), Personality and behavior disorders (Vol. 1, pp. 333–378). New York: Ronald. [19]Google Scholar
Lichtenstein, S. (1965). Bases for preferences among three-outcome bets. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 69, 162–169. [2, 3]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lichtenstein, S., & Newman, J. R. (1967). Empirical scaling of common verbal phrases associated with numerical probabilities. Psychonomic Science, 9, 563–564. [35]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lichtenstein, S., & Slovic, P. (1971). Reversals of preference between bids and choices in gambling decisions. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 89, 46–55. [1, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9, 10, 11, 12, 18, 21, 29, 33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lichtenstein, S., & Slovic, P. (1973). Response-induced reversals of preference in gambling: An extended replication in Las Vegas. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 101, 16–20. [1, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 11]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lichtenstein, S., Slovic, P., Fischhoff, B., Layman, M., & Combs, B. (1978). Judged frequency of lethal events. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Learning and Memory, 4, 551–578. [23]Google Scholar
Lifton, R. J. (1990). The Nazi doctors: Medical killings and the psychology of genocide. New York: Basic Books. [20]Google Scholar
Lindberg, E., Gärling, T., & Montgomery, H. (1988). People's beliefs and values as determinants of housing preferences and simulated choices. Scandinavian Housing and Planning Research, 5, 181–197. [18]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindberg, E., Gärling, T., & Montgomery, H. (1989a, August). Decision with incompletely described alternatives. Paper presented at the 12th European Research Conference on Subjective Probability, Utility, and Decision Making, Moscow. [18]
Lindberg, E., Gärling, T., & Montgomery, H. (1989b). Differential predictability of preferences and choices. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 2, 205–219. [10, 18]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindberg, E., Gärling, T., & Montgomery, H. (1989c). Belief-value structures as determinants of consumer behavior: A study of housing preferences and choices. Journal of Consumer Policy, 12, 119–137. [18]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindberg, E., Gärling, T., & Montgomery, H. (1990). Intra-urban residential mobility: Subjective belief-value structures as determinants of residential preferences and choices (Umea Psychological Reports, No. 197). Umea, Sweden: Department of Psychology, University of Umea. [18]Google Scholar
Lindecrantz, M. (2001). Individuella skillnader vid beslutsfattande: Beslutsprocesser hos staterespektive actionorienterade individer [Individual differences in decision making: Decision processes in state- versus action-oriented individuals]. Unpublished masters thesis, Stockholm University, Stockholm. [19]
Linder, D. E., Cooper, J., & Jones, E. E. (1967). Decision freedom as a determinant of the role of incentive magnitude in attitude change. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 6, 245–254. [16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindman, H. R. (1965). The measurement of utilities and subjective probabilities. Unpublished doctoral dissertation, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor. [1, 2]
Lindman, H. R. (1971). Inconsistent preferences among gambles. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 89, 390–397. [1, 3, 4, 5, 8, 11]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Linville, P., & Fischer, G. W. (1991). Preferences for separating or combining events. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 60, 5–23. [20]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lipshitz, R. (1993). Converging themes in the study of decision making in realistic settings. In Klein, G. A., Orasanu, J., Calderwood, R., & Zsambok, C. E. (Eds.), Decision making in action: Models and methods (pp. 103–137). Norwood, NJ: Ablex. [18]Google Scholar
Littig, L. W. (1962). Effects of skill and chance orientations on probability preferences. Psychological Reports, 10, 67–70. [2]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lodge, M. (1981). Magnitude scaling: Quantitative measurement of opinions. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G. (1987). Anticipation and the valuation of delayed consumption. Economic Journal, 97, 666–684. [23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G. (1988). Frames of mind in intertemporal choice. Management Science, 34, 200–214. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G. (1996). Out of control: Visceral influences on behavior. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 65, 272–292. [9, 28, 29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G. (2000). How people make decisions: Costs and benefits of health- and retirement-related choice. In Burke, S., Kingson, E., & Reinhardt, U. (Eds.), Social Security and Medicare: Individual versus collective risk and responsibility (pp. 87–113). Washington, DC: National Academy of Social Insurance. [38]Google Scholar
Loewenstein, G., & Adler, D. (1995). A bias in the prediction of tastes. Economic Journal, 105, 929–937. [27]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G., Blount, S., & Bazerman, M. H. (1993). Reversals of preference between independent and simultaneous evaluation of alternatives. Unpublished manuscript, Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh, PA. [9]
Loewenstein, G., & Frederick, S. (1997). Predicting reactions to environmental change. In Bazerman, M., Messick, D., Tenbrunsel, A., & Wade-Benzoni, K. (Eds.), Environment, ethics, and behavior (pp. 52–72). San Francisco: New Lexington Press. [9, 29]Google Scholar
Loewenstein, G., O'Donoghue, T., & Rabin, M. (2003). Projection bias in predicting future utility. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, 1209–1248. [35]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G., & Prelec, D. (1992). Anomalies in intertemporal choice: Evidence and an interpretation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107, 573–597. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G., & Prelec, D. (1993). Preferences for sequences of outcomes. Psychological Review, 100, 91–108. [9, 20, 29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G., & Schkade, D. (1999). Wouldn't it be nice? Predicting future feelings. In Diener, E., Schwartz, N., & Kahneman, D. (Eds.), Well-being: The foundations of hedonic psychology (pp. 85–105). New York: Russell Sage Foundation. [23, 28, 29, 30, 34]Google Scholar
Loewenstein, G., & Sicherman, N. (1991). Do workers prefer increasing wage profiles?Journal of Labor Economics, 9, 67–84. [9, 27]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G., & Thaler, R. H. (1989). Anomalies: Intertemporal choice. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3(4), 181–193. [13]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G., Weber, E. U., Hsee, C. K., & Welch, E. S. (2001). Risk as feelings. Psychological Bulletin, 127, 267–286. [21, 23, 24, 29]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Loftus, E. F., & Pickrell, J. E. (1995). The formation of false memories. Psychiatric Annals, 25, 720–725. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loomes, G., Starmer, C., & Sugden, R. (1989). Preference reversal: Information-processing effect or rational nontransitive choice. Economic Journal, 99, 140–151. [8]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loomes, G., & Sugden, R. (1982). Regret theory: An alternative theory of rational choice under uncertainty. Economic Journal, 92, 805–824. [6, 8, 19, 36]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loomes, G., & Sugden, R. (1983). A rationale for preference reversal. American Economic Review, 73(3), 428–432. [1, 6, 7, 8]Google Scholar
Loomis, J. B., Gonzalez-Caban, A., & Gregory, R. (1994). Do reminders of substitutes and budget constraints influence contingent valuation estimates?Land Economics, 70, 499–506. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loomis, J. B., Hanemann, W. M., Kanninen, B., & Wegge, T. (1991). Willingness to pay to protect wetlands and reduce wildlife contamination from agricultural damage. In Dinar, A. & Zilberman, D. (Eds.), The economics and management of water and drainage in agriculture (pp. 411–429). Boston: Kluwer Academic. [33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loomis, J. B., Lockwood, M., & DeLacy, T. (1993). Some empirical evidence on embedding effects in contingent valuation of forest protection. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 25, 45–55. [33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lopes, L. L. (1981). Decision making in the short run. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Learning and Memory, 7, 377–385. [19, 20]Google Scholar
Lopes, L. L. (1982, December). Toward a procedural theory of judgment (Technical Report No. WHIPP 17). Madison: Wisconsin Human Information Processing Program. [7]Google Scholar
Lopes, L. L. (1996). When time is of the essence: Averaging, aspiration, and the short run. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 65, 179–189. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lord, C. G., Lepper, M. R., & Mackie, D. (1984). Attitude prototypes as determinants of attitude-behavior consistency. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 46, 1254–1266. [30]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lowenthal, D. (1993). Preference reversals in candidate evaluation (Working paper). Pittsburgh, PA: Carnegie Mellon University. [9]Google Scholar
Lucas, R. E. (1986). Adaptive behavior and economic theory. Journal of Business, 59, S401–S426. [17, 34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luce, M. F. (1998). Choosing to avoid: Coping with negatively emotion-laden consumer decisions. Journal of Consumer Research, 24, 409–423. [34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luce, M. F., Payne, J. W., & Bettman, J. R. (1999). Emotional trade-off difficulty and choice. Journal of Marketing Research, 36, 143–159. [17, 29, 34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luce, R. D. (1986). Response times: Their role in inferring elementary mental organization. New York: Oxford University Press. [15]Google Scholar
Lundberg, C. G., & Svenson, O. (2000). Postdecision consolidation in a trend prediction task. Scandinavian Journal of Psychology, 41, 159–168. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lusk, C. M., & Judd, C. M. (1988). Political expertise and the structural mediators of candidate evaluations. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 24, 105–126. [26]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lustig, C., & Hasher, L. (2001). Implicit memory is not immune to interference. Psychological Bulletin, 127, 618–628. [21]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lynch, J. G., Chakravarti, D., & Mitra, A. (1991). Contrast effects in consumer judgments: Changes in mental representations or in the anchoring of rating scales?Journal of Consumer Research, 18, 284–297. [17]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lynch, J. G., Marmorstein, H., & Weigold, M. F. (1988). Choices from sets including remembered brands: Use of recalled attributes and prior overall evaluations. Journal of Consumer Research, 15, 169–184. [10]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacGregor, D. G., & Slovic, P. (1986). Perceived acceptability of risk analysis as a decision-making approach. Risk Analysis, 6, 245–256. [33]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
MacGregor, D. G., Slovic, P., Dreman, D., & Berry, M. (2000). Imagery, affect, and financial judgment. Journal of Psychology and Financial Markets, 1, 104–110. [23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Machina, M. J. (1987). Choice under uncertainty: Problems solved and unsolved. Economic Perspectives, 1, 121–154. [8]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacLean, D. (1994). Cost-benefit analysis and procedural values. Analyse & Kritik, 2, 166–180. [36]Google Scholar
Madrian, B. C., & Shea, D. F. (2001). The power of suggestion: Inertia in 401(k) participation and savings behavior. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116, 1149–1187. [37, 38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malone, T. W., & Lepper, M. R. (1987). Making learning fun: A taxonomy of intrinsic motivations for learning. In Snow, R. E. & Farr, M. J. (Eds.), Aptitude, learning and instruction: Vol. 3. Conative and affective process analysis (pp. 223–253). Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [16]Google Scholar
Mandel, N., & Johnson, E. J. (2002). When Web pages influence choice: Effects of visual primes on experts and novices. Journal of Consumer Research, 29, 235–245. [1, 15, 21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mann, L., Janis, I. L., & Chaplin, R. (1969). The effects of anticipation of forthcoming information on predecisional processes. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 11, 10–16. [18]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
March, J. (1978). Bounded rationality, ambiguity, and the rationality of choice. Bell Journal of Economics, 9, 587–608. [1, 6, 9, 17, 27, 29, 34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
March, J. (1994). A primer on decision making: How decisions happen. New York: The Free Press. [28, 29]Google Scholar
Marder, E. (1997). The laws of choice. New York: The Free Press. [34]Google Scholar
Markman, A. B., & Medin, D. L. (1995). Similarity and alignment in choice. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 63, 117–130. [10]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Markman, A. B., Zhang, S., & Moreau, C. P. (2000). Representation and the construction of preferences. In Dietrich, E. & Markman, A. (Eds.), Cognitive dynamics: Conceptual and representational change in humans and machines (pp. 343–365). Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [12]Google Scholar
Markman, K. D., & Hirt, E. R. (2002). Social prediction and the allegiance bias. Social Cognition, 20, 58–86. [28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Markowitz, H. (1952). The utility of wealth. Journal of Political Economy, 60, 151–158. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marsh, H. W. (1984). Students' evaluations of university teaching: Dimensionality, reliability, validity, potential biases, and utility. Journal of Educational Psychology, 76, 707–754. [9]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martin, L. L., & Tesser, A. (Eds.). (1992). The construction of social judgments. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [1]Google Scholar
Martin, L. M. (1986). Set/reset: Use and disuse of concepts in impression formation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 51, 493–504. [15]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
May, K. O. (1954). Intransitivity, utility, and the aggregation of preference patterns. Econometrica, 22, 1–3. [1, 9, 19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McClure, S. M., Li, J., Tomlin, D., Cypert, K. S., Montague, L. M., & Montague, R. P. (2004). Neural correlates of behavioral preference for culturally familiar drinks. Neuron, 44, 379–387. [1]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
McFadden, D. (1994). Contingent valuation and social choice. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 76, 689–703. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McFadden, D. (1999). Rationality for economists. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 19, 73–106. [17, 34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McFadden, D., & Leonard, G. (1993). Issues in The contingent valuation of environmental goods: Methodologies for data collection and analysis. In Hausman, J. A. (Ed.), Contingent valuation: A critical assessment (pp. 165–208). Amsterdam: North-Holland. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McGuire, W. J. (1969). Suspiciousness of experimenter's intent. In Rosenthal, R. & Rosnow, R. L. (Eds.), Artifact in behavioral research (pp. 13–57). New York: Academic Press. [35]Google Scholar
McKenzie, C. R. M., & Nelson, J. D. (2003). What a speaker's choice of frame reveals: Reference points, frame selection, and framing effects. Psychonomic Bulletin and Review, 10, 596–602. [21]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
McKoon, G., & Ratcliff, R. (1995). Conceptual combinations and relational contexts in free association and in priming in lexical decision and naming. Psychonomic Bulletin and Review, 2, 527–533. [15]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
McLanahan, S. S., & Sorensen, A. B. (1984). Life events and psychological well-being: A reexamination of theoretical and methodological issues. Social Science Research, 13, 111–128. [28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McNamara, T. P. (1992). Priming and constraints it places on theories of memory and retrieval. Psychological Review, 99, 650–662. [15]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McNeil, B. J., Pauker, S. G., Sox, H. C. Jr., & Tversky, A. (1982). On the elicitation of preferences for alternative therapies. New England Journal of Medicine, 306, 1259–1262. [1]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mellers, B. A., Chang, S., Birnbaum, M. H., & Ordóñez, L. D. (1992). Preferences, prices, and ratings in risky decision making. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance, 18, 347–361. [9, 10, 28]Google Scholar
Mellers, B. A., & Cooke, A. D. J. (1994). Trade-offs depend on attribute range. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance, 20, 1055–1067. [9]Google Scholar
Mellers, B. A., & Cooke, A. D. J. (1996). The role of task and context in preference measurement. Psychological Science, 7, 76–82. [10]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mellers, B. A., Ordóñez, L., & Birnbaum, M. H. (1992). A change-of-process theory for contextual effects and preference reversals in risky decision making. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 52, 331–369. [1, 9]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mellers, B. A., Richards, V., & Birnbaum, M. H. (1992). Distributional theories of impression formation. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 51, 313–343. [23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mellers, B. A., Schwartz, A., & Cooke, A. D. J. (1998). Judgment and decision making. Annual Review of Psychology, 49, 447–477. [17]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mellers, B. A., Schwartz, A., Ho, K., & Ritov, I. (1997). Elation and disappointment: Emotional reactions to risky options. Psychological Science, 8, 423–429. [24, 29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mellers, B. A., Schwartz, A., & Ritov, I. (1999). Emotion-based choice. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 128, 332–345. [29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Merkhofer, M. W., & Keeney, R. L. (1987). A multiattribute utility analysis of alternative sites for the disposal of nuclear waste. Risk Analysis, 7, 173–194. [33]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Middleton, F. A., & Strick, P. L. (2000). A revised neuroanatomy of frontal-subcortical circuits. In Lichter, D. G. & Cummings, J. L. (Eds.), Frontal-subcortical circuits in psychiatric and neurological disorders (pp. 44–58). New York: Guilford Press. [11]Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. (1974). On liberty. London: Penguin. [38]Google Scholar
Millar, M. G., & Tesser, A. (1986). Effects of affective and cognitive focus on the attitude-behavior relationship. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 51, 270–276. [26]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Millar, M. G., & Tesser, A. (1989). The effects of affective-cognitive consistency and thought on the attitude-behavior relation. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 25, 189–202. [26]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, G. A. (1956). The magical number seven, plus or minus two: Some limits on our capacity for processing information. Psychological Review, 63, 81–97. [19, 20]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Miller, J. G. (1961). Sensory overloading. In Flaherty, B. E. (Ed.), Psychophysiological aspects of space flight (pp. 215–237). New York: Columbia University Press. [2]Google Scholar
Miller, L., & Meyer, D. E. (1966). Decision effectiveness as a function of the structure and number of alternatives at a choice point. Proceedings of the 74th Annual Convention of the American Psychological Association, 1, 25–26. [2]Google Scholar
Milliken, B., Joordens, S., Merikle, P. M., & Seiffert, A. E. (1998). Selective attention: A reevaluation of the implications of negative priming. Psychological Review, 105, 203–229. [21]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mills, J., Meltzer, R., & Clark, M. (1977). Effect of number of options on recall of information supporting different decision strategies. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 3, 213–218. [16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mintzberg, H., Raisinghani, D., & Thoret, A. (1976). The structure of unstructured decisions. Administrative Science Quarterly, 21, 246–275. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitchell, R. C., & Carson, R. T. (1989). Using surveys to value public goods: The contingent valuation method. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future. [31, 33, 34]Google Scholar
Monahan, J. L., Murphy, S. T., & Zajonc, R. B. (2000). Subliminal mere exposure: Specific, general, and diffuse effects. Psychological Science, 11, 462–466. [25]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Montague, R. P. (2002, October). Neural economics and the biological substrates of valuation [Lecture notes]. Paper presented at the University of California Conference on Recent Research in Behavioral Finance, Monterey, CA. [1]
Montague, R. P., & Berns, G. S. (2002). Neural economics and the biological substrates of valuation. Neuron, 36, 265–284. [1, 24]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Montgomery, H. (1983). Decision rules and the search for a dominance structure: Towards a process model of decision making. In Humphreys, P. C., Svenson, O., & Vari, A. (Eds.), Analysing and aiding decision processes (pp. 343–369). Amsterdam/Budapest: North-Holland and Hungarian Academic Press. [1, 6, 12, 18, 19, 22, 23]Google Scholar
Montgomery, H. (1989). From cognition to action: The search for dominance in decision making. In Montgomery, H. & Svenson, O. (Eds.), Process and structure in human decision making (pp. 23–49). Chichester, England: Wiley. [18]Google Scholar
Montgomery, H. (1993). The choice of a home seen from the inside: Psychological contributions to the study of decision making in housing markets. In Gärling, T. & Golledge, R. G. (Eds.), Behavior and environment (pp. 317–341). Amsterdam: Elsevier. [18]Google Scholar
Montgomery, H. (1994). Towards a perspective theory of decision making and judgment. Acta Psychologica, 87, 155–187. [18, 19]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Montgomery, H. (1997). Surrender at Perevolochna: A case study of perspective and action control in decision making under stress. In Flin, R., Salas, E., Strub, M., & Martin, L. (Eds.), Decision making under stress: Emerging themes and applications (pp. 193–204). Aldershot, England: Ashgate. [18]Google Scholar
Montgomery, H. (1998). Decision making and action: The search for a dominance structure. In Kofta, M., Weary, G., & Sedek, G. (Eds.), Personal control in action: Cognitive and motivational mechanisms (pp. 279–298). New York: Plenum. [1, 18]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Montgomery, H., Gärling, T., Lindberg, E., & Selart, M. (1990). Preference judgments and choice: Is the prominence effect due to information integration or to information evaluation? In Borcherding, K., Larichev, O. I., & Messick, D. (Eds.), Contemporary issues in decision making (pp. 149–157). Amsterdam: North-Holland. [18]Google Scholar
Montgomery, H., & Hemlin, S. (1991). Judging scientific quality: A cross-disciplinary investigation of professorial evaluation documents (Göteborg Psychological Reports, Vol. 21, No. 4). Göteborg, Sweden: University of Göteborg, Department of Psychology. [18]Google Scholar
Montgomery, H., Selart, M., Gärling, T., & Lindberg, E. (1994). The judgment-choice discrepancy: Noncompatibility or restructuring?Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 7, 145–155. [10, 18]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Montgomery, H., & Svenson, O. (1989). A think aloud study of dominance structuring in decision processes. In Montgomery, H. & Svenson, O. (Eds.), Process and structure in human decision making (pp. 135–150). Chichester, UK: Wiley. [18, 19]Google Scholar
Moore, D. (1999). Order effects in preference judgments: Evidence for context dependence in the generation of preferences. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 78, 146–165. [28]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Morewedge, C. K., Gilbert, D. T., & Wilson, T. D. (2005). The least likely of times: How remembering the past biases forecasts of the future. Psychological Science, 16, 626–630. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morgan, M. G., Fischhoff, B., Bostrom, A., & Atman, C. J. (2002). Risk communication: A mental models approach. New York: Cambridge University Press. [35]Google Scholar
Morrison, E. R. (1998). Judicial review of discount rates used in regulatory cost-benefit analysis. The University of Chicago Law Review, 65, 1333–1359. [38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morrow, J., & Nolan-Hoeksema, S. (1990). Effects of responses to depression on the remediation of depressive affect. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 58, 519–527. [26]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Morwitz, V. G. (1997). Why consumers don't always accurately predict their own future behavior. Marketing Letters, 8, 57–60. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morwitz, V. G., Johnson, E. J., & Schmittlein, D. (1993). Does measuring intent change behavior?Journal of Consumer Research, 20, 46–61. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morwitz, V. G., & Pluzinski, C. (1996). Do polls reflect opinions or do opinions reflect polls? The impact of political polling on voters' expectations, preferences, and behavior. Journal of Consumer Research, 23, 53–67. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mowen, J. C., & Gentry, J. W. (1980). Investigation of the preference-reversal phenomenon in a new product introduction task. Journal of Applied Psychology, 65, 715–722. [1, 8]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mowrer, O. H. (1960a). Learning theory and behavior. New York: John Wiley & Sons. [23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mowrer, O. H. (1960b). Learning theory and the symbolic processes. New York: John Wiley & Sons. [23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murphy, S. T., Monahan, J. L., & Zajonc, R. B. (1995). Additivity of nonconscious affect: Combined effects of priming and exposure. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 69, 589–602. [25]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Murray, K. B., & Häubl, G. (2005). Processes of preference construction in agent-assisted online shopping. In Haugtvedt, C., Machleit, K., & Yalch, R. (Eds.), Online consumer psychology: Understanding and influencing consumer behavior in the virtual world (pp. 265–286). Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [1]Google Scholar
Mussweiler, T., & Strack, F. (2001a). Considering the impossible: Explaining the effects of implausible anchors. Social Cognition, 19, 145–160. [13]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mussweiler, T., & Strack, F. (2001b). The semantics of anchoring. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 86, 234–255. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mussweiler, T., Strack, F., & Pfeiffer, T. (2000). Overcoming the inevitable anchoring effect: Considering the opposite compensates for selective accessibility. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 26, 1142–1150. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myers, D. G. (1993). The pursuit of happiness: Who is happy and why?New York: Avon Books. [28]Google Scholar
National Institute of Diabetes and Digestive and Kidney Diseases. (2001). Understanding adult obesity. Retrieved May 4, 2005, from http://win.niddk.nih.gov/publications/understanding.htm. [38]
Neill, H. (1995). The context for substitutes in CVM studies: Some empirical observations. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 29, 393–397. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neisser, U. (1967). Cognitive psychology. New York: Appleton-Century-Crofts. [1]Google Scholar
Nelson, P. (1970). Information and consumer behavior. Journal of Political Economy, 78, 331–329. [10]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nickerson, C. (1995). Does willingness-to-pay reflect the purchase of moral satisfaction? A reconsideration of Kahneman and Knetsch. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 28, 126–133. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nicosia, F. M. (1966). Consumer decision processes: Marketing and advertising implications. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. [17]Google Scholar
Nisbett, R., & Ross, L. (1980). Human inference: Strategies and shortcomings of social judgment. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. [1]Google Scholar
Nisbett, R. E., & Wilson, T. D. (1977). Telling more than we can know: Verbal reports on mental processes. Psychological Review, 84, 231–259. [22, 26]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nogee, P., & Lieberman, B. (1960). The auction value of certain risky situations. Journal of Psychology, 49, 167–179. [2]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norman, D. A. (1988). The psychology of everyday things. New York: Basic Books. [34]Google Scholar
North, A. C., Hargreaves, D. J., & McKendrick, J. (1999). The influence of in-store music on wine selections. Journal of Applied Psychology, 84, 271–276. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norwick, R. J., Gilbert, D. T., & Wilson, T. D. (2005). Surrogation: An antidote for errors in affective forecasting. Unpublished manuscript, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA. [1]
Novemsky, N., & Kronzon, S. (1999). How are base-rates used, when they are used: A comparison of additive and Bayesian models of base-rate use. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 12, 55–69. [31]3.0.CO;2-M>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Novemsky, N., & Ratner, R. K. (2003). The time course and impact of consumers' erroneous beliefs about hedonic contrast effects. Journal of Consumer Research, 29, 507–516. [28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nowlis, S. M., & Simonson, I. (1994). The context-dependency of attributes as a determinant of preference reversals between choices and judgments of purchase likelihood (Working paper). Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University. [9, 10]Google Scholar
Nowlis, S. M., & Simonson, I. (1997). Attribute-task compatability as a determinant of consumer preference reversals. Journal of Marketing Research, 34, 205–218. [1, 9, 10, 20, 28, 29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nutt, P. C. (1998). How decision makers evaluate alternatives and the influence of complexity. Management Science, 44, 1148–1166. [34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Curry, S. (1995). Income source effects (Working paper). Chicago: DePaul University, Department of Marketing. [20]Google Scholar
O'Donoghue, E., & Rabin, M. (1997). Incentives for procrastinators (Working paper). University of California, Berkeley, Department of Economics. [20]Google Scholar
O'Donoghue, E., & Rabin, M. (1999). Doing it now or later. American Economic Review, 89(1), 103–124. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Okin, S. M. (1989). Justice, gender, and the family. New York: Basic. [38]Google Scholar
Orasanu, J., & Connoly, T. (1993). The reinvention of decision making. In Klein, G. A., Orasanu, J., Calderwood, R., & Zsambok, C. E. (Eds.), Decision making in action: Models and methods (pp. 3–20). Norwood, NJ: Ablex. [18]Google Scholar
Osgood, C. E., Suci, G. J., & Tannenbaum, P. H. (1957). The measurement of meaning. Urbana: University of Illinois. [23, 31]Google Scholar
Osnos, E. (1997, September 27). Too many choices? Firms cut back on new products. Philadelphia Inquirer, D1, D7. [16]Google Scholar
Oz, M. C., Kherani, A. R., Rowe, A., Roels, L., Crandall, C., Tournatis, L., et al. (2003). How to improve organ donation: Results of the ISHLT/FACT poll. Journal of Heart and Lung Transplantation, 22, 389–396. [37]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Pachella, R. G. (1974). The interpretation of reaction time in information processing research. In Kantowitz, B. H. (Ed.), Human information processing: Tutorials in performance and cognition (pp. 41–82). Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [15]Google Scholar
Papandreou, A. G. (1953). An experimental test of an axiom in the theory of choice. Econometrica, 21, 477. [19]Google Scholar
Parfit, D. (1984). Reasons and persons. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. [27]Google Scholar
Parker, A. M., & Fischhoff, B. (2005). Decision-making competence: External validation through an individual-differences approach. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 18, 1–27. [1, 35]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patrick, C. J. (1994). Emotion and psychopathy: Startling new insights. Psychophysiology, 31, 319–330. [23]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Payne, J. W. (1976). Task complexity and contingent processing in decision making: An information search and protocol analysis. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 16, 366–387. [7, 17, 19, 34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Payne, J. W. (1982). Contingent decision behavior. Psychological Bulletin, 92, 382–401. [6, 10, 16, 17, 19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Payne, J. W., Bettman, J. R., & Johnson, E. J. (1988). Adaptive strategy selection in decision making. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 14, 534–552. [1, 16, 34]Google Scholar
Payne, J. W., Bettman, J. R., & Johnson, E. J. (1990). The adaptive decision maker: Effort and accuracy in choice. In Hogarth, R. M. (Ed.), Insights in decision making: A tribute to Hillel J. Einhorn (pp. 129–153). Chicago: University of Chicago Press. [21]Google Scholar
Payne, J. W., Bettman, J. R., & Johnson, E. J. (1992). Behavioral decision research: A constructive processing perspective. Annual Review of Psychology, 43, 87–131. [1, 9, 10, 12, 17, 19, 21, 22, 31, 33, 34, 37]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Payne, J. W., Bettman, J. R., & Johnson, E. J. (1993). The adaptive decision maker. New York: Cambridge University Press. [11, 13, 15, 16, 17, 19, 23, 34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Payne, J. W., Bettman, J. R., & Schkade, D. A. (1999). Measuring constructed preferences: Towards a building code. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 19, 243–270. [1, 17, 24, 31, 34, 35, 38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Payne, J. W., & Braunstein, M. L. (1978). Risky choice: An examination of information acquisition behavior. Memory & Cognition, 5, 554–561. [7]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Payne, J. W., Braunstein, M. L., & Carroll, J. S. (1978). Exploring predecisional behavior: An alternative approach to decision research. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 22, 17–44. [7]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Payne, J. W., Schkade, D. A., Desvousges, W. H., & Aultman, C. (2000). Valuation of multiple environmental programs. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 21, 95–115. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pennington, N., & Hastie, R. (1988). Explanation-based decision making: Effects of memory structure on judgment. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 14, 521–533. [22]Google Scholar
Pennington, N., & Hastie, R. (1992). Explaining the evidence: Tests of the story model for juror decision making. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 62, 189–206. [22]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pennington, N., & Hastie, R. (1993a). Reasoning in explanation-based decision making. Cognition, 49, 123–163. [18]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pennington, N., & Hastie, R. (1993b). A theory of explanation-based decision making. In Klein, G., Orasano, J., Calderwood, R., & Zsambok, C. E. (Eds.), Decision making in action: Models and methods (pp. 188–204). Norwood, NJ: Ablex. [23]Google Scholar
Peters, E., & Slovic, P. (1996). The role of affect and worldviews as orienting dispositions in the perception and acceptance of nuclear power. Journal of Applied Social Psychology, 26, 1427–1453. [23, 24]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peters, E., & Slovic, P. (2000). The springs of action: Affective and analytical information processing in choice. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 26, 1465–1475. [1, 23, 24]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peters, E., & Slovic, P. (2006). Affective asynchrony and development of the HUE affect scale. (Report No. 06-04). Eugene, OR: Decision Research. [24]
Peters, E., Slovic, P., & Gregory, R. (2003). The role of affect in the WTA/WTP disparity. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 16, 309–330. [24]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peters, E., Slovic, P., & Hibbard, J. (2004). Evaluability manipulations influence the construction of choices among health plans. (Report No. 04-02). Eugene, OR: Decision Research. [24]
Peters, E., Slovic, P., Hibbard, J., & Tusler, M. (2006). Why worry? Worry, risk perceptions, and willingness to act to reduce errors. Health Psychology, 25, 144–152. [24]
Peters, E., Västfjäll, D., & Starmer, C. (2006). Feeling your way to the right price. (Report No. 06-05). Eugene, OR: Decision Research. [24]
Pham, M. T. (1998). Representativeness, relevance, and the use of feelings in decision making. Journal of Consumer Research, 25, 144–159. [23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phillips, C., & Zeckhauser, R. (1989). Contingent valuation of damage to natural resources: How accurate? How appropriate?Toxics Law Reporter, 4, 520–529. [33]Google Scholar
Phillips, F. (2002). The distortion of criteria after decision-making. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 88, 769–784. [12, 19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phillips, L. D. (1984). A theory of requisite decision models. Acta Psychologica, 56, 29–48. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phillips, L. D., & Edwards, W. (1966). Conservatism in a simple probability inference task. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 72, 346–354. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pidgeon, N., & Gregory, R. (2004). Judgment, decision making, and public policy. In Koehler, D. J. & Harvey, N. (Eds.), Blackwell handbook of judgment and decision making (pp. 604–623). Oxford: Blackwell. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Plott, C. R. (1996). Rational individual behavior in markets and social choice processes: The discovered preference hypothesis. In Arrow, K. J., Colombatto, C., Perleman, M., & Schmidt, C. (Eds.), The rational foundations of economic behavior (pp. 225–250). New York: St. Martin's. [1, 17, 34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Plous, S. (1993). The psychology of judgment and decision making. New York: McGraw-Hill. [35]Google Scholar
Pommerehne, W. W., Schneider, F., & Zweifel, P. (1982). Economic theory of choice and the preference reversal phenomenon: A reexamination. American Economic Review, 72(3), 569–574. [8]Google Scholar
Posovac, S. S., Sanbonmatsu, D. M., & Fazio, R. H. (1997). Considering the best choice: Effects of the salience and accessibility of alternatives on attitude-decision consistency. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 72, 253–261. [34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Postman, L., & Underwood, B. J. (1973). Critical issues in interference theory. Memory & Cognition, 1, 19–40. [21]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Poulton, E. C. (1989). Bias in quantifying judgment. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [35]Google Scholar
Pratkanis, A. (1989). The cognitive representation of attitudes. In Pratkanis, A., Breckler, S. J., & Greenwald, A. G. (Eds.), Attitude structure and function (pp. 71–98). Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [23]Google Scholar
Pratto, F. (1994). Consciousness and automatic evaluation. In Niedenthal, P. M. & Kitayama, S. (Eds.), The heart's eye: Emotional influences in perception and attention (pp. 115–143). San Diego, CA: Academic Press. [31]Google Scholar
Prelec, D., & Herrnstein, R. (1991). Preferences or principles: Alternative guidelines for choice. In Zeckhauser, R. J. (Ed.), Strategy and choice (pp. 319–340). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. [22, 28, 29]Google Scholar
Prelec, D., & Loewenstein, G. (1991). Decision making over time and under uncertainty: A common approach. Management Science, 37, 770–786. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Premack, D., & Premack, A. J. (1983). The mind of an ape. New York: Norton. [26]Google Scholar
Preston, M. G., & Baratta, P. (1948). An experimental study of the auction-value of an uncertain outcome. American Journal of Psychology, 61, 183–193. [2]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Puto, C. P. (1987). The framing of buying decisions. Journal of Consumer Research, 14, 301–315. [17]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Qualified Transportation Fringe Benefits, 26 CFR Parts 1 and 602. (2001). [38]
Quattrone, G., & Tversky, A. (1984). Causal versus diagnostic contingencies: On self-deception and the voter's illusion. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 46, 237–248. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rabin, M. (1998). Psychology and economics. Journal of Economic Literature, 36, 11–46. [34]Google Scholar
Rachlin, H. (1995). Self-control: Beyond commitment. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 18, 109–159. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rae, J. (1834/1905). The sociological theory of capital. London: Macmillan. [13]Google Scholar
Raiffa, H. (1968). Decision analysis: Introductory lectures on choices under uncertainty. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley. [1, 3, 26]Google Scholar
Rajecki, D. W. (1974). Effects of prenatal exposure to auditory or visual stimulation on postnatal distress vocalizations in chicks. Behavioral Biology, 11, 525–536. [25]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Randall, A. (1986). Valuation in a policy context. In Bromley, D. (Ed.), Natural resource economics: Policy problems and contemporary analysis (pp. 163–200). Boston: Kluwer/Nijhoff Publishing. [33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Randall, A., & Hoehn, J. (1996). Embedding in market demand systems. Journal of Environmental and Economic Management, 30, 369–380. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Randall, A., Hoehn, J., & Brookshire, D. (1983). Contingent valuation surveys for evaluating environmental assets. Natural Resources Journal, 23, 635–648. [33]Google Scholar
Ranyard, R. (1989). Structuring and evaluating simple monetary risks. In Montgomery, H. & Svenson, O. (Eds.), Process and structure in human decision making. Chichester, UK: Wiley. [19]Google Scholar
Rasmussen, J. (1993). Deciding and doing: Decision making in natural contexts. In Klein, G. A., Orasanu, J., Calderwood, R., & Zsambok, C. E. (Eds.), Decision making in action: Models and methods (pp. 158–171). Norwood, NJ: Ablex. [18]Google Scholar
Ratcliff, R., Cherian, A., & Segraves, M. (2003). A comparison of macaque behavior and superior colliculus neuronal activity to predictions from models of two-choice decisions. Journal of Neurophysiology, 90, 1392–1407. [11]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ratcliff, R., & McKoon, G. (1997). A counter model for implicit priming in perceptual word identification. Psychological Review, 104, 319–343. [21]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ratner, R. K., Kahn, B., & Kahneman, D. (1999). Choosing less-preferred experiences for the sake of variety. Journal of Consumer Research, 26, 1–15. [28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ratneshwar, S., Warlop, L., Mick, D. G., & Seeger, G. (1997). Benefit salience and consumers' selective attention to product features. International Journal of Research in Marketing, 14, 245–259. [15]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rawls, J. (1971). A theory of justice. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. [36]Google Scholar
Read, D., & Loewenstein, G. (1995). Diversification bias: Explaining the discrepancy in variety seeking between combined and separate choices. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Applied, 1, 34–49. [17, 20, 30, 34]Google Scholar
Read, D., Loewenstein, G., & Kalyanaraman, S. (1999). Mixing virtue with vice: The combined effects of hyperbolic discounting and diversification. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 12, 257–273. [20]3.0.CO;2-6>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Read, D., Loewenstein, G., & Rabin, M. (1999). Choice bracketing. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 19, 171–197. [1, 20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Read, D., Ouden, L., Trienekens, H., & Antonides, G. (1999). Diversification bias in choice for consecutive consumption (Working paper). Leeds, UK: Leeds University Business School. [20]Google Scholar
Read, D., & Leeuwen, B. (1998). Predicting hunger: The effects of appetite and delay on choice. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 76, 189–205. [20, 28]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Read, S. J., & Marcus-Newhall, J. (1993). Explanatory coherence in social explanations: A parallel distributed processing account. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 65, 429–447. [12]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Read, S. J., Snow, C. J., & Simon, D. (2003, August). Constraint satisfaction processes in social reasoning. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Cognitive Science Society, Boston. [12]
Read, S. J., Vanman, E. J., & Miller, L. C. (1997). Connectionism, parallel constraint satisfaction processes, and gestalt principles: (Re)introducing cognitive dynamics in social psychology. Personality and Social Psychology Review, 1, 26–53. [12]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Redelmeier, D., & Kahneman, D. (1996). Patients' memories of painful medical treatment: Real-time and retrospective evaluations of two minimally invasive procedures. Pain, 116, 3–8. [1, 27]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Redelmeier, D., Rozin, P., & Kahneman, D. (1993). Understanding patients' decisions: Cognitive and emotional perspectives. Journal of the American Medical Association, 270, 72–76. [38]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Redelmeier, D., & Shafir, E. (1993). Medical decisions over multiple alternatives (Working paper). Toronto, Canada: University of Toronto. [22]Google Scholar
Redelmeier, D., & Tversky, A. (1992). On the framing of multiple prospects. Psychological Science, 3, 191–193. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reder, L. M., & Anderson, J. R. (1980). A partial resolution of the paradox of interference: The role of integrating knowledge. Cognitive Psychology, 12, 447–472. [21]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Reilly, R. J. (1982). Preference reversal: Further evidence and some suggested modifications in experimental design. American Economic Review, 72(3), 576–584. [8]Google Scholar
Revesz, R. L. (1999). Environmental regulation, cost-benefit analysis, and the discounting of human lives. Columbia Law Review, 99, 941–1017. [38]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Reyna, V. F., & Lloyd, F. (1997). Theories of false memory in children and adults. Learning and Individual Differences, 9, 95–123. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reyna, V. F., Lloyd, F. J., & Brainerd, C. J. (2003). Memory, development, and rationality: An integrative theory of judgment and decision making. In Schneider, S. L. & Shanteau, J. (Eds.), Emerging perspectives on judgment and decision research (pp. 203–245). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ristau, C. A., & Robbins, D. (1982). Language in the great apes: A critical review. In Rosenblatt, J. S., Hinde, R. A., Beer, C., & Busnel, M. (Eds.), Advances in the study of behavior (Vol. 12, pp. 141–255). New York: Academic Press. [26]Google Scholar
Ritov, I. (1996). Anchoring in a simulated competitive market negotiation. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 67, 16–25. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ritov, I., Baron, J., & Hershey, J. (1993). Framing effects in the evaluation of multiple risk reduction. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 6, 145–159. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, G. H. (1964). Continuous estimation of a time-varying probability. Ergonomics, 7, 7–21. [2]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, R. J., Keltner, D., Ward, A., & Ross, L. (1995). Actual versus assumed differences in construal: “Naive realism” in intergroup perception and conflict. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 68, 404–417. [30]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roe, R. M., Busemeyer, J. R., & Townsend, J. T. (2001). Multi-alternative decision field theory: A dynamic connectionist model of decision-making. Psychological Review, 108, 370–392. [11]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roedder, D. L. (1981). Age differences in children's responses to television advertising: An information-processing approach. Journal of Consumer Research, 8, 144–153. [17]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roedder, D. L., Sternthal, B., & Calder, B. J. (1983). Attitude-behavior consistency in children's responses to television advertising. Journal of Marketing Research, 20, 337–349. [17]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roedinger, H. L., & Guynn, M. J. (1996). Retrieval processes. In Bjork, E. L. & Bjork, R. A. (Eds.), Memory (pp. 197–236). San Diego, CA: Academic Press. [21]Google Scholar
Roese, N. J. (1997). Counterfactual thinking. Psychological Bulletin, 121, 133–148. [28]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rohrmann, B., & Borcherding, K. (1988, August). The cognitive structure of residential decisions: A longitudinal field study. Paper presented at the XXIV International Congress of Psychology, Sydney, Australia. [18]
Rolston, H. (1981). Values in nature. Environmental Ethics, 3, 115–128. [33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosch, E., & Lloyd, B. (1978). Cognition and categorization. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [31]Google Scholar
Rosen, L. D., & Rosenkoetter, P. (1976). An eye fixation analysis of choice and judge ment with multiattribute stimuli. Memory & Cognition, 4, 747–752. [7]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosenthal, R., & Rosnow, R. L. (1969). Artifact in behavioral research. New York: Academic Press. [35]Google Scholar
Ross, H. L. (1973). Law, science, and accidents: The British Road Safety Act of 1967. Journal of Legal Studies, 2, 1–78. [13]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rottenstreich, Y., & Hsee, C. K. (2001). Money, kisses, and electric shocks: On the affective psychology of risk. Psychological Science, 12, 185–190. [23, 24, 29, 32]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rottenstreich, Y., & Tversky, A. (1997). Unpacking, repacking, and anchoring: Advances in support theory. Psychological Review, 104, 406–415. [31]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rotter, J. B. (1966). Generalized expectancies for internal versus external locus of con trol of reinforcement. Psychological Monographs, 80, 1–28. [16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Royden, H. L., Suppes, P., & Walsh, K. (1959). A model for the experimental measure ment of the utility of gambling. Behavioral Science, 4, 11–18. [2]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rumelhart, D. E., & McClelland, J. L. (1986). Parallel distributed processing: Explorations in the microstructure of cognition (Vol. 1). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. [11, 12]Google Scholar
Russell, J. A. (2002). Core affect and the psychological construction of emotion. Psychological Review, 110, 145–172. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Russell, M. (1990). The making of cruel choices. In Hammond, P. B. & Coppock, R. (Eds.), Valuing health risks, costs, and benefits for environmental decision making: Report of a conference (pp. 15–22). Washington, DC: National Academy Press. [34]Google Scholar
Russo, J. E. (1977). The value of unit price information. Journal of Marketing Research, 14, 193–201. [17, 34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Russo, J. E., & Dosher, B. A. (1983). Strategies for multiattribute binary choice. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 9, 676–696. [7, 9, 10, 17]Google ScholarPubMed
Russo, J. E., & Leclerc, F. (1991). Characteristics of successful product information programs. Journal of Social Issues, 67, 73–92. [13]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Russo, J. E., & Leclerc, F. (1994). An eye-fixation analysis of choice processes for con sumer nondurables. Journal of Consumer Research, 21, 274–290. [1, 17]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Russo, J. E., Medvec, V. H., & Meloy, M. G. (1996). The distortion of information during decisions. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 66, 102–110. [12, 17, 19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Russo, J. E., Meloy, M. G., & Medvec, V. H. (1998). Predecisional distortion of product information. Journal of Marketing Research, 35, 438–452. [12, 19, 21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Russo, J. E., Meloy, M. G., & Wilks, T. J. (2000). Predecisional distortion of information by auditors and salespersons. Management Science, 46, 13–27. [19, 21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Russo, J. E., & Rosen, L. D. (1975). An eye fixation analysis of multialternative choice. Memory & Cognition, 3, 267–276. [7]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Russo, J. E., & Schoemaker, P. J. H. (1989). Decision traps. New York: Fireside. [34]Google Scholar
Rutherford, M., Knetsch, J. L., & Brown, T. (1998). Assessing environmental losses: Judgments of importance and damage schedules. Harvard Environmental Law Review, 22, 51–101. [31]Google Scholar
Ryan, R. M., & Deci, E. L. (2001). On happiness and human potentials: A review of research on hedonic and eudaimonic well-being. Annual Review of Psychology, 52, 141–166. [28]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Sabini, J., & Silver, M. (1982). Moralities of everyday life. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. [20]Google Scholar
Salancik, G. R. (1974). Inference of one's attitude from behavior recalled under linguistically manipulated cognitive sets. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 10, 415–427. [26]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Salo, I. (2000). A psychological process approach to decision making: Postdecision restructuring of value conflicts. Unpublished doctoral dissertation, Lund University, Lund, Sweden. [19]
Salo, I., & Svenson, O. (2001). Constructive psychological responses before and after a real-life choice. In Alwood, C. M. & Selart, M. (Eds.), Decision making: Social and creative dimensions (pp. 137–151). Dordrecht, Germany: Kluwer. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Salthouse, T. A. (1992). Why do adult age differences increase with task complexity?Developmental Psychology, 28, 905–918. [24]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, P. (1963). Risk and uncertainty: A fallacy of large numbers. Scientia, 98, 108–113. [20]Google Scholar
Samuelson, W., & Zeckhauser, R. (1988). Status quo bias in decision-making. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 1, 7–59. [19, 37, 38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sanbonmatsu, D. M., & Fazio, R. H. (1990). The role of attitudes in memory-based decision making. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 59, 614–622. [10]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Sanbonmatsu, D. M., Kardes, F. R., & Gibson, B. D. (1991). The role of attribute knowledge and overall evaluations in comparative judgment. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 48, 131–146. [10]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sanfey, A., & Hastie, R. (1998). Does evidence presentation format affect judgment? An experimental evaluation of displays of data for judgments. Psychological Science, 9, 99–103. [23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Savage, L. J. (1954). The foundations of statistics. New York: Wiley. [1, 22]Google Scholar
Scheffler, S. (1985). The role of consent in the legitimation of risky activities. In Gibson, M. (Ed.), To breathe freely (pp. 75–88). Totowa, NJ: Rowman and Littlefield. [36]Google Scholar
Schelling, T. C. (1978). Micromotives and macrobehavior. New York: Norton. [14]Google Scholar
Schelling, T. C. (1984a). Choice and consequence: Perspectives of an errant economics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. [27]Google Scholar
Schelling, T. C. (1984b). Self-command in practice, in policy, and in a theory of rational choice. American Economic Review, 74(2), 1–11. [29]Google Scholar
Schick, F. (1991). Understanding action: An essay on reasons. New York: Cambridge University Press. [22]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schkade, D. A., & Johnson, E. J. (1989). Cognitive processes in preference reversals. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 44, 203–231. [1, 6, 7, 8, 9, 10, 11]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schkade, D. A., & Kahneman, D. (1998). Does living in California make people happy? A focusing illusion in judgments of life satisfaction. Psychological Science, 9, 340–346. [21, 28, 29, 30]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schkade, D. A., & Payne, J. W. (1994). How people respond to contingent valu ation questions: A verbal protocol analysis of willingness to pay for an environmental regulation. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 26, 88. [20, 34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmidt, U., & Hey, J. D. (2004). Are preference reversals errors?Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 29, 207–218. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schneider, C. E. (1998). The practice of autonomy: Patients, doctors, and medical decisions. New York: Oxford University Press. [38]Google Scholar
Schoemaker, P. J. H. (1982). The expected utility model: Its variants, purposes, evidence, and limitations. Journal of Economic Literature, 20, 529–563. [7]Google Scholar
Schoemaker, P. J. H. (1991). When and how to use scenario planning: A heuristic approach with illustration. Journal of Forecasting, 10, 549–564. [34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schooler, J. W., & Engstler-Schooler, T. Y. (1990). Verbal overshadowing of visual memories: Some things are better left unsaid. Cognitive Psychology, 22, 36–71. [26]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Schooler, J. W., Ohlsson, S., & Brooks, K. (1993). Thoughts beyond words: When ver balization overshadows insight. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 122, 166–183. [26]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schreiber, C. A., & Kahneman, D. (2000). Determinants of the remembered utility of aversive sounds. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 129, 27–42. [31]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Schultz, W., Romo, R., Ljungberg, T., Mirenowicz, J., Hollerman, J. R., & Dickinson, A. (1995). Reward-related signals carried by dopamine neurons. In Houk, J. C., Davis, J. L., & Beiser, D. G. (Eds.), Models of information processing in the basal ganglia (pp. 233–248). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. [11]Google Scholar
Schulz, R. (1976). Effects of control and predictability on the physical and psychological well-being of the institutionalized aged. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 33, 563–573. [16]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Schulz, R., & Hanusa, B. H. (1978). Long-term effects of control and predictability-enhancing interventions: Findings and ethical issues. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 36, 1194–1201. [16]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Schulze, W., McClelland, G. H., Waldman, D., & Lazo, J. (1996). Sources of bias in contingent valuation. In Bjornstad, D. J. & Kahn, J. R. (Eds.), The contingent valua tion of environmental resources: Methodological issues and research needs (pp. 97–116). Brookfield, VT: Edward Elgar. [33]Google Scholar
Schuman, H., & Presser, S. (1981). Questions and answers in attitude surveys: Experiments on question form, wording, and context. New York: Academic Press. [34]Google Scholar
Schwartz, B. (1994). The costs of living: How market freedom erodes the best things in life. New York: W. W. Norton & Company. [16]Google Scholar
Schwartz, B. (2000). Self-determination: The tyranny of freedom. American Psychologist, 55, 79–88. [16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwartz, B. (2004). The paradox of choice: Why more is less. New York: HarperCollins. [1]Google Scholar
Schwarz, N. (1990). Feelings as information: Informational and motivational functions of affective states. In Sorrentino, E. T. H. R. (Ed.), Handbook of motivation and cognition: Foundations of social behavior (Vol. 2, pp. 527–561). New York: Guilford Press. [30]Google Scholar
Schwarz, N. (1996). Cognition and communication: Judgmental biases, research methods, and the logic of conversation. Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [34]Google Scholar
Schwarz, N. (1999). Self-reports: How the questions shape the answers. American Psychologist, 54, 93–105. [35]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwarz, N., & Clore, G. L. (1983). Mood, misattribution, and judgments of well-being: Information and directive functions of affective states. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 45, 513–523. [21, 24, 30]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwarz, N., & Clore, G. L. (1988). How do I feel about it? Informative functions of affective states. In Fiedler, K. & Forgas, J. (Eds.), Affect, cognition, and social behavior (pp. 44–62). Toronto: Hogrefe International. [23]Google Scholar
Schwarz, N., & Clore, G. L. (2003). Mood as information: 20 years later. Psychological Inquiry, 14, 294–301. [24]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schweitzer, M. (1994). Disentangling status quo and omission effects: An experimental analysis. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 58, 457–476. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scitovsky, T. (1976). The joyless economy. New York: Oxford University Press. [27, 28]Google Scholar
Sedeck, G., Kofta, M., & Tyszka, T. (1993). Effects of uncontrollability on subsequent decision making: Testing the cognitive exhaustion hypothesis. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 6, 1270–1281. [18]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Segal, U. (1988). Does the preference reversal phenomenon necessarily contradict the independence axiom?American Economic Review, 78(1), 233–236. [1, 8]Google Scholar
Seidl, C. (2002). Preference reversal. Journal of Economic Surveys, 16, 621–655. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seip, K., & Strand, J. (1992). Willingness to pay for environmental goods in Norway: A contingent valuation study with real payment. Environmental and Resource Economics, 2, 91–106. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selart, M. (1996). Structure compatibility and restructuring in judgment and choice. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 65, 106–116. [18]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selart, M., Montgomery, H., Romanus, J., & Gärling, T. (1994). Violations of procedural invariance in preference measurement: Cognitive explanations. European Journal of Cognitive Psychology, 6, 417–436. [18]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seligman, C., Fazio, R. H., & Zanna, M. P. (1980). Effects of salience of extrinsic rewards on liking and loving. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 38, 453–460. [26]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seligman, M. E. P. (2002). Authentic happiness: Using the new positive psychology to realize the potential for lasting fulfillment. New York: The Free Press. [28]Google Scholar
Seligman, M. E. P., & Csikszentmihalyi, M. (2000). Positive psychology: An introduction. American Psychologist, 55, 5–14. [28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, A. (1982). Choice, welfare, and measurement. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. [13]Google Scholar
Sen, A. (1987). On ethics and economics. Blackwell, UK: Oxford. [27]Google Scholar
Sen, A. (1990). Rational behavior. In Eatwell, J., Milgate, M., & Newman, P. (Eds.), The new Palgrave: Utility and probability (pp. 198–216). New York: W. W. Norton. [27]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, A. (1993). Internal consistency of choice. Econometrica, 61, 495–521. [27, 28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, A. (1997). Maximization and the act of choice. Econometrica, 65, 745–779. [34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shafer, G., & Tversky, A. (1985). Language and designs for probability judgment. Cognitive Science, 9, 309–339. [6]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shafir, E. (1993). Choosing versus rejecting: Why some options are both better and worse than others. Memory & Cognition, 21, 546–556. [1, 9, 19, 22]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Shafir, E. (2002). Cognition, intuition, and policy guidelines. In Gowda, R. & Fox, J. (Eds.), Judgments, choices, and public policy (pp. 71–88). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. [9, 28]Google Scholar
Shafir, E., & LeBoeuf, R. A. (2002). Rationality. Annual Review of Psychology, 53, 491–517. [19]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Shafir, E., Osherson, D. N., & Smith, E. E. (1989). An advantage model of choice. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 2, 1–23. [17, 23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shafir, E., Osherson, D. N., & Smith, E. E. (1993). The advantage model: A compara tive theory of evaluation and choice under risk. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 55, 325–378. [17, 23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shafir, E., Simonson, I., & Tversky, A. (1993). Reason-based choice. Cognition, 49, 11–36. [1, 12, 16, 18, 21, 22, 23, 29]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Shafir, E., & Tversky, A. (1992). Thinking through uncertainty: Nonconsequential rea soning and choice. Cognitive Psychology, 24, 449–474. [16, 19, 22]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shamoun, S. (2004). Post-decisional processes: Consolidation and value conflicts in decision making. Unpublished doctoral dissertation, Stockholm University, Stockholm. [19]
Shamoun, S., & Svenson, O. (2002). Value conflict and post-decisional consolidation. Scandinavian Journal of Psychology, 43, 325–333. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepard, R. N. (1964). On subjectively optimum selection among multiattribute alter natives. In Shelley, M. W. II, & Bryan, G. L. (Eds.), Human judgments and optimality (pp. 257–281). New York: Wiley. [2, 19, 34]Google Scholar
Sherman, D. A., Kim, H., & Zajonc, R. B. (1998, August). Affective perseverance: Cogni tions change but preferences stay the same. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Psychological Society, San Francisco. [23]
Sherman, L. W. (1990). Police crackdowns: Initial and residual deterrence. In Tonry, M. & Morris, N. (Eds.), Crime and justice: An annual review of research (Vol. 12, pp. 1–48). Chicago: University of Chicago Press. [13]Google Scholar
Sherman, S. J. (1980). On the self-erasing nature of errors of prediction. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 39, 211–221. [28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sherman, S. J., McMullen, M. N., & Gavanski, I. (1992). Natural sample spaces and the inversion of conditional judgments. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 28, 401–421. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shiffrin, R. M., & Schneider, W. (1977). Controlled and automatic human informa tion processing: II. Perceptual learning, automatic attending, and a general theory. Psychological Review, 84, 127–190. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shiller, R. J. (1998). Human behavior and the efficiency of the financial system. In Taylor, J. B. & Woodford, M. (Eds.), Handbook of macroeconomics (Vol. 1, pp. 1305–1340). Amsterdam: Elsevier. [13, 14]Google Scholar
Shiller, R. J. (2000). Irrational exuberance. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. [1, 38]Google Scholar
Shiv, B., Edell, J. A., & Payne, J. W. (1997). Factors affecting the impact of nega tively and positively framed ad messages. Journal of Consumer Research, 24, 285–294. [17]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shuford, E. H. (1961). Percentage estimation of proportion as a function of element type, exposure time, and task. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 61, 430–436. [2]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Siegel, S. (1956). Nonparametric statistics for the behavioral sciences. New York: McGraw-Hill. [16]Google Scholar
Siegel, S., Krank, M. D., & Hinson, R. E. (1987). Anticipation of pharmacological and nonpharmacological events: Classical conditioning and addictive behavior. Journal of Drug Issues, 17, 83–110. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simmons, C. J., Bickart, B. A., & Lynch, J. G. Jr. (1993). Capturing and creating public opinion in survey research. Journal of Consumer Research, 20, 316–329. [17, 34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, D., & Holyoak, K. J. (2002). Structural dynamics of cognition: From consistency theories to constraint satisfaction. Personality and Social Psychology Review, 6, 283–294. [1, 12, 19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, D., Krawczyk, D. C., & Holyoak, K. J. (2004). Construction of preferences by constraint satisfaction. Psychological Science, 15, 331–336. [1, 12,19]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Simon, D., Pham, L. B., Le, Q. A., & Holyoak, K. J. (2001). The emergence of coherence over the course of decision making. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 27, 1250–1260. [12, 19]Google ScholarPubMed
Simon, D., Snow, C. J., & Read, S. J. (2004). The redux of cognitive consistency theories: Evidence judgments by constraint satisfaction. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 86, 814–837. [12]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Simon, H. A. (1955). A behavioral model of rational choice. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 59, 99–118. [1, 16, 17, 19, 27, 34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1956). Rational choice and the structure of the environment. Psychological Review, 63, 129–138. [1, 16, 23]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Simon, H. A. (1957). Models of man: Social and rational. New York: Wiley. [2, 20]Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1978). Rationality as process and as product of a thought. American Economic Review, 68(2), 1–16. [33]Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1990). Invariants of human behavior. Annual Review of Psychology, 41, 1–19. [17, 19]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Simonson, I. (1989). Choice based on reasons: The case of attraction and compromise effects. Journal of Consumer Research, 16, 158–174. [1, 11, 22, 29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simonson, I. (1990). The effect of purchase quantity and timing on variety seeking behavior. Journal of Marketing Research, 27, 150–162. [17, 20, 27, 28, 29, 30]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simonson, I. (1992). The influence of anticipating regret and responsibility on purchase decisions. Journal of Consumer Research, 19, 105–118. [17]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simonson, I., Carmon, Z., & O'Curry, S. (1994). Experimental evidence on the negative effect of product features and sales promotions on brand choice. Marketing Science, 13, 23–40. [22]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simonson, I., Huber, J., & Payne, J. W. (1988). The relationship between prior brand knowledge and information acquisition order. Journal of Consumer Research, 14, 566–578. [10]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simonson, I., & Nowlis, S. M. (2000). The role of explanations and need for uniqueness in consumer decision making: Unconventional choices based on reasons. Journal of Consumer Research, 27, 150–162. [28, 29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simonson, I., Nowlis, S. M., & Lemon, K. (1993). The effect of local consideration sets on global choice between lower price and higher quality. Marketing Science, 12, 357–377. [10]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simonson, I., Nowlis, S. M., & Simonson, Y. (1993). The effect of irrelevant preference arguments on consumer choice. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 2, 287–306. [22]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simonson, I., & Tversky, A. (1992). Choice in context: Tradeoff contrast and extreme ness aversion. Journal of Marketing Research, 29, 281–295. [10, 17, 22]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simonson, I., & Winer, R. S. (1992). The influence of purchase quantity and display format on consumer preference for variety. Journal of Consumer Research, 19, 133–138. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sloman, S. A. (1996). The empirical case for two systems of reasoning. Psychological Bulletin, 119, 3–22. [1, 23, 32]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slovic, P. (1972). From Shakespeare to Simon: Speculation – and some evidence – about man's ability to process information. Oregon Research Institute Research Monograph, 12(2). [34]Google Scholar
Slovic, P. (1975). Choice between equally valued alternatives. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance, 1, 280–287. [5, 6, 18, 19, 22]Google Scholar
Slovic, P. (1987). Perception of risk. Science, 236, 280–285. [23, 35]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Slovic, P. (1990). Choice. In Osherson, D. N. & Smith, E. E. (Eds.), An invitation to cognitive science (Vol. 3, pp. 89–116). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. [22]Google Scholar
Slovic, P. (1995). The construction of preference. American Psychologist, 50, 364–371. [12, 13, 14, 15, 17, 19, 21, 23, 24, 31, 34, 37]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slovic, P. (2000a). Rational actors and rational fools: The influence of affect on judgment and decision-making. Roger Williams University Law Review, 6, 163–212. [23]Google Scholar
Slovic, P. (Ed.). (2000b). The perception of risk. London: Earthscan. [35]Google Scholar
Slovic, P. (2001). Cigarette smokers: Rational actors or rational fools? In Slovic, P. (Ed.), Smoking: Risk, perception, & policy (pp. 97–124). Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. [23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slovic, P., Finucane, M. L., Peters, E., & MacGregor, D. G. (2002). The affect heuristic. In Gilovich, T., Griffin, D., & Kahneman, D. (Eds.), Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment (pp. 397–420). New York: Cambridge University Press. [1, 23, 24, 29, 32, 35, 36]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slovic, P., Fischhoff, B., & Lichtenstein, S. (1977). Behavioral decision theory. Annual Review of Psychology, 28, 1–39. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slovic, P., Fischhoff, B., & Lichtenstein, S. (1982). Response mode, framing, and information-processing effects in risk assessment. In Hogarth, R. M. (Ed.), New direc tions for methodology of social and behavioral science: No. 11. Question framing and response consistency (pp. 21–36). San Francisco: Jossey-Bass. [33]Google Scholar
Slovic, P., Griffin, D., & Tversky, A. (1990). Compatibility effects in judgment and choice. In Hogarth, R. M. (Ed.), Insights in decision making: A tribute to Hillel J. Einhorn (pp. 5–27). Chicago: University of Chicago. [1, 6, 8, 9, 10, 11, 19, 23, 33, 36]Google Scholar
Slovic, P., Kunreuther, H., & White, G. F. (1974). Decision processes, rationality and adjustment to natural hazards. In White, G. F. (Ed.), Natural hazards: Local, national, global (pp. 187–205). New York: Oxford University Press. [38]Google Scholar
Slovic, P., Layman, M., Kraus, N., Flynn, J., Chalmers, J., & Gesell, G. (1991). Perceived risk, stigma, and potential economic impacts of a high-level nuclear waste repository in Nevada. Risk Analysis, 11, 683–696. [23]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Slovic, P., & Lichtenstein, S. (1968). Relative importance of probabilities and payoffs in risk-taking. Journal of Experimental Psychology Monograph, 78(3, Pt. 2), 1–18. [1, 2, 3, 4, 6, 7, 8, 29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slovic, P., & Lichtenstein, S. (1971). Comparison of Bayesian and regression approaches to the study of information processing in judgment. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 6, 649–744. [1, 6, 33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slovic, P., & Lichtenstein, S. (1983). Preference reversals: A broader perspective. American Economic Review, 73(4), 596–605. [1, 6, 7, 8, 18]Google Scholar
Slovic, P., Lichtenstein, S., & Edwards, W. (1965). Boredom-induced changes in pref erences among bets. American Journal of Psychology, 78, 208–217. [1, 2]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slovic, P., Lichtenstein, S., & Fischhoff, B. (1979). Images of disaster: Perception and acceptance of risks from nuclear power. In Goodman, G. & Rowe, W. (Eds.), Energy risk assessment (pp. 223–245). London: Academic Press. [33]Google Scholar
Slovic, P., Lichtenstein, S., & Fischhoff, B. (1984). Modeling the societal impact of fatal accidents. Management Science, 30, 464–474. [35]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slovic, P., & MacPhillamy, D. J. (1974). Dimensional commensurability and cue utilization in comparative judgment. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 11, 172–194. [1, 10, 33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slovic, P., Monahan, J., & MacGregor, D. G. (2000). Violence risk assessment and risk communication: The effects of using actual cases, providing instructions, and employing probability vs. frequency formats. Law and Human Behavior, 24, 271–296. [23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slovic, P., & Tversky, A. (1974). Who accepts Savage's axiom?Behavioral Science, 19, 368–373. [27]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, E. R. (1992). The role of exemplars in social judgment. In Martin, L. L. & Tesser, A. (Eds.), The construction of social judgments (pp. 107–132). Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [19]Google Scholar
Smith, G. (1997). The political impact of name sounds. Unpublished manuscript, Eastern Washington University, Ellensburg, WA. [23]
Smith, V. K. (1992). Arbitrary values, good causes, and premature verdicts. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 22, 71–89. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, V. K., & Desvousges, W. (1987). An empirical analysis of the economic value of risk changes. Journal of Political Economy, 95, 89–114. [34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, V. K., Desvousges, W., & Fisher, A. (1986). A comparison of direct and indi rect methods for estimating environmental benefits. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 68, 280–290. [33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Soelberg, P. (1967). Unprogrammed decision making. Management Review, 3, 19–29. [18]Google Scholar
Soman, D., & Cheema, A. (2001). The effects of windfall gains on the sunk-cost effect. Marketing Letters, 12, 51–62. [29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spangenberg, E. R., & Greenwald, A. G. (1999). Social influence by requesting self-prophecy. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 8, 61–89. [28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spellman, B. A., & Holyoak, K. J. (1992). If Saddam is Hitler then who is George Bush? Analogical mapping between systems of social roles. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 62, 913–933. [12]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spellman, B. A., Ullman, J. B., & Holyoak, K. J. (1993). A coherence model of cognitive consistency: Dynamics of attitude change during the Persian Gulf War. Journal of Social Issues, 49, 147–165. [12]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stanovich, K. E. (1999). Who is rational? Studies of individual differences in reasoning. Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [1]Google Scholar
Stanovich, K. E., & West, R. F. (1998). Individual differences in rational thought. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 127, 161–188. [17]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stanovich, K. E., & West, R. F. (2000). Individual differences in reasoning: Implications for the rationality debate?Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 23, 645–726. [1]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Starr, C. (1969). Social benefit versus technological risk. Science, 165, 1232–1238. [35]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Steele, C. M. (1988). The psychology of self-affirmation: Sustaining the integrity of self. In Berkowitz, L. (Ed.), Advances in experimental social psychology (Vol. 21, pp. 261–302). New York: Academic Press. [30]Google Scholar
Stevens, S. S. (1951). Mathematics, measurement, and psychophysics. In Stevens, S. S. (Ed.), Handbook of experimental psychology (pp. 1–49). New York: Wiley. [33]Google Scholar
Stevens, S. S. (1975). Psychophysics. New York: Wiley. [13, 31, 32]Google Scholar
Stevens, S. S., & Galanter, E. H. (1957). Ratio scales and category scales for a dozen perceptual continua. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 54, 377–411. [2]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Stevens, T. H., Echeverria, J., Glass, R. J., Hager, T., & More, T. A. (1991). Measuring the existence value of wildlife: What do CVM estimates really show?Land Economics, 67, 390–400. [1, 33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strack, F., Argyle, M., & Schwarz, N. (Eds.). (1991). Subjective well-being: An interdisci plinary perspective. New York: Pergamon Press. [28]Google Scholar
Strack, F., & Mussweiler, T. (1997). Explaining the enigmatic anchoring effect: Mecha nisms of selective accessibility. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 73, 437–446. [13, 21, 31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sudman, S., Bradburn, N. M., & Schwarz, N. (1996). Thinking about answers: The application of cognitive processes to survey methodology. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass. [34]Google Scholar
Suh, E., Diener, E., & Fujita, F. (1996). Events and subjective well-being: Only recent events matter. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 70, 1091–1102. [30]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Sujan, M. (1985). Consumer knowledge: Effects of evaluation strategies mediating consumer judgments. Journal of Consumer Research, 12, 16–31. [10]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Summers, L. H. (1986). Does the stock market rationally reflect fundamental values?Journal of Finance, 41, 591–602. [13, 14]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, C. R. (1990). Preferences and politics. Philosophy and Public Affairs, 20, 3–34. [34]Google Scholar
Sunstein, C. R. (2001). Human behavior and the law of work. Virginia Law Review, 87, 205–276. [38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, C. R. (2002a). Risk and reason: Safety, law, and the environment. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. [38]Google Scholar
Sunstein, C. R. (2002b). Switching the default rule. New York University Law Review, 77, 106–134. [38]Google Scholar
Sunstein, C. R. (2004). Lives, life-years, and willingness to pay. Columbia Law Review, 104, 205–252. [38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, C. R., Kahneman, D., & Schkade, D. (1998). Assessing punitive damages. Yale Law Journal, 107, 2071–2153. [31, 32]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, C. R., Kahneman, D., Schkade, D., & Ritov, I. (2002). Predictably incoherent judgments. Stanford Law Review, 54, 1153–1215. [13, 14, 28, 38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, C. R., & Thaler, R. H. (2003). Libertarian paternalism is not an oxymoron. The University of Chicago Law Review, 70, 1159–1202. [1, 37, 38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svenson, O. (1973). Analysis of strategies in subjective probability inferences as evidenced in continuous verbal reports and numerical responses. (Reports from the Psychological Laboratories, No. 396.) Sweden: University of Stockholm. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svenson, O. (1974). A note on think aloud protocols obtained during the choice of a home. (Reports from the Psychological Laboratories, No. 421.) Sweden: University of Stockholm. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svenson, O. (1979). Process descriptions of decision making. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 23, 86–112. [1, 18, 19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svenson, O. (1983). Cognitive processes in judging cumulative risk over different periods of time. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 33, 22–41. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svenson, O. (1985). Cognitive strategies in a complex judgment task: Analysis of con current verbal reports and judgments of cumulated risk over different exposure times. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 36, 1–15. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svenson, O. (1990). Some propositions for the classification of decision situations. In Borcherding, K., Larichev, O. I., & Messick, D. M. (Eds.), Contemporary issues in decision making (pp. 17–31). Amsterdam: Elsevier. [19]Google Scholar
Svenson, O. (1992). Differentiation and Consolidation Theory of human decision making: A frame of reference for the study of pre- and post-decision processes. Acta Psychologica, 80, 143–168. [12, 18, 19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svenson, O. (1996). Decision making and the search for fundamental psychological realities: What can be learned from a process perspective?Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 65, 252–267. [1, 18, 31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svenson, O. (2003). Values, affect, and processes in human decision making: A Differentiation and Consolidation Theory perspective. In Schneider, S. L. & Shanteau, J. (Eds.), Emerging perspectives on judgment and decision making (pp. 287–326). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svenson, O., & Benthorn, L. (1992). Consolidation processes in decision making: Post-decision changes in attractiveness of alternatives. Journal of Economic Psychology, 13, 1–13. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svenson, O., & Edland, A. (1987). Change of preferences under time pressure: Choices and judgments. Scandinavian Journal of Psychology, 29, 322–330. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svenson, O., & Fischhoff, B. (1985). Levels of environmental decisions: A case study of radiation in Swedish homes. Journal of Environmental Psychology, 5, 55–67. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svenson, O., & Hill, T. (1997). Turning prior disadvantages into advantages: Decision making through the glass of differentiation and consolidation theory. In Ranyard, R., Crozier, W. R., & Svenson, O. (Eds.), Decision making: Cognitive models and explanations (pp. 218–232). London: Routledge. [18, 19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svenson, O., & Malmsten, N. (1991). Post-decision consolidation processes in human decision making. Journal of Scientific Contributions to Human Decision Making (Italy), 6, 109–120. [19]Google Scholar
Svenson, O., & Malmsten, N. (1996). Post-decision consolidation overtime as a function gain or loss of an alternative. Scandinavian Journal of Psychology, 37, 302–311. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svenson, O., Ortega Rayo, A., Sandberg, A., Svahlin, I., & Andersen, M. (1994). Post-decision consolidation as a function of the instructions to the decision maker and of the decision problem. Acta Psychologica, 87, 181–197. [19]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Svenson, O., & Shamoun, S. (1997). Predecision conflict and different patterns of post decision attractiveness restructuring: Empirical illustrations from an important real-life decision. Scandinavian Journal of Psychology, 38, 243–251. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swagler, R. M., & Wheeler, P. (1989). Rental-purchase agreements: A preliminary inves tigation of consumer attitudes and behaviors. Journal of Consumer Affairs, 23, 145–160. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swann, W. B., & Pittman, T. S. (1977). Initiating play activity of children: The moderat ing influence of verbal cues on intrinsic motivation. Child Development, 48, 1128–1132. [16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taurek, J. (1977). Should the numbers count?Philosophy and Public Affairs, 6, 293–316. [36]Google ScholarPubMed
Taylor, K. F., & Sluckin, W. (1964). Flocking in domestic chicks. Nature, 201, 108–109. [25]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Taylor, S. E. (1983). Adjustment to threatening events: A theory of cognitive adaptation. American Psychologist, 38, 1161–1173. [30]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, S. E. (1989). Positive illusions: Creating self-deception and the healthy mind. New York: Basic Books. [16]Google Scholar
Taylor, S. E., & Armor, D. A. (1996). Positive illusions and coping with adversity. Journal of Personality, 64, 873–898. [30]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Taylor, S. E., & Brown, J. D. (1988). Illusion and well-being: A social-psychological perspective on mental health. Psychological Bulletin, 103, 193–210. [16, 30]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Taylor, S. E., & Fiske, S. T. (1981). Getting inside the head: Methodologies for process analysis. In Harvey, J. H., Ickes, W. J., & Kidd, R. F. (Eds.), New directions in attribution research (Vol. 3, pp. 459–524). Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [7]Google Scholar
Taylor, S. E., & Gollwitzer, P. M. (1996). Effects of mindset on positive illusions. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 69, 213–226. [18]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Telhami, S. (1990). Power and leadership in international bargaining: The path to the Camp David Accords. New York: Columbia University Press. [22]Google Scholar
Tesser, A. (1978). Self-generated attitude change. In Berkowitz, L. (Ed.), Advances in experimental social psychology (Vol. 11, pp. 289–338). New York: Academic Press. [1]Google Scholar
Tesser, A., Leone, C., & Clary, G. (1978). Affect control: Process constraints versus catharsis. Cognitive Therapy and Research, 2, 265–274. [26]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tesser, A., & Martin, L. (1996). The psychology of evaluation. In Higgins, E. T. & Kruglanski, A. W. (Eds.), Social psychology: Handbook of basic principles (pp. 400–432). New York: Guilford Press. [31]Google Scholar
Tetlock, P. E. (1992). The impact of accountability on judgment and choice: Toward a social contingency model. In Zanna, M. P. (Ed.), Advances in experimental social psychology (Vol. 25, pp. 331–376). New York: Academic Press. [22]Google Scholar
Tetlock, P. E., & Boettger, R. (1989). Accountability: A social magnifier of the dilution effect. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 57, 388–398. [29]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Thagard, P. (1989). Explanatory coherence. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 12, 435–502. [12]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (1980). Toward a positive theory of consumer choice. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 1, 39–60. [27]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (1985). Mental accounting and consumer choice. Marketing Science, 4, 199–214. [20, 29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (1991). Quasi-rational economics. New York: Russell Sage. [38]Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (1992). The winner's curse: Paradoxes and anomalies of economic life. New York: The Free Press. [31]Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (1999). Mental accounting matters. In Kahneman, D. & Tversky, A. (Eds.), Choices, values and frames (pp. 241–268). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. [20, 21, 29]Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H., & Benartzi, S. (2004). Save More Tomorrow™: Using behavioral eco nomics to increase employee saving. Journal of Political Economy, 112, S164–S187. [38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. H., & Shefrin, H. M. (1981). An economic theory of self-control. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 392–406. [20, 29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. H., Tversky, A., Kahneman, D., & Schwartz, A. (1997). The effect of myopia and loss aversion on risk taking: An experimental test. The Quarterly Journal of Eco nomics, 112, 647–661. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thorngate, W. (1980). Efficient decision heuristics. Behavioral Science, 25, 219–225. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thurstone, L. L. (1928). Attitudes can be measured. American Journal of Sociology, 33, 529–554. [23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Timmermans, D. (1993). The impact of task complexity on information use in multi-attribute decision making. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 6, 95–111. [16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Toda, M. (1962). The design of a fungus-eater: A model of human behavior in an unsophisticated environment. Behavioral Science, 7, 164–183. [2]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Toulmin, S. (1950). An examination of the place of reason in ethics. New York: Cambridge University Press. [22]Google Scholar
Townsend, J. T., & Busemeyer, J. R. (1995). Dynamic representation of decision-making. In Port, R. F. & Gelder, T. (Eds.), Mind as motion (pp. 101–120). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. [11]Google Scholar
Trafimow, D., & Sheeran, P. (2004). A theory about the translation of cognition into affect and behavior. In Maio, G. R. & Haddock, G. (Eds.), Contemporary perspectives in the psychology of attitudes: The cardoff symposium (pp. 57–75).London: Psychology Press. [24]
Trollope, A. (1883/1980). An autobiography. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. [20]Google Scholar
Tune, G. S. (1964). Response preferences: A review of some relevant literature. Psychological Bulletin, 61, 286–302. [35]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Turner, C. F., & Krauss, E. (1978). Fallible indicators of the subjective state of the union. American Psychologist, 33, 456–470. [35]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A. (1967a). Additivity, utility and subjective probability. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 4, 175–201. [2]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A. (1967b). Utility theory, additivity analysis, and decision making under risk. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 75, 27–36. [2, 3]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A. (1969). Intransitivity of preferences. Psychological Review, 76, 31–48. [1, 3, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9, 11, 17, 28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A. (1972). Elimination by aspects: A theory of choice. Psychological Review, 79, 281–299. [1, 5, 11, 17, 19, 23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A. (1977). Features of similarity. Psychological Review, 84, 327–352. [6, 17]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A. (1996). Contrasting rational and psychological principles of choice. In Zeckhauser, R. J., Keeney, R. L., & Sebenius, J. K. (Eds.), Wise choices: Decisions, games, and negotiations (pp. 5–21). Boston: Harvard Business School Press. [17, 34]Google Scholar
Tversky, A., & Bar-Hillel, M. (1983). Risk: The long and the short. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 9, 713–717. [20]Google Scholar
Tversky, A., & Gati, I. (1978). Studies of similarity. In Rosch, E. & Lloyd, B. (Eds.), Cognition and categorization (pp. 79–98). Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [6]Google Scholar
Tversky, A., & Griffin, D. (1991). Endowment and contrast in judgments of well-being. In Strack, F., Argyle, M., & Schwarz, N. (Eds.), Subjective well-being: An interdisciplinary perspective (Vol. 12, pp. 101–118). Oxford, UK: Pergamon Press. [9, 29]Google Scholar
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1971). Belief in the law of small numbers. Psychological Bulletin, 76, 105–110. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1973). Availability: A heuristic for judging frequency and probability. Cognitive Psychology, 5, 207–232. [38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science, 185, 1124–1131. [1, 6, 7, 13, 21, 23, 35, 38]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1981). The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice. Science, 211, 453–458. [1, 17, 19, 20, 33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1982). Evidential impact of base rates. In Kahneman, D., Slovic, P., & Tversky, A. (Eds.), Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases (pp. 153–160). New York: Cambridge University Press. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1983). Extensional versus intuitive reasoning: The conjunction fallacy in probability judgment. Psychological Review, 90, 293–315. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1986). Rational choice and the framing of decisions. Journal of Business, 59, S251–S278. [1, 6, 8, 12, 17, 22, 27, 31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1991). Loss aversion in riskless choice: A reference-dependent model. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 1039–1061. [17, 21, 27, 31, 37]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1992). Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5, 297–323. [19, 27, 32]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A., Sattath, S., & Slovic, P. (1988). Contingent weighting in judgment and choice. Psychological Review, 95, 371–384. [1, 6, 7, 8, 9, 10, 11, 17, 18, 21, 22, 28, 29, 33, 34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A., & Shafir, E. (1992a). Choice under conflict: The dynamics of deferred decision. Psychological Science, 3, 358–361. [22]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A., & Shafir, E. (1992b). The disjunction effect in choice under uncertainty. Psychological Science, 3, 305–309. [22]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A., & Simonson, I. (1993). Context-dependent preferences. Management Science, 39, 1179–1189. [11, 17, 22]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A., Slovic, P., & Kahneman, D. (1990). The causes of preference reversal. American Economic Review, 80(1), 204–217. [1, 6, 7, 8, 27, 33, 36]Google Scholar
Tversky, A., & Thaler, R. H. (1990). Anomalies: Preference reversals. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 4(2), 201–211. [Frontispiece, 1, 31, 38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tyszka, T. (1983). Contextual multiattribute decision rules. In Sjöberg, L., Tyszka, T., & Wise, J. A. (Eds.), Human decision making (pp. 243–256). Bodafors, Sweden: Bokförlaget Doxa. [18]Google Scholar
Tyszka, T. (1985). Variability of predecisional information seeking behavior. Polish Psychological Bulletin, 16, 275–282. [19]Google Scholar
Tyszka, T., & Wielochovski, M. (1991). Must boxing verdicts be partial?Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 4, 283–295. [18, 19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Urban, G. L., & Hauser, J. R. (1993). Design and marketing of new products (2nd ed.). Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. [10]Google Scholar
Urban, G. L., Hauser, J. R., Qualls, W. J., Weinberg, B. D., Bohlmann, J. D., & Chicos, R. A. (1997). Information acceleration: Validation and lessons from the field. Journal of Marketing Research, 34, 143–153. [34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. (1993). Comparative risk. Washington, DC: Author. [35]
Usher, M., & McClelland, J. L. (2004). Loss aversion and inhibition in dynamic models of multi-alternative choice. Psychological Review, 111, 757–769. [11]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vaillant, G. (1993). The wisdom of the ego. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. [30]Google Scholar
Meer, H. C. (1963). Decision-making: The influence of probability preference, variance preference, and expected value on strategy in gambling. Acta Psychologica, 21, 231–259. [2]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gelder, L. (1996, January 7). Remembering the road not taken. The New York Times, p. F7. [30]Google Scholar
van Praag, B. M. S. (2003). The connection between old and new approaches to financial satisfaction. Unpublished manuscript. [28]
van Raaij, W. F. (1977). Consumer information processing for different informa tion structures and formats. In Perrault, W. D. (Ed.), Advances in consumer research (pp. 176–184). Chicago: Association for Consumer Research. [19]Google Scholar
Vanderplas, J. M. (1960). Some tests of significance of multivariate data. Journal of General Psychology, 62, 257–268. [2]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
VanDeVeer, D. (1986). Paternalistic intervention: The moral bounds of benevolence. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. [38]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Varey, C. A., & Kahneman, D. (1992). Experiences extended across time: Evaluation of moments and episodes. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 5, 169–185. [27, 31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Varian, H. R. (1984). Microeconomic analysis. New York: Norton. [6, 31]Google Scholar
Varian, H. R. (1999). Intermediate microeconomics: A modern approach (5th ed.). New York: Norton. [21]Google Scholar
Verplanken, B., Hofstee, G., & Janssen, H. J. W. (1998). Accessibility of affective versus cognitive components of attitudes. European Journal of Social Psychology, 28, 23–36. [24]3.0.CO;2-Z>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Verplanken, B., & Svenson, O. (1997). Personal involvement in human decision making: On conceptualization and effects on decision process. In Ranyard, R., Crozier, W. R., & Svenson, O. (Eds.), Decision making: Cognitive models and explanations (pp. 41–57). London: Routledge. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Viscusi, W. K. (1992). Smoking: Making the risky decision. New York: Oxford University Press. [23]Google Scholar
Viscusi, W. K., & Magat, W. A. (1987). Learning about risk: Consumer and worker responses to hazard warnings. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. [33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Viscusi, W. K., Magat, W. A., & Huber, J. (1986). Informational regulation of consumer health risks: An empirical evaluation of hazard warnings. Rand Journal of Economics, 17, 351–365. [33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Viscusi, W. K., Magat, W. A., & Huber, J. (1991). Pricing environmental health risks: Survey assessments of risk-risk and risk-dollar trade-offs for chronic bronchitis. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 21, 32–51. [33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Viswanathan, M., & Narayanan, S. (1994). Comparative judgments of numerical and verbal attribute labels. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 3, 79–102. [10, 29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
von Clausewitz, C. (1992). On war.Harmandsworth, UK: Penguin Books (Original work published 1832). [20]
Neumann, J., & Morgenstern, O. (1947). Theory of games and economic behavior (2nd ed.). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. [21, 22, 35]Google Scholar
von Winterfeldt, D. (1999). On the relevance of behavioral decision research for deci sion analysis. In Shanteau, J., Mellers, B., & Schum, D. (Eds.), Decision science and technology: Reflections on the contributions of Ward Edwards (pp. 133–154). Boston: Kluwer. [1]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winterfeldt, D., & Edwards, W. (1986). Decision analysis and behavioral research. New York: Cambridge University Press. [33, 34, 35]Google Scholar
Wald, A. (1950). Sequential analysis. New York: Wiley. [19]Google Scholar
Walden, M. L. (1990). The economics of rent-to-own contracts. Journal of Consumer Affairs, 24, 326–337. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walsh, R. G., Bjonback, R. D., Aiken, R. A., & Rosenthal, D. H. (1990). Estimating the public benefits of protecting forest quality. Journal of Environmental Management, 30, 175–189. [33]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Watkins, M. J., & Tulving, E. (1978). When retrieval cueing fails. British Journal of Psychology, 69, 443–450. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Watkins, O. C., & Watkins, M. J. (1975). Buildup of proactive inhibition as a cue-overload effect. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Learning and Memory, 1, 442–452. [21]Google Scholar
Watterson, B. (1996). It's a magical world. Kansas City, MO: Andrews and McNeel. [16]Google Scholar
Weber, E. U., Ames, D. R., & Blais, A.-R. (2005). “How do I choose thee? Let me count the ways”: A textual analysis of similarities and differences in modes of decision-making in China and the United States. Management and Organization Review, 1, 87–118. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, E. U., Goldstein, W. M., & Barlas, S. (1995). And let us not forget memory: The role of memory processes and techniques in the study of judgment and choice. In Busemeyer, J. R., Hastie, R., & Medin, D. L. (Eds.), Decision making from the perspective of cognitive psychology (Vol. 32, pp. 33–82). San Diego: Academic Press. [17, 21]Google Scholar
Weber, E. U., & Hsee, C. K. (2000). Culture and individual judgment and decision making. Applied Psychology: An International Review, 49, 32–61. [21]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wedell, D. H. (1991). Distinguishing among models of contextually induced prefer ences reversals. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 17, 767–778. [22]Google Scholar
Wedell, D. H., & Bockenholt, U. (1990). Moderation of preference reversals in the long run. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance, 16, 429–438. [1, 20]Google Scholar
Wedell, D. H., & Bockenholt, U. (1994). Contemplating single versus multiple encoun ters of a risky prospect. American Journal of Psychology, 107, 499–518. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wertenbroch, K. (1998). Segmentation and pricing under consumption self-control via purchase quantity rationing. Marketing Science, 17, 317–337. [17]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
West, P. M., Brown, C. L., & Hoch, S. J. (1996). Consumption vocabulary and preference formation. Journal of Consumer Research, 23, 120–135. [17]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Westen, D. (1994). Toward an integrative model of affect regulation: Applications to social psychological research. Journal of Personality, 62, 641–667. [30]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wickens, C. D. (1984). Engineering psychology and human performance. Columbus, OH: Merrill. [6]Google Scholar
Wickens, J. R., & Oorschot, D. E. (2000). Neuronal dynamics and surround inhibition in the neostriatum: A possible connection. In Miller, R. & Wickens, J. R. (Eds.), Brain dynamics and the striatal complex (pp. 141–150). Amsterdam: Harwood Academic. [11]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wicklund, R. A., & Brehm, J. W. (1976). Perspectives on cognitive dissonance. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [12, 22]Google Scholar
Wilde, O. (1893). Lady Windermere's fan: A play about a good woman. London: Mathews and Lane. [30]Google Scholar
Willemsen, M. C., & Keren, G. (2002). Negative-based prominence: The role of neg ative features on matching and choice. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 88, 643–666. [28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Willemsen, M. C., & Keren, G. (2004). The role of negative features in joint and separate evaluation. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 17, 313–329. [28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Willén, H. (1994). How do couples decide about having their first child? An explorative study (Göteborg Psychological Reports, Vol. 24, No. 1). Göteborg, Sweden: Göteborg University, Department of Psychology. [18]Google Scholar
Wilson, T. D. (1990). Self-persuasion via self-reflection. In Olson, J. M. & Zanna, M. P. (Eds.), Self-inference processes: The Ontario Symposium (Vol. 6, pp. 43–67). Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [26]
Wilson, T. D., & Brekke, N. (1994). Mental contamination and mental correction: Unwanted influences on judgments and evaluations. Psychological Bulletin, 19, 117–142. [30]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, T. D., & Dunn, D. S. (1986). Effects of introspection on attitude-behavior consistency: Analyzing reasons versus focusing on feelings. Journal of Experimen tal Social Psychology, 22, 249–263. [26]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, T. D., Dunn, D. S., Kraft, D., & Lisle, D. J. (1989). Introspection, attitude change, and attitude-behavior consistency: The disruptive effects of explaining why we feel the way we do. Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, 22, 287–343. [26, 29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, T. D., & Gilbert, D. T. (2003). Affective forecasting. In Zanna, M. (Ed.), Advances in experimental social psychology (pp. 345–411). New York: Elsevier. [28]Google Scholar
Wilson, T. D., & Hodges, S. D. (1992). Attitudes as temporary constructions. In Tesser, A. & Martin, L. (Eds.), The construction of social judgment (pp. 37–65). Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. [1, 26]Google Scholar
Wilson, T. D., Hodges, S. D., & LaFleur, S. J. (1995). Effects of introspecting about reasons: Inferring attitudes from accessible thoughts. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 68, 16–28. [29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, T. D., Houston, C. E., Etling, K. M., & Brekke, N. (1996). A new look at anchor ing effects: Basic anchoring and its antecedents. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 125, 387–402. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, T. D., & Kraft, D. (1993). Why do I love thee? Effects of repeated introspections about a dating relationship on attitudes toward the relationship. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 19, 409–418. [26]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, T. D., Kraft, D., & Dunn, D. S. (1989). The disruptive effects of explaining attitudes: The moderating effect of knowledge about the attitude object. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 25, 379–400. [26, 28]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, T. D., & LaFleur, S. J. (1993). [Effects of analyzing reasons on the accuracy of self-predictions]. Unpublished data, University of Virginia. [26]
Wilson, T. D., LaFleur, S. J., & Lindsey, J. S. (1995). Expertise and introspection: Analyzing the reasons for one's attitudes. Unpublished manuscript. [1]
Wilson, T. D., Lisle, D. J., Schooler, J. W., Hodges, S. D., Klaaren, K. J., & LaFleur, S. J. (1993). Introspecting about reasons can reduce post-choice satisfaction. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 19, 331–339. [1, 26, 30]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, T. D., & Schooler, J. W. (1991). Thinking too much: Introspection can reduce the quality of preferences and decisions. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 60, 181–192. [1, 22, 26, 28, 29, 34]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wilson, T. D., Wheatley, T., Meyers, J. M., Gilbert, D. T., & Axsom, D. (2000). Focalism: A source of durability bias in affective forecasting. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 78, 821–836. [28, 30]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wilson, W. R. (1979). Feeling more than we can know: Exposure effects without learn ing. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 37, 811–821. [25]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winer, B. J. (1971). Statistical principles in experimental design. New York: McGraw-Hill. [7]Google Scholar
Winkielman, P., Zajonc, R. B., & Schwarz, N. (1997). Subliminal affective priming resists attributional interventions. Cognition & Emotion, 11, 433–465. [23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wolf, J. S., Servino, E. M., & Nathan, H. N. (1997). National strategy to develop public acceptance of organ and tissue donation. Transplantation Proceedings, 29, 1477–1478. [37]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wood, W. (1982). Retrieval of attitude-relevant information from memory: Effects on susceptibility to persuasion and on intrinsic motivation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 42, 798–810. [26]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Woodworth, R. S., & Schlosberg, H. (1954). Experimental psychology. New York: Holt. [35]Google Scholar
Wortman, C. B., & Silver, R. C. (1989). The myths of coping with loss. Journal of Con sulting and Clinical Psychology, 57, 349–357. [30]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wright, A. A., & Lynch, J. G. (1995). Communication effects of advertising versus direct experience when both search and experience attributes are present. Journal of Consumer Research, 21, 708–718. [29, 32]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, P. L. (1975). Consumer choice strategies: Simplifying vs. optimizing. Journal of Marketing Research, 12, 60–67. [16, 17, 23]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, P. L., & Kriewall, M. A. (1980). State-of-mind effects on the accuracy with which utility functions predict marketplace choice. Journal of Marketing Research, 17, 277–293. [17, 34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, P. L., & Rip, P. D. (1980). Product class advertising effects on first time buyers' decision strategies. Journal of Consumer Research, 7, 176–188. [15]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, P. L., & Weitz, B. (1977). Time horizon effects on product evaluation strategies. Journal of Marketing Research, 14, 429–443. [34]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, W., & Bower, G. H. (1992). Mood effects on subjective probability assessment. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 52, 276–291. [24]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wu, G. (1999). Anxiety and decision making with delayed resolution of uncertainty. Theory and Decision, 46, 159–198. [32]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wu, G., & Gonzalez, R. (1996). Curvature of the probability weighting function. Management Science, 42, 1676–1690. [32]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wu, G., & Gonzalez, R. (1998). Common consequence effects in decision making under risk. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 16, 113–135. [32]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yaari, M., & Bar-Hillel, M. (1984). On dividing justly. Social Choice and Welfare, 1, 1–24. [20]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yalch, R. F., & Yalch, R. E. (1984). The effect of numbers on the route to persuasion. Journal of Consumer Research, 11, 522–527. [29]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yamagishi, K. (1997). When a 12.86% mortality is more dangerous than 24.14%: Impli cations for risk communication. Applied Cognitive Psychology, 11, 495–506. [23]3.0.CO;2-J>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yankelovich, D. (1991). Coming to public judgment: Making democracy work in a complex world. Syracuse, NY: Syracuse University Press. [34]Google Scholar
Yates, J. F. (1990). Judgment and decision making. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. [19]Google Scholar
Yi, Y. (1990). The effects of contextual priming in print advertisements. Journal of Consumer Research, 17, 215–222. [15]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zajonc, R. B. (1968). Attitudinal effects of mere exposure. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology Monograph, 9(2, Pt. 2), 1–27. [23, 25]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zajonc, R. B. (1980). Feeling and thinking: Preferences need no inferences. American Psychologist, 35, 151–175. [1, 19, 22, 23, 25, 27, 32]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zajonc, R. B. (2000). Feeling and thinking: Closing the debate over the independence of affect. In Forgas, J. P. (Ed.), Feeling and thinking: The role of affect in social cognition (pp. 31–58). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. [25]Google Scholar
Zajonc, R. B. (2001). Mere exposure: A gateway to the subliminal. Current Directions in Psychological Science, 10, 224–228. [1, 25]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zakay, D., & Tsal, Y. (1993). The impact of using forced decision making strategies on post-decision confidence. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 6, 53–68. [19]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zaller, J. (1992). The nature and origins of mass opinion. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. [31]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zinbarg, R. E., & Mohlman, J. (1998). Individual differences in the acquisition of affectively-valenced associations. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 74, 1024–1040. [24]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zola-Morgan, S., Squire, L. R., Alvarez-Royo, P., & Clower, R. P. (1991). Independence of memory functions and emotional behavior. Hippocampus, 1, 207–220. [25]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Zuckerman, M., Porac, J., Lathin, D., Smith, R., & Deci, E. L. (1978). On the impor tance of self-determination for intrinsically motivated behavior. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 4, 443–446. [16]CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×