Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-25wd4 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-25T11:16:04.750Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

3 - Adaptation Costs in One Dimension

Firms, Contracts, and Price Lists

from Part II - The Main Argument

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 November 2016

Birger Wernerfelt
Affiliation:
Massachusetts Institute of Technology
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Adaptation, Specialization, and the Theory of the Firm
Foundations of the Resource-Based View
, pp. 33 - 57
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2016

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alchian, Armen A., and Demsetz, Harold, “Production, Information Costs and Economic Organization,” American Economic Review, 62, December, 777–95, 1972.Google Scholar
Allen, Terry F., An Analysis of Food Brokers Versus Grocery Manufacturers’ Sales Forces. D.B.A. thesis, University of Virginia, 1984.Google Scholar
Anderson, Erin, The Salesperson as outside Agent or Employee: A Transaction Cost Analysis. Working paper. Cambridge, Mass.: Marketing Science Institute, pp. 84107, August, 1984.Google Scholar
Anderson, Erin, “The Salesperson as Outside Agent or Employee: A Transaction Cost Analysis,” Marketing Science, 4, Summer, 234–54, 1985.Google Scholar
Anderson, Erin, and Schmittlein, David C., “Integration of the Salesforce: An Empirical Examination,” RAND Journal of Economics, 15, Autumn, 385–95, 1984.Google Scholar
Aoki, M., “Horizontal vs. Vertical Information Structure of the Firm,” American Economic Review, 76, December, 971–83, 1986.Google Scholar
Barnard, Chester, The Functions of the Executive. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1938.Google Scholar
Ben-Porath, Yoram, “The F-Connection: Family, Friends, and Firms and the Organization of Exchange,” Population and Development Review, 6, March, 130, 1980.Google Scholar
Broadcast Music Inc. v. Columbia Broadcast System, 441 U.S. Report, Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1978.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H., “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica, n.s., 4, November, 386405, 1937.Google Scholar
Directory of Corporate Affiliations. New Providence, N.J.: National Register Publishing, 1996.Google Scholar
Dutta, Shantanu, Bergen, Mark, Heide, Jan B., and John, George, “Understanding Dual Distribution: The Case of Reps and House Accounts,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 11, April, 189204, 1995.Google Scholar
Etgar, Michael, “Effects of Administrative Control on Efficiency of Vertical Marketing Systems,” Journal of Marketing Research, 13, February, 1224, 1976.Google Scholar
Fenoaltea, Stefano, “Slavery and Supervision in Comparative Perspective: A Model,” Journal of Economic History, 44, September, 635–68, 1984.Google Scholar
Garvey, Gerald, and Swan, Peter L., The Fable of the Barge-pullers: An Advantage of Capitalistic over Worker-owned Organizations, Mimeographed. Sidney: University of New South Wales, 1992.Google Scholar
Gresik, Thomas A., and Satterthwaite, Mark A., “The Rate at Which a Simple Market Converges to Efficiency as the Number of Traders Increases: An Asymptotic Result for Optimal Trading Mechanisms,” Journal of Economic Theory, 48, 304–32, 1989.Google Scholar
Grossman, Sanford, and Hart, Oliver D., “The Costs and Benefits of Ownership,” Journal of Political Economy, 94, August, 691719, 1986.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grout, Paul A., “Investment and Wages in the Absence of Binding Contracts: A Nash Bargaining Approach,” Econometrica, 52, March, 449–60, 1984.Google Scholar
Hart, Oliver D., “An Economist’s Perspective on the Theory of the Firm,” Columbia Law Review, 89, November, 1757–74, 1989.Google Scholar
Hart, Oliver D., and Moore, John, “Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm,” Journal of Political Economy 98, December, 1119–58, 1990.Google Scholar
Holmstrom, Bengt, and Milgrom, Paul, “The Firm as an Incentive System,” American Economic Review, 84, September, 972–91, 1994.Google Scholar
Hurwicz, Leonid, “Optimality and Informational Efficiency in Resource Allocation Mechanisms,” in Arrow, Kenneth, Karlin, Samuel, and Suppes, Patrick (eds.), Mathematical Methods in the Social Sciences, Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1960.Google Scholar
Hurwicz, Leonid, “On Informationally Decentralized Systems,” in McGuire, C. Bartlett and Radner, Roy (eds.), Decision and Organization, Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1972.Google Scholar
Klein, Saul, Frazier, Gary L., and Roth, Victor J., “A Transaction Cost Analysis Model of Channel Integration in International Markets,” Journal of Marketing Research, 27, May, 196208, 1990.Google Scholar
Kreps, David M., “Corporate Culture and Economic Theory,” in Alt, J. and Shepsle, K. (eds.), Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990.Google Scholar
Lilien, Gary L., “ADVISOR 2: Modelling the Marketing Mix Decision for Industrial Products,” Management Science, 25, February, 191204, 1979.Google Scholar
Maskin, Eric, and Tirole, Jean, “Unforeseen Contingencies and Incomplete Contracts,” Review of Economic Studies, 66, 83114, 1999.Google Scholar
Masten, Scott E., “A Legal Basis for the Firm,” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 4, Spring, 181–98, 1988.Google Scholar
Milgrom, Paul, and Roberts, John, “Bargaining Costs, Influence Costs, and the Organization of Economic Activity,” in Alt, J. and Shepsle, K. (eds.), Perspectives on Positive Political Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990.Google Scholar
Myerson, Roger B., and Satterthwaite, Mark A., “Efficient Mechanisms for Bilateral Trading,” Journal of Economic Theory, 29, 265–81, 1983.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Radner, Roy, “The Organization of Decentralized Information Processing,” Econometrica, 61, September, 1109–46, 1993.Google Scholar
Radner, Roy, and Van Zandt, Timothy, “Information Processing in Firms and Returns to Scale,” Annales d’Economie et de Statistique, 25, no. 26, 265–98, 1992.Google Scholar
Radner, Roy, and Van Zandt, Timothy, “Information Processing and Returns to Scale in Statistical Decision Problems,” Mimeographed, Murray Hill, N.J.: AT&T Bell Labs, 1993.Google Scholar
Schotter, Andrew, The Economic Theory of Social Institutions, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, Herbert A., “A Formal Theory of the Employment Relationship,” Econometrica, 19, July, 293305, 1951.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A., Administrative Behaviour, 3rd edition, New York: Free Press 1976.Google Scholar
Stephens, M., Bibliography of Information Sources on Manufacturers’ Representatives, Geneva, Ill.: Manufacturers’ Representatives Educational Research Foundation, 1993.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J., “The Division of Labor is Limited by the Extent of the Market,” Journal of Political Economy, 59, June, 185–93, 1951.Google Scholar
Taylor, Ronald K., Profiling Differences between Manufacturers’ Representatives and Direct Company Salespeople: An Exploratory Study, D.B.A. thesis, University of Indiana, 1988.Google Scholar
Department of the Treasury, Internal Revenue Service, Business Reporting Publication 937, Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of the Treasury, 1990.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E., “Hierarchical Control and Optimum Firm Size,” Journal of Political Economy, 75, April, 123–38, 1967.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E., “Transaction-cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Relations,” Journal of Law and Economics, 22, October, 223–61, 1979.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E., The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, New York: Free Press, 1985.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×