Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-hfldf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-09T03:42:37.284Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Part 2 - Protean Power: Embracing Uncertainty

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 December 2017

Peter J. Katzenstein
Affiliation:
Cornell University, New York
Lucia A. Seybert
Affiliation:
American University, Washington DC

Summary

Type
Chapter
Information
Protean Power
Exploring the Uncertain and Unexpected in World Politics
, pp. 57 - 144
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2018
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NC
This content is Open Access and distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence CC-BY-NC 4.0 https://creativecommons.org/cclicenses/

3 Protean Power and Revolutions in Rights

Christian Reus-Smit

Revolutions in rights are always momentous and always surprising. With hindsight, we find ways to explain them: attributing interests, sketching institutional architectures, unearthing material substrata, and artfully tracing key mechanisms and processes. But at the time, on the ground, in the turmoil of real-time politics, revolutions in rights have been either the stuff of dreams – long-term yet evolving objectives, animating activism that is one part strategy, two parts seat-of-the-pants innovation – or barely credible threats, unimaginable transformations of political orders defended by invested elites, backed by material might, and undergirded by old values codified in law. Revolutions in rights are always the product of struggle, generally long and sustained. Yet their triumphs come with a rush. Undercurrents of change break the surface, and suddenly the impossible becomes real: long hostile public opinion swings, new institutional opportunities hand activists unexpected victories, coercion becomes counterproductive, opponents lose the will to fight what was once beyond the pale, and all of a sudden, what constitutes a recognized fundamental right transforms, or the category of humans entitled to such rights expands. The same story has played out time and again: with anti-slavery, workers’ rights, women’s rights, indigenous rights, and now rights to marriage equality.

The surprising nature of revolutions in rights raises far-reaching questions about the nature of power. Two things stand out. First, how rights are defined and allocated affects the distribution of legitimate power in any social order in which individual rights are the prevailing form of moral and legal entitlement.Footnote 1 Rights are legitimate powers. They entitle rights-holders to act in particular ways, and circumscribe legitimate action beyond the domain of rights. They demand the exercise of political authority in some areas, but also circumscribe it. Second, because regimes of rights structure the organization of legitimate power in a social order, struggles for rights are struggles for power, and revolutions in rights are the product of such struggles. Yet the workings of power within these revolutions is only partially captured by our prevailing conceptions. For Lucia Seybert and Peter Katzenstein (Chapter 1), these conceptions understand power as control, as the ability to exercise control in situations of calculable risk. Evidence of such power can certainly be found in revolutionary struggles for rights: establishment elites have routinely exercised their material and institutional capabilities in calculated attempts to prevent change, often succeeding for long periods of time. The power that ultimately produces change, however, has been far more complex, and cannot be reduced to actors’ capabilities exercised under conditions of calculable risk. In all struggles, uncertainty has been the order of the day, and power has come, often unexpectedly, through innovation in an order’s cracks and contradictions, not control.

This chapter explores the nature and workings of this “protean” form of power, focusing on a particularly consequential revolution in rights, that associated with the codification of the 1945 human rights regime and the associated reconstitution of the right to self-determination. As I have shown elsewhere, today’s global system of sovereign states is the product of successive waves of imperial collapse, the most significant of which were driven by struggles for individual rights.Footnote 2 Post-1945 decolonization was the most momentous of these waves: not only did multiple empires collapse, but so too did the institution of empire. Conventional accounts attribute this transformation to a shift in control power: after the Second World War, European powers lost their material capacity to control their empires; the new superpowers, the United States and the Soviet Union, were both anti-imperial; and local anti-colonial struggles raging across multiple empires defeated the European powers on the ground. Common though this view is, it sits uncomfortably with the facts. After the war most imperial powers reasserted their commitment to empire, and their material frailties were evident in some colonies but not in others. Washington’s anti-imperialism waned with the onset of the Cold War, and it ended up siding with the imperial powers to oppose any right to self-determination. The Soviet Union’s rhetorical opposition to empire was contradicted by its own quasi-imperial structure, and its stance in anti-colonial debates was increasingly at odds with that of leading post-colonial states. Local anti-colonial struggles varied greatly in strength, and cannot be credited with the near simultaneous collapse of multiple empires, or the demise of the institution of empire itself. Post-1945 decolonization was the product of a struggle for power, but it was protean power, entangled in a complex rights revolution that drove change, not control power.

The discussion proceeds in two parts. The first is theoretical. Building on Seybert’s and Katzenstein’s conception of protean power, I advance three propositions: radical uncertainty is a condition of all systems of rule; some ideas are politically dynamic and defy control; and actors innovate within the cracks and contradictions of institutional complexes, understood as arrays of co-existing, overlapping, but often discordant singular institutions (in this case, the post-1945 complex of persistent empires and the emerging universal institutions of the United Nations [UN], but a phenomenon also highlighted by Phillip Ayoub (Chapter 4) as well as Noelle Brigden and Peter Andreas (Chapter 5). Taken together, these propositions challenge Stephen Krasner’s oft-quoted argument about power in a world of normative complexity. States encounter multiple, often contradictory, international norms, he contends, allowing materially powerful actors to select norms that serve their strategic interests. “In an environment characterized by multiple norms, power asymmetries, and the absence of authoritative structures that could resolve conflict, rulers can select among strategies that deploy normative as well as material resources in different and sometimes original ways.”Footnote 3 Normative complexity thus favors the exercise of control power. Yet in the argument that follows precisely the opposite is true. If the uncertainty inherent to institutional complexes privileges any kind of power, it is protean power not control power. When the meaning of norms is indeterminate, and when multiple norms co-exist in institutional complexes, uncertainty overwhelms the calculable, and innovation in the cracks and contradictions of an institutional complex can challenge the exercise of control. Part 2 illustrates these propositions with reference to the revolution in rights that drove the wholesale decolonization of Europe’s empires and the emergence of a universal system of sovereign states.

Radical Uncertainty

Michael Barnett and Raymond Duvall identify four conceptions of power: compulsory, institutional, structural, and productive. Compulsory power “focuses on a range of relations between actors that allow one to shape directly the circumstances and/or actions of another,” and institutional power concerns “the formal and informal institutions that mediate between A and B, as A, working through the rules and procedures that define those institutions, guides, steers, and constrains the actions (or non-actions) and conditions of existence of others, sometimes even unknowingly.”Footnote 4 With structural and productive power, agency is more diffuse and obscure. Structural power “produces the very social capacities of structural, or subject, positions in direct relation to one another,” while productive power constitutes social subjects “through social systems of knowledge and discursive practices of broad and general scope.”Footnote 5 While this framework accommodates many of the existing ways that international relations scholars understand power, the “protean” power emphasized in this volume sits uncomfortably within its conceptual distinctions. Control power is easily assimilated within the categories of compulsory or institutional power, but, as we shall see, protean power confounds these categories, particularly institutional power. Furthermore, while protean power can change actor’s subjectivities, as well as their structural positions, how this works is not easily accommodated within conventional notions of structural or productive power. Crucially, protean power comes to the fore under conditions of uncertainty, conditions inimical to structural control.

Seybert and Katzenstein distinguish between two kinds of uncertainty. Operational uncertainty consists of known unknowns, and can, at least in theory, be transformed by greater knowledge into the world of risk. Radical uncertainty is characterized by unknown unknowns, which “are unknowable and cannot be converted to risk” (Katzenstein and Seybert, Chapter 2, p. 41). The closer one moves to the second of these, the more uncertainty appears not simply as a cognitive condition – a lack of knowledge – but an inherent feature of complexity. Some contexts are relatively simple and are amenable to control through the calculation of risk. But increasingly actors must navigate complex, polycentric social, political, and economic contexts in which uncertainty is an existential condition. Furthermore, complex contexts have constitutive effects, creating social subjects. Innovators are not free-wheeling entrepreneurs who step, pre-constituted, into complex environments and work their magic. As Chapter 6 on science and start-ups shows, innovators are products of uncertainty bred of complexity. Innovation is a knowledgeable practice, learnt through engagement with the demands of uncertainty. And “innovator” is a social identity, clearly apparent in Sergey Brin’s recent declaration that “Google is not a conventional company. We do not intend to become one.”Footnote 6

To understand the workings of protean power in rights revolutions, the concept of radical uncertainty requires further elaboration, as does its distinctive manifestation in struggles for rights. In what follows, I advance three propositions. The first is the general proposition that uncertainty can take radical forms, where unknowable unknowns are hard-wired into complex contexts. The second and third focus on two aspects of radical uncertainty peculiar to revolutions in rights: the open, dynamic nature of rights themselves, and the uncertainty inherent to institutional complexes.

Beyond Cognitive Uncertainty

Some kinds of uncertainty are contextual, others are not. If I sit down to work out a tough problem in mathematics, I am sure to be uncertain about how to proceed: how do I break it down, what techniques do I employ to solve each part, how do I put it all together? My uncertainty is real, but it is not contextual: it derives from the limits of my cognitive capacities, and the puzzling nature of an abstract, deontological equation. This is in contrast to other forms of uncertainty that have less to do with my cognitive limitations than with the social context in which I seek to act. Practice theorists speak of an actor’s social competence, defined as socially recognized mastery of a practice or practices.Footnote 7 I might be a fully competent actor, a recognized master of relevant practices, but still encounter contexts marked by endemic uncertainty. Diplomats – recognized masters of diplomatic practice – spend most of their time navigating such contexts. No degree of competence renders such contexts controllable arenas of calculable risk: uncertainty is hard-wired into their complex configurations.

As noted above, when Seybert and Katzenstein think about uncertainty and risk, they do so in contextual and experiential terms: from the perspective of the observer, contexts can be uncertain or risky, and actors within such contexts may, or may not, experience them as such (Seybert and Katzenstein, Chapter 1, p. 13, Figure 1.1). This emphasis on experience and context is evident in their desire to accommodate both control and protean power. While they criticize the field’s overemphasis on control power, they do not deny its existence or relevance to world politics. Indeed, they insist that some contexts – those that most closely approximate closed laboratory systems – are, from the perspective of the observer, amenable to the exercise of such power, to control through the calculation of risk. Their point, however, is that contexts such as these are far from the norm. World politics is increasingly characterized by complex “open social systems,” in which inherent uncertainty defies control and the effective calculation of risk. Uncertainty is thus a feature of a particular kind of context, and protean power is a product of innovation, a knowledgeable practice impelled by uncertainty.

Uncertainty is not simply an externality generated by particular kinds of context though. Whether or not relevant actors fully experience it, uncertainty can be an intrinsic feature of those contexts. It would be an externality if all that was involved was complexity, where the sheer openness, multidimensional character, and tangled intersections of a context produced a host of known unknowns: what Seybert and Katzenstein term operational uncertainty (Chapter 2). Here uncertainty would be a product of unmanageable knowledge demands, impeding reasonable calculations of risk. This kind of uncertainty is common, but it often goes hand in hand with radical uncertainties. An uncertainty is radical if it comprises unknowable unknowns, if it cannot be reduced to attributes of the actors’ in the prevailing context, and if it conditions actors’ identities, interests, and actions. Quantum theory tells us that such uncertainties are inherent to the physical universe, but they can also be ideational.Footnote 8 Indeed, radical uncertainties are endemic to all complex institutional environments, where webs of intersubjective meanings structure social action. This is because such meanings are inherently indeterminate, open to diverse and often contradictory interpretations. Much has been written about the indeterminacy of legal rules, for example. While often touted as the most objective of all meanings, they are rendered indeterminate by both the “semantic openness of legal speech” (words and phrases can be open to diverse interpretation), and by contradictory reasons that generated the speech in the first place.Footnote 9

My claim here is a strong one. Intersubjective meanings, whether embedded in norms, rules, or practices, whether formal or informal, generate radical uncertainties. These uncertainties are more than the known unknowns of operational uncertainty; they involve unknown – and unknowable – unknowns. Even in the realm of common law, where formal processes of judicial interpretation are informed by accumulated precedents, the scope of possible interpretations remains unknowable. This is not only because of the inherent indeterminacy of the law, but because the social domain of interpretation is not confined to formal legal processes. In many areas the meaning of legal rules is the subject of broad political debate, in which the scope and substance of interpretation has a relative autonomy from formal judicial reasoning. This is especially true in the international realm, where authoritative interpretation remains rare. Debate over the legality of the 2003 Iraq War, for example, was not confined to the UN Security Council, and debate within the Council did not determine how the Charter and past Council resolutions were interpreted in the broader political domain.

The radical uncertainty that attends intersubjective meanings is why Stephen Brooks and William Wohlforth are wrong when they claim that the United States, as the unipolar power, can define the terms of its own legitimacy. To be sure, dominant powers – unipoles, hegemons, or the like – have unrivaled capacities to mobilize and codify particular meanings, but this is not the same as controlling meanings. In an artful response to claims about America’s declining legitimacy, Brooks and Wohlforth accept the importance of legitimacy, but insist that if transnational advocacy networks can mobilize norms in legitimacy contests, so too can a unipole, with an order of magnitude of greater capacity. “Advantages in power capabilities,” they contend, “expand the range and scope of various strategies the United States can use to build legitimacy and mold institutions to its purposes.”Footnote 10 Put differently, for Brooks and Wohlforth control power determines legitimacy. But even if a unipole enjoys certain advantages in the mobilization of meanings – and Washington’s skill in this has been less than striking in recent years – the indeterminacy of relevant norms, and the complex institutional environment in which normative contestation takes place, leaves considerable scope for interpretive innovation and struggle. Indeed, the politics of legitimacy engaged by the United States evinces little evidence of control. To the contrary, American legitimacy has been conditioned by a swirling mix of control and protean power, the latter generated by supposedly weak but innovative actors exploiting the radical uncertainty that attends normative indeterminacy and complexity.Footnote 11

Revolutions in rights have been profoundly affected by the radical uncertainties associated with meaning indeterminacy. To begin with, as we shall see below, the very idea of a general individual right, which has repeatedly animated such revolutions, is inherently dynamic: its constituent ideas provoke ever more expansive interpretation. Again, my claim here is a strong one. It is commonplace to describe some concepts as “essentially contested,” in the sense that they can circulate widely, be invoked frequently in public debate, but be understood differently by different actors. Power, culture, democracy, etc. are classic examples. I want to suggest more than this, though: that some ideas, by their very nature, provoke debate, invite ever more expansive interpretation, and defy control. General individual rights are a prime example. Second, actors have mobilized and contested such ideas within multilayered, highly variegated institutional contexts: some formal, some informal. These contexts are riddled with cracks and contradictions that enable some forms of mobilization and struggle while foreclosing others.

General Individual Rights

The revolutions in rights that interest me here have all been about general individual rights, of which human rights are a species. Individual rights can take two forms: “special” rights and “general” rights. A special right is one that an individual holds by virtue of a particular transaction or social relationship in which they stand or are engaged. A good example are the rights an individual acquires when contracting to buy or sell a house. The contract of sale grants both the vendor and the purchaser individual rights – rights that would not exist without the contract, and rights only the parties to that contract hold. This type of rights is in contrast to general individual rights. An individual has such rights not because of particular transactions or social relationships, but because they are said to constitute a particular kind of moral being. Human rights are the best examples of such rights. As explained elsewhere, “individuals have such rights because they are human beings: normative agents with the capacity to ‘form pictures of what a good life would be’ and to ‘try and realize these pictures.’ Individuals have human rights to protect these capacities, to safeguard their moral ‘personhood.’”Footnote 12

Two forms of indeterminacy are built into the idea of general individual rights. The first concerns their scope: what are they rights to? If they are meant to safeguard an individual’s moral personhood, what kind of rights are essential to this end? Reaching a definitive answer to this question is probably impossible, as is evident in the persistent debate about what constitute essential human rights: civil and political rights, social and economic rights, or some combination thereof? The second form of indeterminacy concerns the zone of application of individual rights: the group of individuals who, at any given historical moment, are thought to be moral beings worthy of such rights. We now assume that all biological humans are entitled to general individual rights, thus rendering them “human” rights in the full sense. Yet for most of the history of general rights only a portion of the human population has been deemed moral beings with such entitlements. The norm has been for a select group to assert their status as such beings while confidently denying that other human beings qualified. Slaves, followers of other religions, unpropertied men, colonialized peoples, women, indigenous peoples, homosexuals, and transsexuals have all found themselves excluded from the zone of application.

In what follows I am particularly interested in this second kind of indeterminacy. The idea of a general individual right depends on the existence of qualified moral beings. Not only are such beings the bearers of general rights, their perceived needs determine what these rights are. Yet defining what such a moral being is, and who among all biological humans qualify, is an entirely subjective enterprise. All sorts of arguments have been used historically to define the zone of application in one way or another. Religion, race, civilization, property, gender, and sexuality have all been invoked to justify patterns of inclusion and exclusion. None have ever come close to being objective, as what constitutes a worthy moral being can be defined only with reference to other subjective values. Added to this, any non-universal attempt to define such beings, and to draw an exclusionary zone of application, has been politically contentious. As explained above, how rights are allocated in a social order affects the distribution of legitimate power, often in life and death ways. Any non-universal definition of the zone of application simultaneously empowers some while disempowering others, giving the latter powerful incentives to challenge prevailing definitions of the moral subject and expand the zone of application. Herein lies the inherent political dynamism of the idea of general individual rights. Non-universal definitions of the zone of application beg revision, almost always through struggle. And the bounds of such revision, and the potential scope of struggle, is as indeterminate as the concept of a qualified moral being. This is evident in the discussion of decolonization that follows, and in Phillip Ayoub’s analysis of LGBT rights (Chapter 4). Even drawing the line around all biological humans has proven to be controversial, as attempts persist to exclude some humans as being morally incompetent or compromised, and calls are made to extend basic rights to non-human species: great apes, for example.

Institutional Complexes

If radical uncertainty can be a product of the meaning indeterminacy that attends general individual rights, this is compounded by the institutional environments in which actors have mobilized and contested rights claims. Institutions are commonly defined as “stable sets of norms, rules, and principles that serve two functions in shaping social relations: they constitute actors as knowledgeable social agents, and they regulate behavior.”Footnote 13 Institutions, so understood, are thought to be embedded in, and reproduced by, actors’ routinized social practices: they are the product not only of what actors think and say, but what they do.Footnote 14 As the rights case illustrates, actors navigate their way through multiple, often contradictory, institutions simultaneously, and since meaning indeterminacy is inherent to all of their constituent rules and norms, radical uncertainty is accentuated, both as an observed reality of institutional environments and the lived experiences of actors themselves (locating the institutional politics of rights in the lower right-hand quadrant of Figure 1.1).

It is common in international relations to theorize institutional behavior as though actors exist within single institutions. Regime theorists studied the regulatory effects of an institution – the GATT, the NPT, the EU, etc. – on the actors operating within that institution. Similarly, most constructivist work on the constitutive effects of social norms has focused on single norms: how they emerge, how they socialize actors, and now, how they erode. The idea that actors might operate within multiple institutions features only at the margins. Regime theorists acknowledge that actors forum-shop, jumping from one institutional arena to another in a strategic effort to maximize gains. In the end, though, all this says is that utility-maximizing actors who face a menu of institutional options will gravitate toward the optimal single institution. Constructivists talk about the grafting of norms, how norm entrepreneurs seed new norms by appealing “to values higher than those which they want to justify, by proving that the latter are but an interpretation of the higher values, or that they can be related to these higher values without logical contradiction.”Footnote 15 These remain stories, however, of the construction of single norms, albeit in association with other extant norms.

In reality, actors exist within, and spend their lives navigating, complexes of multiple institutions. The regulatory effects of any one institution (in the field of climate change, for example) will depend on how it stands in relation to the other institutions actors engage (such as in the area of trade). And how actors are constituted as knowledgeable social agents will be determined by the highly variegated, often contradictory, institutional complexes in which they are socialized, complexes that by definition vary from one individual actor to another. The crucial thing for our purposes is that radical uncertainty in institutional complexes is doubly determined. Not only do the norms, rules, and practices of individual institutions suffer meaning indeterminacy, institutional complexes are riddled with cracks and contradictions, generating yet another layer of uncertainty. This doubly determined uncertainty is evident in current international legal debates, where recognition of the indeterminacy of legal rules is joined by growing consternation about the proliferation of overlapping and contradictory legal instruments and mechanisms that threaten to dissolve the international legal order into a fragmented institutional complex.Footnote 16

The Instability of Mixed Worlds

Seybert and Katzenstein (Chapter 1, p. 10, Table 1.1) rightly argue that pure worlds of calculable risk and control power, on the one hand, and uncertainty and protean power, on the other, are ideal types. Real worlds are always mixed. Arenas of calculable risk that permit control always co-exist with radical and operational uncertainties that demand innovation and improvisation, producing often transformative circuits of protean power. To capture this, Seybert and Katzenstein propose an interactive approach: these “two kinds of power co-exist and co-evolve” (Chapter 1, p. 5). Nothing in this chapter contests this proposition. I want to suggest, however, that mixed worlds of risk and uncertainty, and control and protean power, can be far from stable. Indeed, in crucial cases they are not only unstable, but pull toward uncertainty, innovation, and protean power.

This is especially true in the case of systems of rule. Systems of rule are the framing arenas for politics, and international systems of rule, whether we call them systems, societies, or orders, provide the political architecture for international politics. They define the political game – the principal political units, how they stand in relation to one another, and the bounds of acceptable political action – and their rise and fall alters the basic parameters of political life. International systems of rule take multiple forms, varying principally according to their organizing principles. Some are sovereign, some are suzerain, some are heteronomous, and, importantly for us, some are hybrids. What matters, though, is that stable systems of rule – whatever their form – cannot rest on control power alone. The quintessential form of such power is compulsory: the ability of “one to shape directly the circumstances and/or actions of another,”Footnote 17 an ability derived from the material command of the distribution of risk. But as Edmund Burke pointed out in a classic statement, “the use of force is but temporary. It may subdue for a moment, but it does not remove the necessity of subduing again; and a nation is not governed, which is to be perpetually conquered.”Footnote 18 Stable systems of rule depend on something additional, on legitimacy: the “generalized perception or assumption that the actions of an entity are desirable, proper, appropriate within some socially constructed system of norms, values, beliefs, and definitions.”Footnote 19

Yet as soon as legitimacy enters the equation, so too does uncertainty. To begin with, legitimacy is in the eye of the beholder. Auto-legitimation is impossible; it always depends on the perceptions of others, and these are difficult to control as millennia of politicians have discovered. At best, perceptions of legitimacy are known unknowns. Second, perceptions of legitimacy, as the Suchman quote indicates, are norm-referential. Actors make legitimacy judgments with reference to interpretations of prevailing intersubjective understandings about rightful agency and action. But this brings us into the realm of meaning indeterminacy, where norms, rules, and practices can be open to diverse, and at times contradictory, interpretations. Struggles over legitimacy sometimes see actors appealing to radically different norms or principles, but often contests are over the meaning of the same norms. Finally, legitimacy is seldom constructed, sustained, or contested in singular institutional contexts. More commonly, the politics of legitimacy plays out within highly variegated institutional complexes. When this is combined with the meaning indeterminacy of legitimating norms, the context of uncertainty moves from operational to radical.

If this is true, surely mixed worlds are likely to be stable? A stable system of rule, for example, might settle on an optimal balance of control and legitimacy, risk and uncertainty. While theoretically possible, two empirical reasons suggest otherwise. Seybert and Katzenstein (Chapter 2) argue that open systems are inherently uncertain and privilege innovation and, in turn, protean power. The openness of a system is generally understood in interactional terms, but systems can be open epistemically as well. New ideas can enter a system through creativity – the artful fashioning of new knowledge out of extant ideational resources – and through cross-fertilization and localization: two forms of innovation. Systems of rule are open systems in both interactional and epistemic terms, and the structures and practices of legitimation that sustain them are always vulnerable to the creation and conscription of new ideas. The second reason has to do with elite incapacity. When the mobilization of new ideas challenges the legitimacy of a system of rule, elites can either recalibrate the system’s legitimacy, or they can compensate for a legitimacy deficit by deploy-ing greater control power: most commonly, coercion and bribery. Historically, in the great rights revolutions that have transformed international orders, elites have almost always chosen the second of these paths, ultimately compounding the crisis of legitimacy. For both of these reasons, I suggest, mixed systems, if systems of rule are anything to go by, pull toward uncertainty and protean power, and artful politics is needed to sustain any balance.

Rights and Universal Sovereignty

Today’s global system of rule has one feature that distinguishes it from all prior international orders: universal state sovereignty. Systems of sovereign states have been rare in world history, and always regional affairs: Ancient Greece; the warring states period in China; Renaissance Italy; and post-Westphalian Europe. Today’s order is unique in being global, and unique in having a single legitimate form of polity: the sovereign state. Furthermore, this novel global order is very young, emerging fully only in the wake of post-1945 decolonization. Prior to this, a hybrid order organized political life across most of the globe, an order in which sovereignty in the European core was institutionally tied to empire in the non-European periphery. The transition from sovereign/imperial order to universal sovereignty was one of the momentous shifts in the global configuration of political authority in world history.

The dismantling of the sovereign/imperial order occurred over several centuries, propelled by a series of great imperial implosions: the eighteenth- and nineteenth-centuries collapse of Europe’s empires in the Americas; the early twentieth-century break-up of the Austro-Hungarian, German, and Ottoman empires; and then, most dramatically, the total dissolution of Europe’s remaining empires after 1945. Across these waves of imperial fragmentation, the sovereign core of the hybrid order gradually expanded: the number of recognized sovereign states grew, eventually drawing in non-European states, and the institutional norms of the sovereign order clarified and consolidated. It was not until the final act, however – post-1945 decolonization – that empire, as a legitimate form of rule, was discredited. Individual empires might have fallen, each suffering their own distinct crisis of legitimacy, but the institution of empire remained robust well into the second half of the twentieth century. As Edward Keene explains, until post-1945 decolonization, Europeans (and Westerners more generally) were quite comfortable “adopting one kind of relationship, equality and mutual independence, as the norm in their dealings with each other, and another, imperial paramountcy, as normal in their relations with non-Europeans.”Footnote 20 It was not until the 1960s that these norms were finally undercut, leaving the hybrid order without legitimating foundations.

As noted in the introduction, conventional accounts of post-1945 decolonization emphasize shifts in control power: the waning of metropolitan power; the rise of anti-imperial superpowers; and the diffusion of power to anti-colonial nationalists. According to such accounts, Europe’s far-flung empires were held together by the imperial powers’ material might. After half a century of world war such might no longer existed, and the balance of global power had shifted to the United States and the Soviet Union, both of whom were anti-imperial. Added to this, Europe’s grip on empire was undercut by anti-colonial wars in Africa and Asia, wars that the Europeans lacked both the will and capacity to defeat. Common though this view is, it is contradicted by the facts. The Europeans were greatly weakened by a half a century of war, but in most cases weakness encouraged renewed commitments to empire. The United States and the Soviet Union had long touted their anti-imperial credentials, but as the Cold War intensified, Washington fell in behind the imperial powers, and Moscow’s brand of anti-imperialism clashed with that emanating from much of the colonial world. Anti-colonial struggles were waged in many colonies, but not all were destined for success, and local struggles cannot explain the wholesale dissolution of Europe’s empires.

The greatest failing of these accounts, however, is that shifts in the balance of control power tell us little about arguably the most important feature of post-1945 decolonization: that it involved not only the simultaneous collapse of multiple empires across the globe, but also, and most significantly, the moral disintegration of the institution of empire itself. In the space of two decades, empire went from being the norm, a thoroughly acceptable system of rule, to a moral, if not a legal, crime. The institution of empire suffered a profound crisis of legitimacy from which it never recovered. Scholars debate whether the United States is an imperial power – a move that stretches the concept too far in my view – and some like Niall Ferguson think Washington should come clean and embrace this status.Footnote 21 But since the 1960s no state concerned with its moral standing could make such a declaration: “empire” became, and has remained, a term of moral opprobrium.

A focus on control power cannot explain the collapse of the institution of empire, a key factor in the rapid and simultaneous disintegration of multiple particular empires. To understand this collapse, we need to see it for what it was: a collapse in legitimacy. In 1945, the drafters of the UN Charter could still describe Western tutelage of non-Western peoples as a “sacred trust,” but by the 1970s, UN General Assembly Resolution 2621 called “the continuation of colonialism in all its forms and manifestations a crime.”Footnote 22 By 1960, the legitimacy of empire had all but disintegrated, and this in turn undercut the last vestiges of local imperial legitimacy. In the decade following the 1960 UN Declaration on the Granting of Independence to Colonial Countries and Peoples the rate of decolonization tripled, from 1.26 new states per year between 1946 and 1960 to 3.86 per year thereafter.Footnote 23

To understand the crisis that befell the institution of empire, we need to see empires as systemic hierarchies: they rest on an unequal distribution of authority between the core and periphery, and a differential allocation of social and political entitlements between metropolitan citizens and colonial subjects. Elsewhere I call these “regimes of unequal entitlements,”Footnote 24 regimes comprising differential special rights (grounded in custom and law, and derived from social position). In empires, a central political challenge sustains the legitimacy of these regimes, both within the metropole and among subject peoples. From the late eighteenth century onward, Europeans justified such regimes with reference to a standard of civilization that in the nineteenth century they codified in international law. This standard, which divided humanity into civilized, barbarian, and savage peoples, placed Europeans at the top of a human pyramid and licensed both their domination/tutelage of the non-European world, as well as the unjust distribution of social and political entitlements within their individual empires.Footnote 25

The dramatic collapse of imperial legitimacy was the product of artful innovation under conditions of radical uncertainty – uncertainty generated by institutional complexity and norm indeterminacy. The struggles over imperial legitimacy that intensified after 1945 took place within a distinctive institutional complex. In the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, the institutional arena for struggles over imperial legitimacy was predominantly intra-imperial. For example, both the Concert of Europe and the Holy Alliance were concerned with the fate of the Spanish empire in the Americas, but anti-colonial forces had no access to these institutions. It was insurgent Cortes of Cadiz, formed in response to Napoleon’s usurpation of the Spanish crown, that provided the principal, intra-imperial institutional setting for debates over the empire’s legitimacy. With the Versailles peace negotiations and eventual settlement after the First World War a more complex institutional environment emerged, in which struggles over imperial legitimacy could play out both within individual empires and in the embryonic fora of the League of Nations. After 1945, this multidimensional institutional context received ever greater elaboration, as the UN developed not only an increasingly robust general assembly of states, but also emergent human rights fora charged with negotiating an international bill of rights. Proponents and critics of empire were thus faced with a highly variegated institutional context, in which local imperial institutions co-existed with new supranational institutional arenas.

This new institutional complex significantly empowered purportedly weak actors, most notably newly independent post-colonial states that joined the UN in its first decade. The emergent institutions of the UN provided unexpected spaces in which to innovate with key norms of international society, particularly those pertaining to membership and legitimate statehood. Crucial here were UN bodies charged with negotiating the two binding international covenants on human rights: the Human Rights Commission and the Third Committee of the General Assembly. As others have shown, the UN’s founders were far from anti-imperial, and the early architects of its human rights instruments did not see them as a tool against empire.Footnote 26 Yet newly independent post-colonial states found spaces in the UN’s emergent human rights bodies in which to redefine and rehabilitate the collective right to self-determination, grafting it onto evolving human rights norms.

After Versailles the right to self-determination was defined as a right of ethnically defined nations, and only those within Europe. This conception emerged from the Second World War as morally and politically denuded. The Nazi Holocaust cast a pall over any claims to ethnic exclusivity, and the idea that only ethnically defined nations could claim self-determination was of little use to colonial peoples in Africa, Asia, and the Pacific, most of whom were ethnically heterogeneous. If such a right was to be of any use after 1945 it had to be reconstituted by placing it on more universalist foundations. Newly independent post-colonial states – such as India, Pakistan, the Philippines, and Lebanon, working closely with key Latin American states – used UN human rights fora to achieve this reconstitution.

There is a long-standing myth, taught to all students of human rights, that the international human rights regime was a Western achievement: a myth that gives pride of place to enlightened liberal powers, especially the United States, and iconic norm entrepreneurs, such as Eleanor Roosevelt. The truth is almost the reverse. The myth holds that African and Asian states favored social and economic rights over civil and political rights. But while this was consistently the Soviet Union’s position, key post-colonial states insisted on the primacy of civil and political rights. When debating the Universal Declaration of Human Rights, the Soviet Union tried to subordinate civil and political rights, to which India asserted that it “would never agree to restricting political rights in order to realize social aims.”Footnote 27 The myth also holds that Western states were strongly committed to the universality of human rights. In reality, Australia, Canada, and the United States joined Europe’s imperial powers in seeking to limit the application of human rights norms within colonial territories and federal states. Again, it was newly independent post-colonial states who defeated these moves, thus ensuring a universal zone of application. It was these states who put the “human” in human rights.Footnote 28

What we see here is innovation bred of norm indeterminacy. As noted earlier, human rights, as general individual rights, suffer from two forms of indeterminacy, both stemming from the idea of a worthy moral being. The first concerns the scope of such rights: what rights are essential to protect someone’s moral personhood? The debate about the relative priority of civil and political rights over social and economic rights reflects this indeterminacy. The second concerns the zone of application of core human rights; a zone the new UN institutional fora enabled post-colonial states to expand.

Post-colonial states redefined and rehabilitated the right to self-determination by grafting it onto the emergent human rights norms they were fashioning. This enabled them to transform a norm previously restricted to ethnically defined nations within Europe to a norm of universal reach. The connection was first made by Afghanistan and Saudi Arabia in 1950 when they moved a motion in the Third Committee of the General Assembly calling on the Human Rights Commission to study “the right of peoples and nations to self-determination.” When the Commission failed to do so, post-colonial states called on the General Assembly to compel the Commission to include an article on self-determination in the draft covenants, arguing that “no basic human rights could be ensured unless this right were ensured.”Footnote 29 The Commission not only went ahead and included the requested articles in both covenants, but asked the General Assembly to pass a resolution encouraging states to uphold the right. Resolution 637(A), adopted in 1952, states explicitly that “the right of peoples and nations to self-determination is a prerequisite for the enjoyment of all fundamental human rights.”Footnote 30 In his well-publicized attempt to cast human rights as a post-1970s revolution, and to deny that decolonization had anything to do with human rights, Samuel Moyn misinterprets the meaning of “prerequisite” here. While he assumes that it meant normatively primary, to post-colonial states it meant no such thing. For them, fundamental human rights could not be secured unless people were self-determining, not that self-determination was a higher value than such rights.Footnote 31

In Seybert’s and Katzenstein’s schema, protean power is an unintended effect of the innovative practices of knowledgeable actors, in which “micro-level” actions produce “macro” outcomes. In revolutions in rights, such as the one discussed above, this played out in complex ways. First, the model suggests that innovative actors can generate transformative protean power unintentionally. Intentionality is complicated in the rights case, though. Actors innovating with rights who intend to produce transformative protean power, or actors innovating with rights with no such intention, do not exhaust the range of possibilities. Rights are not just tools of innovation, they are constitutive values that when actors embrace them transform their understandings of themselves as moral beings. In doing so, rights may generate new circuits of protean power, manifest in new patterns of agency and identification, irrespective of their innovative mobilization. Second, the rights case is a clear example of how innovation under conditions of radical uncertainty produces transformative protean power. But it is also a case of how protean power defies possession. After 1945, newly independent post-colonial states played a central role in constructing today’s international human rights regime, but many of these states are now being criticized on the basis of the very norms they helped to define and codify. Put differently, the radical uncertainty that characterized the post-1945 institutional environment encouraged innovation that had transformative effects. Yet, as Figure 1.1 captures (Seybert and Katzenstein, Chapter 1, p. 13, above), this first wave of uncertainty was displaced by a new wave of uncertainty, one that now confronts post-colonial states as they navigate the international human rights norms they helped to institutionalize, but are now mobilized by NGOs, international organizations, and leading Western states.

Conclusion

Those who wield control power are often the most surprised when revolutions in rights transform the social and political orders they have defended with all their might. How are such transformations possible when they, the order’s elite, hold all the material cards, and when their lofty status ought to breed its own legitimacy? The answers lie in the diminishing value of control power to arrest crises of legitimacy, especially under conditions of radical uncertainty. A distinct pattern characterizes all the rights revolutions that have driven the expansion of the modern international system: those associated with the Westphalian settlement; the collapse of the Spanish Empire; and post-1945 decolonization. In each case, when the legitimacy of the regimes of unequal entitlements that held imperial hierarchy together was challenged by new rights claims, imperial elites sought control through coercion. In short, while objectively the context was one of radical uncertainty, these elites understood it as one of risk, placing them in the upper right-hand quadrant of Figure 1.1 (Chapter 1, p. 13, above). Not only did this further erode imperial legitimacy, it radicalized anti-imperial groups, pushing them from voice to exit. Furthermore, because these groups were animated by ideas of general individual rights, action took place under conditions of radical uncertainty: the scope and zone of the application of such rights is neither fixed nor amenable to control. Add to this the uncertainty that attends institutional complexity, and one has a realm of political action that privileges innovation. Time and again it has been the protean power generated by the innovations of seemingly weak actors that has driven change in the modern international order.

As Seybert and Katzenstein (Chapter 2) note, control power and protean power relate in complex and often contradictory ways. Brigden and Andreas (Chapter 5) show how in the migration case the two were mutually reinforcing. Just as prevailing systems of border control inspired new modes of transgressive improvisation and innovation, these very same modes also led to heightened transit dangers and ever more coercive means of border control. In yet another example of this complex relationship, Ayoub shows how the institutionalization of LGBT rights in the EU created a new form of control power, which then provoked “affirmation” and “refusal” in several Eastern European states, producing a new regime of control over LGBT communities (Chapter 4). This has, in turn, encouraged innovative new strategies of translation to encourage greater local acceptance of LGBT rights. The revolutions in rights discussed in this chapter suggest a third version of this complex relationship, this time working at the level of systems change from one kind of international order to another. The rights revolution that led to post-1945 decolonization replayed a common pattern: in their attempts to shore up the prevailing hybrid system of rule imperial elites relied ever more heavily on control power. Early withdrawal from some colonies was matched by violent repression in others, and the emerging institutions of the UN were used not to recalibrate the legitimacy of empire, but as sites for rearguard resistance against anti-colonialism. This in turn created new opportunities for early post-colonial states to innovate with emerging human rights norms, enabling them to reconstitute the right to self-determination. Their eventual success, however, replaced one system of rule with another: the hybrid order was replaced by a universal system of states. The architecture of control power thus took a new institutional form and created the structural conditions for the post-1970s politics of human rights; a politics characterized by new manifestations of protean power born of the innovations of transnational advocacy networks.

4 Protean Power in Movement: Navigating Uncertainty in the LGBT Rights Revolution

Phillip M. Ayoub Footnote 1

Few revolutions in rights have emerged as suddenly, and with such intensity, as the sweeping changes we have observed around LGBTFootnote 2 rights in the last two decades. In multiple states, these monumental changes have transformed many LGBT people from the proverbial “other” – often perceived as criminal and degenerate – into respected and sometimes even celebrated members of society. Coming out of the depths of the AIDS crisis of the 1980s, few would have predicted the major victories in rights many states afford LGBT people in 2017. From the passage of gender recognition in Colombia and Malta to same-sex marriage in Ireland and South Africa, the diversity of states that address such norms have surprised even the most pessimistic onlooker. As such, LGBT rights constitute an intriguing example of unexpected and transformative social change on a global scale.

What powers, then, have spurred this transformation? Indeed, the theoretical explanations for this striking revolution have often obscured the very real struggle that LGBT people – and the movements that represent them – have experienced on the ground. Too often our theories have focused on concepts closely tied to control power, such as cond-itionality and the diffusion of formal rules. What is obscured is the resistance that top-down diffusion provokes on the ground and the destabilizing polarization we also see surrounding LGBT rights globally. Undoubtedly, the LGBT rights revolution conforms to the broader characterization of such revolutions painted by Chris Reus-Smit (Chapter 3, p. 59): “Revolutions in rights are always the product of struggle, generally long and sustained. Yet their triumphs come with a rush.” A movement’s struggle consists of the innovative practices and little surprises that come along the way, which taken together explain the big transformations we then remember. By taking protean power seriously, we refocus on the struggle, which has explained more of the path to tangible rights than a singular and homogeneous notion of top-down power. Analyzing a movement’s struggle, as it navigates a complex world, aids our understanding, explanation, and interpretation of power.

This chapter thus applies the concepts of protean and control power to understand transnational advocacy surrounding LGBT rights. Using the cases of the European Union (EU) and the Council of Europe (CoE), I rethink the hard mechanisms of conditionality – a type of control power – often associated with the successful transfer and diffusion of rights. Importantly, the control power driving these conceptions of sexuality as human rights can also lead to the inflation of threat in multiple domestic contexts.Footnote 3 As such, control power, in the form of hard law diffusion, has had the effects of affirmation and refusal (without internalization), often provoking active resistance and sometimes increased repression. When it does, it changes the experience of actors on the ground, departing from conventional expectations and making their surroundings more uncertain. I argue that these local advocates, embedded in transnational networks, navigate these uncertain and complex terrains with practices of improvisation and innovation that are inherent to the concept of protean power. These actors are attentive to the realities that remain invisible from the top – realities that render control power ineffective on its own – and help to generate transformative change in world politics.

Faced with competing claims about new norms governing sexuality, especially those that problematically conflate sexual rights with the external imposition of “Western” power over “vulnerable” states, local advocates commonly improvise with a practice of translation. They step in where control power falls short to align “external” norms to local contexts. The product is initially movement survival, and sometimes ultimately transformative change, in response to a troubled “one size fits all” approach that can, at times, be counterproductive to the goal of rights recognition. It is the protean power generated by such improvisation that has sustained LGBT movements in times of seemingly insurmountable odds. While improvisation is a common practice in coping with operational uncertainty as activists navigate the unanticipated consequences of control power, its deeper form comes in practices of innovation during radical uncertainty. Radical uncertainty is present when advocates experience a world in which their local surroundings are uncharted and the underlying context of LGBT rights norms is indeterminate. During these times their innovations often feed back up to change the strategies for transnational human rights promotion. Indeed, for LGBT advocates the world in which they operate is constantly changing. Linking back to Seybert’s and Katzenstein’s Figure 1.1 (Chapter 1, p. 13), their mode of operation in any one cell is rather momentary, shifting between practices of improvisation, innovation, refusal, and affirmation as new obstacles arise and terrains change. In most cases of LGBT activism, however, uncertainty characterizes at least one axis of movement operation (either in context or experience) and control and protean power interact. In sum, protean power and control power complement one another in a relationship that is continuously changing – sometimes alternating and always interacting – under various conditions of uncertainty.

In what follows, I introduce the European LGBT rights regime in the first section; use that empirical case to discuss affirmation, refusal, and improvisation (as effects and causes of power) in the region in the second section; then, I take a step back from the intricacies of the case to reflect on broader processes under conditions of risk, complexity, and uncertainty, and how they relate to LGBT power practices and effects in the third section; before concluding in the last section.

European LGBT Rights Regime

LGBT activism has a long history of generating protean power through niches that innovative actors have created. Centered in Wilhelmine, and subsequently Weimar, Germany, the initial – though small scale and without widespread public recognition – political mobilization around homosexuality dates back to the mid-1800s.Footnote 4 During that time, pioneer activists such as Karl Heinrich Ulrichs and Magnus Hirschfeld operated with no compass in a world where homosexuality was invisible in the public sphere. For Ulrichs, responding to the potential proliferation of anti-sodomy legislation that made his sexual orientation illegal, as well as the social sanction that left him without employment prospects, innovation was the only option available.Footnote 5 Innovation was central to this process, since the desires he understood had no name, prompting his writings – which were published and disseminated using pseudonyms in various pamphlets – on what he would call urnings (and later homosexuals).Footnote 6 His efforts, therefore, offer an example of the innovation that produces protean power during radical uncertainty, for he was operating in a world where sexual minorities were publicly invisible. Only through interactions with like people did he feel compelled to chart their existence. This ultimately gave his innovation of the urning identity the ability to generate movement power – by “offering previously unavailable modes of consciousness” (Emanuel Adler, quoted in Katzenstein and Seybert, Chapter 2, p. 38) and spurring mobilization and research around a new identity – once it was shared and received by others through his writings. In much the same spirit of innovation, Hirschfeld’s later research focused on charting the existence of sexual and gender minorities and studying their proclivities. Both Ulrichs and later Hirschfeld had several near successes at repealing the Prussian anti-sodomy legislation (paragraph 175) before it was ultimately enhanced by the young National Socialist regime in 1935.Footnote 7 That regime extinguished the movement throughout Europe (except for a small organization in Switzerland) and sent thousands of gay men to concentration camps. The innovative practices of activists like Ulrichs and Hirschfeld has informed many episodes of LGBT movement history, including the more contemporary one – as a case of improvisation during operational uncertainty – addressed in this chapter. The need for improvisation, in response to severe backlash and resistance is equally apparent in later episodes of the movement.

It was after the Second World War, as part of a post-1945 rights revolution, that sexual minority rights first evolved on the periphery of the broader human rights regime, eventually attaining high political salience across many parts of the world in recent years. Reacting to unresponsive states that had long prohibited access to sexual minorities, LGBT actors in Europe sought out new sources of power outside the state. Because sexual minorities exist in some form across societies, cross-border ties became of paramount importance to political action for post-war Homophile and post-Stonewall (1969) Gay Liberation activism. Recognizing that several elements of their situations were shared across borders, many activists generated unlikely transformative power by organizing transnationally. In 1978, an enduring transnational constellation emerged as the result of a nationally diverse activist meeting in Coventry, United Kingdom: the International Lesbian, Gay, Bisexual, Trans and Intersex Association (originally IGA, later ILGA).Footnote 8 Due to uneven support among their respective states, ILGA activists – and a handful of pioneering states that supported their cause – began targeting European institutions as a venue to challenge the state powers that had previously closed the door to them. These activists were innovative, if not visionary, because they targeted an international organization, the European Community, more than a decade before it had the social mandate it would attain after the Maastricht Treaty of 1992.Footnote 9 At the time, the odds of finding institutional allies from an economically focused international organization, and on this contentious issue, were low.

Targeting the EU – and other organizations, such as the CoE and the Organization for Security and Cooperation in Europe – did eventually change the underlying international context by creating a place for sexual minority rights at the periphery of the broader human rights regime. Over time, the articulations of a norm that LGBT people are entitled to fundamental human rights, deserving of state recognition and protection, became increasingly clear in both the rhetoric and the legal framework of EU and CoE institutions.Footnote 10 Article 13 of the 1997 Amsterdam Treaty introduced the first internationally binding law on the issue: it prohibited employment discrimination on the basis of sexual orientation. The 2000 Employment Anti-Discrimination Directive; the European Charter for Fundamental Rights; the 1993 Copenhagen Criteria; various European Parliament resolutions; European Court of Human Rights (ECtHR) decisions; and European Court of Justice decisions further institutionalized the norm as part of European human rights values.Footnote 11 In more recent years, and especially for post-communist states that wish(ed) to join the EU and CoE, the “return to Europe”Footnote 12 would mean adopting the universal understandings of the LGBT norm that European institutions now proffered. Having access to new-found institutional control mechanisms of support and sanction, European advocates began operating in a complex world where risk and uncertainty interact: a world of operational uncertainty, where protean and control power meet.

From Effects to Causes of Power
Affirmation and Refusal: Complying with and Resisting the LGBT Rights Norm

While advocates rely on these now dominant systems of knowledge that have legitimated LGBT rights norms in the European polity – especially in unresponsive states –the “one size fits all” interpretations of such rights have produced varied and unpredictable outcomes across states. On the one hand, the EU has used incentives, such as membership or enhanced political ties, to produce desirable rights outcomes in a calculable fashion. Indeed, such carrot/stick power has produced compliance outcomes: notably the introduction of employment anti-discrimination measures, which now exist across the twenty-eight-state polity. In a different area of civil liberties, the threat of reduced EU regional subsidies may have also compelled the Hungarian government to step back from its calls in 2017 to close the Central European University in Budapest. The CoE, which has also played an activist role in promoting the LGBT norm, has produced major court rulings in defense of LGBT people.

However, affirmation can abruptly shift to refusal, opening small niches for protean power during periods of operational uncertainty. More often than not, such predetermined diffusion models were met with considerable resistance as they were diffused across the CoE, the EU, and their neighborhoods. Importantly, the control power driving these dominant conceptions of sexuality as human rights also resulted in the inflation of threat perception in multiple domestic contexts, making the situational experience of local LGBT advocates increasingly uncertain as new resistances formed. Opposing sectors of societies viewed these models as challenging the fixity of national identity, questioning their national sovereignty, values, and self-understandings – even in a context as open to human rights as Europe, and more so in other regions with less established human rights frameworks. Often portrayed as foreign power over the domestic sphere, emerging counter-movements problematically conflated LGBT rights with “secular” or “Western” imposition.Footnote 13

Reminiscent of the practice of refusal, hard law conditionality around sexual minority rights thus came with sudden shocks that could backslide the early successes of LGBT movements by mobilizing new social actors to challenge them. When such measures were introduced, many new member states responded by simultaneously banning public assembly and even proposing homophobic bills, such as those that proposed removing LGBT people from teaching in schools and constitutional bans on same-sex unions.Footnote 14 State authorities did this both because of the recognition of uncertainty in society – and to reap political gains from them – and with the intention of further enhancing it by questioning the validity of the norm. As a direct response to a ECtHR ruling against Russia, for example, Moscow took the opposite position and banned public assembly by LGBT people for 100 years. States have also introduced novel bills intended to protect “religious liberty,” sanctify marriage, oppose “gender ideology,” and ban the promotion of homosexuality. Refusal by governments creates an indeterminacy surrounding the legitimacy of LGBT norms that also fuels the fomentation of societal backlash domestically. In response, at the societal level, rates of violence against LGBT people in other spheres of life often accelerated, and popular attitudes toward LGBT people often declined. Within the EU, the mean country scores measuring the approval of homosexuality dropped in the Czech Republic, Estonia, Slovakia, and Slovenia in the European Values Survey waves before and after EU accession.Footnote 15

In the EU’s neighborhood, Ukraine is the most recent example of this paradox, in which the power of strict conditionality is initially met with a mixed response of affirmation and refusal. In exchange for liberalized travel visas, it was compelled to adopt employment anti-discrimination measures with protections on the basis of sexual orientation. Yet such minimal compliance does not equate with the norm internalization goals set by the LGBT movement. After two failed attempts to pass such a bill in early November 2015, Ukrainian parliamentarians were obliged to make the third time “the charm”; begrudgingly they introduced the bill after immense pressure from state leaders and EU officials. Yet passing the bill came with the simultaneous practice of refusal. Political leadership across parties initially assured their citizens that Ukraine would not introduce any other rights for such minorities, and that tolerance toward LGBT people would not be internalized as part of Ukrainian national values. President Petro Porochenko declared that “family values will remain inviolable,” and the “speaker of parliament assured deputies that the law would not threaten ‘family values’, saying: ‘I hear some fake information which says that there may be same-sex marriages in Ukraine. God forbid, this will ever happen. We will never support this.’”Footnote 16 In 2016, a march in Lviv was canceled after the state said it could not be protected, prompting activists to flee the city after right-wing groups attended the planned meeting shouting “kill, kill, kill.”Footnote 17 Societal backlash also ensued, including an arson attack on a cinema during a screening of a gay-themed film in October 2014, as well as targeted attacks on activists.Footnote 18 Amid safety concerns spurred by increased repression, Ukrainian LGBT activists opted to protest outside Parliament without the symbolic rainbow flag, a 1970s innovation of the American gay liberation movement that became a global symbol for LGBT people. Indeed, this refusal of typical LGBT symbols – largely because they buttressed the Russian Duma’s claims that pro-EU Maidan protestors were all “gay” – was so evident that an LGBT organization attributed a flash mob of protestors using the rainbow flag as a provocation organized by pro-Russian groups and the Ukrainian Security Service.Footnote 19

The anti-gay politics of Vladimir Putin’s Russia, a member of the CoE, is equally exemplary of refusal, leading to indeterminacy. The state has used the rhetoric of “traditional values” to present Russia as the international protectorate of the new post-secular morality politics, justifying the passage and diffusion of anti-“homopropaganda” laws that center on sexual “decadency” as deviant.Footnote 20 This politics of traditional values has been used as a geopolitical tool with which to symbolically distance Russia from Western power. It explains why, as BatesonFootnote 21 has described, the Ukrainian “pro-Kremlin media was attempting to portray the pro-EU [Maidan] protests two years ago as a tantrum by LGBT people yearning to join ‘Gayropa.’”

Thus, while EU law – and the United Nations’ more recent rhetoric and declarations (cf. Hillary Clinton’s 2011 speech in Geneva)Footnote 22 – might lead us to take for granted that systems of knowledge place LGBT people squarely within universal human rights, this knowledge system does not go uncontested. Contentious debates destabilize new international narratives at local levels, and they can undermine the efficacy of such institutions to engineer change from above. Indeed, there is a multiplicity of centers of control from which such power can be exercised that make norms indeterminate. As the new Russian paradigm of “traditional values” politics exemplifies, refusal as a response to power also leads to what Symons and Altman call “norm polarization.”Footnote 23 Such polarization refers to a process in which states purposively take contradictory positions on the same norm, leading to norm indeterminacy (see Chapter 3) at the global level. This heightens uncertainty – in this example, beyond operational and toward radical uncertainty – for LGBT advocates in states not firmly embedded in the transatlantic community of states. It is not surprising, thence, that when the American President Barack Obama threatened the material consequences of cutting aid to Uganda for passing an anti-homosexuality bill, Ugandan President Yoweri Museveni replied he would then “want to work with Russia.”Footnote 24

Returning to the EU, empirical evidence suggests that hard law mechanisms are only part of the story when relating to the spread of sexual minority rights, and that they are dependent on local translation. If we look at the broader range of the LGBT rights agenda (anti-discrimination, decriminalization, partnership, parenting, and hate crime legislation), EU membership conditionality alone did not have a significant effect on advancing the movement’s goals.Footnote 25 Despite the wide array of formal pressure points associated with EU accession, top-down conditionality was not statistically correlated with transformative legal change. While it does predict changes in anti-discrimination legislation (which states were required to adopt in the three most recent accession waves), it is challenged in predicting wider shifts of incorporating LGBT norms into domestic legal frameworks. By contrast, the presence of activists engaged in the practice of norm translation did aid the adoption of the norm, which I elaborate on below.Footnote 26 The powers that have produced tangible and lasting change are not associated only with control power. The work of activists has certainly been facilitated by EU rules and regulations, but processes of change rely on the actors that connect practices of control and protean power. Typically, during operational uncertainty, protean power occupies the spaces created by control power’s unanticipated consequences.

It is thus worth emphasizing that responses to the diffusion of LGBT rights norms are rarely calculable, even if LGBT international non-governmental organizations (INGOs) and the institutions that support them hope to perceive them as such. Actors on both the international and domestic levels provide competing views of, and solutions to, the issue of LGBT rights. When LGBT rights first appear in popular discourse, they almost always provoke resistance. Thus, the top-down introduction of LGBT norms – however important that step may be – also produces a set of other unpredictable and undesirable outcomes, ones that control power alone cannot remedy. As the next subsection demonstrates, protean power operates in the periods of operational uncertainty I have outlined above.

Improvisation: Translation during Operational Uncertainty

Experiencing uncertainty with competing claims about new norms, local LGBT activists respond with a process of translation, adapting universal norms to distinct local contexts, and innovation, when no functioning models exist. This is especially crucial for audiences in which LGBT people have been previously isolated from the public sphere: as an unknown that, when initially visible, provokes resistance. Two types of uncertainty operate in these common scenarios: operational and radical. The first (operational) has to do with the uncertainty on the ground for local advocates that emerges from the clash of norms. They face the conundrum of what to do given resistance and backlash, painfully aware both of the expectations of prior legitimate models as well as their unanticipated consequences that they must now confront. The second (radical) is that uncertainty that is built into all levels of the system: both in the underlying context and in actor experience on the ground. It has to do with deep norm indeterminacy surrounding rights at the domestic and international levels: domestic indeterminacy in response to “imposed” and illegitimate norms that clash with local sovereignty, as well as international indeterminacy involving norm polarization. Radical uncertainty questions the very existence of LGBT people and their rights; it typically operates when LGBT individuals first step into the light of local public visibility. Local LGBT actors focus on reducing operational uncertainty, while also addressing the radical indeterminacies surrounding the norm to root the claim’s legitimacy.

During these periods of uncertainty, when political opposition intensifies, local LGBT advocates turn to innovation and improvisation to adapt to changing environments. In doing so, they help to interpret norms and create knowledge concerning the societal place of the group they represent. The degree to which this is done can vary from innovation during radical uncertainty (as the Ulrichs example above suggested) to some combination of refusal and improvisation during operational uncertainty. During operational uncertainty, this can mean that actors both dismantle and adapt common attributes of the universal norm, using their local knowledge to translate the norm in unique social and cultural terms.Footnote 27 Such translation comes into play when universal scripts clash with local ones. It is especially necessary in the case of LGBT rights, since majority populations often turn to traditional social conventions – ones that rarely provide positive etymologies of LGBT people – when “external” LGBT norms are made visible. Translation is the interactive top-down and bottom-up process in which actors package dominant conceptions of sexual rights for distinct audiences.Footnote 28 Advocates can balance engaging in translation while maintaining relations with outside actors (including other states and EU institutions) who provide valuable resources and support. Thus, they creatively find spaces to exploit when control power from above produces unwanted outcomes.

An example of this process is the Polish LGBT movement’s consistent improvisation as it navigates among various competing groups in periods of intense backlash.Footnote 29 Provoked by the perceived imposition of new EU standards, Polish counter-movements framed sexual rights as “external” and incongruent with Polish national identity. This is an aspect of the controlling discourse of universal norms that can perversely limit room for local expression and fan the flames of resistance. During an intense period of politicized homophobia following EU accession, from 2004 to 2007, local LGBT actors worked to reconcile authoritative international demands and create appropriate local meanings for norms. This process is highly improvisational, and it produces protean power to shape new understandings of sexual minorities in the domestic sphere by moving them from the external periphery to connect them to domestic political debates. At the core of this process has been repackaging the norm according to different contexts and forms of emerging opposition.Footnote 30 The innovative nature of these movement actors is captured in the practice of translation. It describes how advocates reconcile external and internal understandings of the norm, constantly reshaping the norm’s message.

Polish activists have long engaged in a process of translation that connects the universal LGBT norms championed by EU institutions to their local audiences. Leading up to Poland’s EU accession, activists framed the issue as one of European values and responsibilities associated with democratization. When public assembly was banned in 2004 and 2005, activists used their transnational networks to mobilize European dignitaries to march in Poland. When these dignitaries were brought to the front of the illegal demonstrations by their respective embassies, the police were compelled to protect them, and thus they indirectly protected the Polish protestors that organized the march.Footnote 31 For the strategic local activists, this human-shield technique was imperative at a time when any public assembly was outnumbered by often violent counter-demonstrations. It was a way to generate visibility for local LGBT people who could not safely march otherwise.Footnote 32 During periods of Euro-optimism, the LGBT frame was primarily attached to the EU. Protestors donned t-shirts that stated “Europa=Tolerancja” and waved EU flags. Foreign dignitaries were told to refer to themselves as Europeans, which resonated with the wider political discourse of Poland’s “return to Europe.”

In a later post-accession period, when anti-EU politics intensified, activists shifted gears. By emphasizing that LGBT people were precisely the aspect of “Europe” that was to be rejected, the emerging opposition surprisingly changed the focus of the LGBT movement to the nation. While the Polish cultural counter-movement is a loose conglomeration of religious, political, and nationalist actors, their frames converged around an issue of the nation being “under attack” by external forces – largely in a differentiated response to the international human rights frames touted by the LGBT movement initially.Footnote 33 As Agnès Chetaille and I have traced across twenty years of Polish activism, the movement responded to its opposition strategically by emphasizing its Polishness in frames that signal a far more rooted politics of sexuality than before.Footnote 34 They used “Catholic” and (increasingly) “national” frames to root LGBT rights as Polish. For example, Poland’s largest LGBT organization, the transnationally linked Campaign Against Homophobia, changed its logo to mimic the national borders of Poland. In 2016, the organization co-developed a campaign called Przekażmy Sobie Znak Pokoju (Let us offer each other a sign of peace).Footnote 35 It adapted the locally resonant phrase – used by Polish bishops in a reconciliatory letter to German bishops in 1965, as well as by parishioners as a greeting during mass – placing it over a picture of two hands shaking, one hand adorned with a rosary and the other with a rainbow flag bracket. The campaign, displayed on billboards across the country, generated a firestorm of media attention. Early signs seem to suggest a historic step forward in soothing the oil-and-water relationship between Catholicism and LGBT rights in Poland.

These tactics were contentious within and without the Polish movement, as activists remain hesitant to wash away the decades of harm they have experienced as a result of the Church’s vehement opposition. The tactic would also appear ill-conceived to some of the best practice handbooks and directives, emphasizing universality, composed by LGBT lobbyists and policymakers in Brussels (and in Amsterdam, Stockholm, and Berlin). But Polish actors do so in an innovative way that has countered and co-opted the arguments of the resistances that emerged in response to imported and sometimes coercive models of external LGBT activism.Footnote 36 At the INGO ILGA-Europe’s 2016 summit, the early success of the controversial Polish campaign turned heads, with new calls emerging to replicate it in other domestic contexts. It is thus also an example of how protean and control powers are entangled. They both make room for and replace one another, constituting and reconstituting human rights norms.

As Table 4.1 illustrates with the work of Ayoub and Chetaille, activists were consistently improvisational in how they presented LGBT rights according to the changing context in which they functioned.Footnote 37 Throughout this process, local actors borrow models that fit (e.g., human rights, democracy, European values) as well as altering and adapting them in an agile process of translation. This is done as they navigate what comes their way in a constantly changing environment of contestation. In the Polish case, frames have become increasingly rooted in response to nationalist local challenges. For the Polish activists, translation becomes an interactive top-down and bottom-up process in which actors present and package dominant ideas and master frames of sexual rights for distinct audiences.

Table 4.1 Innovative Framing by the Polish movement, 1990–2010

1990–20012001–42004–52005–10
I. Changing periods of uncertaintyDemocratic transition and the “return to Europe”Political allies and European accessionNew adversaries/ opposition intensifiesMovement– counter-movement interaction
II. Innovative frame attributesExternal and universalExternal and non-contentiousContentious and diversifiedDiversified, rooted and particular
III. Types of frames usedHuman rights: universal principles of equality and rightsEducational: anti-discrimination, anti-homophobicDefining adversaries: political parties, nationalist organizationsReclaiming localness: patriots vs. nationalists
Democracy: return to EuropeEuropeanization: European values and responsibilitiesNational turn: religion, culture and memory
Source: Adapted from Ayoub and Chetaille Reference Ayoub and Chetaille2018.

While this example has drawn on Poland, LGBT activists throughout the world respond to ever-changing contexts of uncertainty. Even in the aforementioned Ukrainian case, activists today are debating and adapting the initial strategies they deployed two years earlier.Footnote 38 In response to the backlash and a rapidly changing domestic environment, local activists have pursued varied innovative strategies – including invisibility strategies to initially deflect the anti-gay opposition’s strategic use of universal LGBT symbols – that have engendered some positive change in recent years.Footnote 39 These successes include pride parades in Kiev, an activist conference, enhanced capacity-building for civil society organizations, and some elite political support in the domestic sphere.Footnote 40 The same dynamic of translation is true of countries with older LGBT movements. Kelly Kollman has shown, for example, how the LGBT norm, which is often presented in the language of “European values” in the EU, has been reframed according to context. British activists abandoned the frame entirely, framing it in national terms. German activists held on to the resonant frame, shaming Germany for “falling behind” European human rights standards. Dutch activists argued that LGBT rights were a forum for the Netherlands to play a norm pioneer role in European and world politics.Footnote 41 In other mainly non-European contexts, activists have rejected the terms “queer,” “gay,” and “lesbian” entirely for their specific constituency. In the hopes of removing their “foreignness” or to strengthen their inclusivity, they prefer local language variants or other terms, such as “men who have sex with men” (MSM) or the more inclusive “sexual orientation and gender identity” (SOGI).Footnote 42

In sum, the LGBT rights revolution shows that control power, through the diffusion of formal rules and conditionality, can obscure the experience of local resistance and global polarization around LGBT rights. Uncertainty produced by the clash or misfit between international human rights norms with domestic values has generated protean power impulses for local LGBT activists who translate EU rules and regulations into different national contexts. Faced with emerging counter-movements and competing claims about new norms governing sexuality, local advocates, embedded in transnational networks, developed tools of norm translation to navigate this complex terrain. In recent decades they have engaged supranational institutions when their respective states closed access to them. And later, after successfully securing international support, they translated and localized the norm as it re-entered the domestic sphere. In times of operational uncertainty, they looked for new allies and sought to reframe the norm in a discourse that resonated with local audiences and disempowered the frames used by their opposition. In this interactive process, the practices of LGBT advocates help protean power rise to complement and subsequently reshape top-down control power on their behalf.

Reflections on the Theoretical Framework
Practices of Power under Conditions of Risk, Complexity, and Uncertainty

Stepping back from the intricacies of the cases, this section connects the empirics described above back to the ontological assumptions of Katzenstein’s and Seybert’s Figure 2.1 (Chapter 2, p. 33, above). In doing so, it navigates the interaction between control and protean powers as a theoretical exercise, while also addressing the counterfactuals of worlds defined purely by risk or radical uncertainty. Empirically, this is a challenging task because there is ample and frequent movement across the length of Figure 2.1’s spectrum, with most scenarios operating in between the purest forms of control and protean power practices.Footnote 43 Indeed, I occasionally shift into the hypothetical to imagine a world for LGBT rights that functions at the extreme ends of the spectrum, when power wielders and the targets of power (roles that are malleable in the real world and often occupied by different actors from one scenario to the next) both operate in settings of calculable risk or radical uncertainty. While I do illustrate scenarios at the extreme ends, the majority of LGBT rights cases fall into the center of the figure, echoing a core argument of this volume: that we live in a world of complexity in which control and protean power are entangled. I should also note that operating in any one space along the spectrum is rather momentary for the LGBT case. For example, and as the Polish case demonstrates, a refusal response is usually met with one of improvisation, and both can continue simultaneously, with creative practices eventually being co-opted by control power actors (though whether a model based on these practices leads to success in a new context is not given). In what follows, I begin at the far left of Katzenstein’s and Seybert’s Figure 2.1 (risk) and move along the spectrum to the right (toward radical uncertainty).

Risk

A scenario of pre-accession conditionality comes closest to the example of risk at the far left of the spectrum. In it a state conforms to pressure from the EU, and the INGOs that support it, in adopting some aspect of LGBT rights. The aforementioned case of anti-discrimination based on sexual orientation in the run-up to the 2004, 2007, and 2013 waves of EU accession is a useful example. Here there is a calculation made at both ends, because adopting the norm is tied to a clearly defined set of other material and social benefits that come with EU membership. Thus, both the EU (as a power wielder) and state actors (as a target) can entertain a cost–benefit analysis in a world in which context and experience align. This is an example of the EU’s power over the applicant state, and it has led directly to affirmation around some aspects of the LGBT norm. While much literature regarding rights diffusion assumes a power relationship of this nature, most power dynamics surrounding LGBT rights are far more complex. If power operates in moments of a calculable and risk-based world, they are short moments indeed. Affirmation can abruptly shift into backlash locally, which rapidly moves us further right on the spectrum to refusal, opening niches for protean power. It is in the following two scenarios that the interaction between or entanglement of the two kinds of power becomes most apparent.

Complexity: Manifested primarily in Control Power Practices

The more common scenario is one of complexity, in which the underlying context of the world and local actor experience are not in sync – as in the diagonal cells of Figure 1.1 of Chapter 1. With the interaction still slightly favoring control power practices, the more uncertain the underlying context becomes, the more it opens a space for refusal. For example, Russia’s new paradigm of moral conservatism has changed the dynamic for power wielders supportive of LGBT rights, amplifying and (re)introducing contestation and indeterminacy around the norm at the international level. As discussed above, instead of an increasingly strengthened international norm, the movement is faced with international norm polarization. While this dynamic is still relatively new, since politics surrounding LGBT movements have been at the grassroots for much of their history, refusals toward LGBT politics are also regularly played out at the international level. This involves one community of states refusing the values of another, making LGBT rights part of a geopolitics in which states co-opt the values that align with “their” side. This can shake the experience of actors at the grassroots level, as their issue is debated, partly unchecked, at a very abstract universal level.

Complexity: Manifested Primarily in Protean Power Practices

Moving further right on the spectrum, we come closer to a type of interaction that is common in the contemporary LGBT case. Here, templates of sympathetic international organizations and human rights INGOs for how to provoke change in multiple domestic realms are contested locally. With uncertainty prevailing on the ground, states and their societies refuse “imposed” norms. This shifts the interaction further away from control power practices. Uncertainty is high in contexts where the LGBT rights norm is still unknown, because LGBT people themselves have been largely invisible on the ground. Such contexts invite a host of societal actors into a debate (e.g., a mix of political elites, religious institutions, nationalist resistance movements) when the norm first diffuses into the domestic space, leading to anti-LGBT resistance and subsequently new uncertainties experienced by local LGBT advocates in the domestic sphere. The approximate sequence is one of diffusion (state affirmation), followed by resistance (societal refusal), followed by translation (movement improvisation). As in the Polish example, here the impetus falls on local advocates, which usually multiply during these times, to translate the norm for a local audience. Innovative power practices involve translation, which can circulate up to sympathizing power wielders, in a world dominated by operational uncertainty.

Yet again, I want to note how momentary a world of complexity favoring either control or protean power is. Take, for example, the US criticism of Russia’s handling of the Sochi Olympics, an example falling at the left space of complexity. While international condemnation met refusal when challenging Russian domestic policy toward LGBT people, local American actors could shift gears to condemn US policy, which they said sounded hypocritical and hollow in its criticism of Russia, considering the long list of issues facing LGBT Americans.Footnote 44 Thus, activists shift us right on the spectrum of Figure 1.1 toward the protean space of complexity. This may have contributed to reshaping the underlying context for advocates on the ground in “the West,” where states are now expected to live up to their discourse more than they were before.

Uncertainty

Further right, at the other extreme end, we enter a world of deeply radical uncertainty. Even when there is uncertainty among power wielders, states usually fall into one group or another in a world of regions. A unique example, however, might be a case like Uganda, which has a heated contest domestically around these rights, and power wielders also compete over it at the international level (i.e., the US Obama Administration threatening to cut aid and Russia offering to provide it). At some points in time, the Ukraine case also exemplifies a similar dynamic of being caught between Russia and the EU. Scenarios like these open ample space for innovation by activists, as both the underlying international context and the experience of actors on the ground are deeply uncertain. We could also think back to the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries when there were no “power wielders” (in the form of de facto powerful actors and institutions) to think of that supported the norm. By this I mean no would-be commands exist, let alone provide a model for how to achieve it at any level of analysis. In these cases, LGBT rights advocates have to (re)invent much of the rule book from scratch, innovating new ways of claiming their rights and reconstituting social orders. From this vantage point, the innovation of Ulrichs during radical uncertainty is related – though a much more pronounced version – to the improvisation of Polish activists during complexity. Here protean power practices involve innovation that completely rethinks or recreates models at all levels, in a world that is radically uncertain for movement advocates. Such innovative practices that generate protean power almost always circulate back to change the underlying context of LGBT norm promotion at international and domestic levels.

Conclusion

This chapter has explored the concepts of protean and control power as they relate to the transnational advocacy networks surrounding the issue of LGBT rights. The case of LGBT rights embodies two aspects of unexpected change. The first concerns what the proponents of LGBT rights would consider positive. The sweeping changes surrounding the adoption of norms governing LGBT rights around the globe are truly surprising, and scholarship has grappled with the failure to predict it. At the same time, the second aspect of unexpected change concerns the resistance to these emerging norms. While backlash itself is common, and thus anticipated by movement actors, the various shapes it takes are not. In this sense, it is much like in the case of migration (Chapter 5), where border enforcers react and adapt to the strategies of migrants, or in the case of anti-terrorism (Chapter 9), where states adapt to their failed attempts at control. The constellations of opposition actors and their methods of resistance are unique, unpredictable, and ever-changing across domestic contexts. In many cases of resistance, the opposition is also connected to state actors at an international level, which the example of Russia’s normative opposition to LGBT rights makes explicit.

Identifying stagnant, or even central, nodes of power is thus challenging when we consider the diverse realm of contending actors at play in LGBT politics as well as the global polarization of the norm. Just as US state power has been a force for some LGBT people in the Obama years, an array of US non-state actors were responsible for introducing anti-gay bills to various regions in the first place (e.g., anti-gay activist Scott Lively’s involvement in early iterations of the notorious Ugandan “kill the gays” bill).Footnote 45 Just as activists improvise to defeat domestic opposition, anti-LGBT counter-movements seek out and find new state and non-state allies. And just as states and counter-movements can refuse the promotion of the LGBT norms, so can local LGBT activists refuse and reshape the ways that states and INGOs advocate on their behalf. Thus, the actors exercising and generating power are always interchanging in a complex and uncertain world. Especially for a chapter on a vulnerable population, it is essential to emphasize this important point, that protean power is not only a tool for the “weak” or the “good.”Footnote 46 As Brigden and Andreas (Chapter 5) demonstrate so well, the protean power practices available to actors via improvisation is likewise available to the various contending actors in this dynamic story.

A core goal of this chapter has been to highlight such contestation in a world of complexity. The institutionalization of LGBT rights has shown recurrent, divergent understandings, even contradictions, of human rights at international and domestic levels. This has created opportunities for innovative political mobilization and the creative grafting of new rights onto local contexts.Footnote 47 That is, the control power exercised by the EU and CoE was a necessary (if not sufficient) condition to generate conflict between supranational rights and domestic norms, opening spaces for protean power through the introduction of additional uncertainties. Most episodes of LGBT rights diffusion and circulation are in the spaces where control and protean power interact. While the empirics surrounding LGBT rights advocacy drew heavily from the broader European context in this chapter, we observe a related dynamic of this contestation and indeterminacy in other world regions. As Ashley Currier has demonstrated, the universal underpinnings of LGBT rights norms have also clashed in Namibia and South Africa, where they have been portrayed as colonial and un-African.Footnote 48 Palestinian LGBT groups face a similar dilemma under occupation in advocating for gay rights while disassociating themselves from the “pinkwashing” politics of Israel’s gay rights promotion.Footnote 49

Navigating such uncertainty generates protean power, embodied in the innovative and improvisational practices that have always been paramount to LGBT advocacy. When international standards of human rights in Europe inadvertently provoked backlash, activists creatively reframed them, often rooting them locally with frames that had previously been seen as antithetical to LGBT rights norm promotion. Depending on the time period and context, different frames helped to facilitate translation to the national level. This was evident in the Polish case, in which activists rooted the universal human rights claims by linking them to the frames used by their opposition.

In doing so, LGBT rights activists resist state repression and thus find the power to, more or less successfully, transform the state’s conception of human rights. Often their innovative practices also loop back to amplify uncertainty and influence the strategies of international institutions and INGOs, which may or may not find similar success when they are used again. Thus, the case of LGBT rights in Europe demonstrates how advocates navigate between international and local arenas, translating international norms to local realities. It is under conditions of complexity that most of these interactions between protean and control power occur.

In sum, I have emphasized that LGBT rights advocacy predominantly operates in an incalculable and uncertain world that relies on an entanglement between both types of power. As this volume advocates, the case of LGBT rights compels those analyzing power to withstand the temptation to simplify the world to such an extent that it appears to be readily controllable through risk-based strategies. We must acknowledge the existence of uncertainty and the space it gives to the emergence of protean power and highlight the dynamics of power that will always leave room to the disruptions that innovation creates for affirmation.

5 Border Collision: Power Dynamics of Enforcement and Evasion across the US–Mexico Line

Noelle K. Brigden and Peter Andreas

In 2005, Maria,Footnote 1 a humble and devout woman from rural El Salvador, embarked on a clandestine journey to the United States. She made a contract with a hometown smuggler, who then subcontracted with a series of guides along the route. While under the care of one of those guides, her travel party took a van across southern Mexico.Footnote 2 Confronted with the possibility of being stopped by immigration authorities and questioned, Maria began to pray and sing for their safe passage. She began timidly at first. Upon hearing her shy voice, the guide turned to face her, and demanded urgently and unkindly to know what she was doing. When she explained, his face broke into a broad smile, and he responded, “Yes! Great idea! If they stop us, we will tell them we are a church group.” The smuggler, faced with the potential for unpredictable traffic inspections by immigration authorities, seized on the idea. For the rest of the journey in the van, her travel party sang their praises to God loudly alongside their smuggler.

This encounter between Maria and her smuggler unwittingly generated a new survival tactic, one of many novel tactics employed during a clandestine journey to evade capture. Encounters between migrants, smugglers, and the state are often creative moments. New strategies are devised. New trajectories are imagined. New roles are crafted. This creativity emerges from their interaction, as people grapple with uncertainty and danger. Maria’s mobility, despite the state’s attempt to thwart her passage, is thus an outcome of a power that neither belongs fully to Maria nor to her smuggler, but instead circulates contingent on uncertain social moments.

An analysis of Maria’s story, to which we will return later, helps to elucidate why attempts to control the US–Mexico boundary have long had an ambiguous, and often counterproductive, impact on clandestine flows. An unrelenting unauthorized traffic rolls north across the US–Mexico line. Nevertheless, while a massive allocation of resources to the border has not succeeded in stemming the tide of contraband and migration, it has dramatically reshaped these flows.Footnote 3 The geographic focal points,Footnote 4 modes of transport, protocols, social relationships, and smuggling networksFootnote 5 that underpin routes adapt to policing, and policing, in turn, adapts to these adaptations. In the last two decades, border crossings have grown more dangerous for unauthorized migrants, generating a new humanitarian crisis at the doorstep of the United States.Footnote 6 Thus, the border remains porous, but policing has altered crossing practices with deleterious consequences for migrants. The exercise of state power has collided with a complex transnational social reality, producing cross-cutting consequences.

Our chapter explores the ambiguous outcome of this collision across the US–Mexico divide. A myopic focus on conventional notions of power, or its failure, contributes to perverse border policies and analytical shortcomings. Public discourse neglects the protean power evident in migrant improvisations, thereby underplaying migrants’ agency and vilifying smugglers with deleterious consequences for border policy; the binary of powerless migrants/victims and powerful smugglers/victimizers justifies further escalation of policing to protect both national and human security.Footnote 7 Furthermore, this discourse also tends toward historical amnesia about its own origins, highlighting the supposedly unprecedented nature of migration crises and forgetting that the power dynamics evident across the border extend back more than a century. Indeed, the starting point in most analyses is the past few decades.

Finally, scholarship generally highlights the failure of border control, rather than unpacking its complex consequences from different levels of analysis. A broad consensus of scholars focuses on the inevitability that border patrol displaces migration to new terrain and social practice, but we know less about how exactly this displacement takes place, and how it has varied across place and time. While the flow continues, displacement is a disruptive and painful process in the lives of unauthorized migrants. On the one hand, migrants endure tremendous precarity and violence, and they sometimes die. On the other hand, migrants are not passive victims; if they survive the treacherous journey north, their success can often be attributed to a combination of fortuitous circumstance, intellectual and physical agility, and social flexibility that emerges within encounters with other migrants, smugglers, or state authorities. Scholarship has generally left unexplored how these individual creative moments collectively contribute to displacement.

Moving beyond traditional conceptualizations of power elucidates such moments, and thereby explains the process of displacement over time. The lens of protean power reveals the multifaceted roles played, not only by traditionally powerful actors like the state and organized crime, but also by individual migrants, like Maria, in concert with the social landscape they must cross. Practically, the lens of protean power complicates the binary of victim–villain, and thereby undermines a useful fiction to justify border escalation. Analytically, this lens also provides a window onto the primary mechanism of displacement: improvisation.

Thus, this chapter applies the concepts of protean power and control power in tracing the evolution of the US–Mexico border enforcement and evasion from the nineteenth century to the present. Following the definition in this volume, protean power is the effect of an imaginative agility, which contrasts with traditional notions of power. Protean power navigates a world of uncertainty, where successful responses to danger and/or opportunity must rely, to a much greater degree, on improvisation and a leap of faith. In contrast, control power is rooted in the capacity to manipulate and respond to risk. This capacity presupposes a world of rational calculations and knowable probabilities; under those relatively predictable conditions, control power can be more effectively utilized to incentivize and coerce particular behaviors from other actors.

Combining a historical perspective with more recent ethnographic fieldwork on the experiences of unauthorized Central American migrants, the chapter recasts the escalatory spiral of policing and smuggling at the border as a collision between worldviews of risk and uncertainty, and between protean and control power. The political and bureaucratic theatrics that drive border policing are primarily premised on a world of risk. Policing measures taken at the border are meant to convey an image of control. Smugglers and migrants, however, live in a world of uncertainty, as well as risk.Footnote 8 Border policing has increased the probability of dangers befalling migrants on their journey, but it has also intensified the difficulties of judging that probability. Smugglers’ and migrants’ experiences with and reactions to this hostile and unpredictable environment illustrate the agility and adaptation associated with protean power. Thus, the chapter provides a micro-foundation for understanding the dynamic interaction between the state and unauthorized migration flows.

Importantly, we argue that protean power is not an instrument that marginalized people can harness to produce “social justice” in any predictable way. In other words, it is not an effective means to achieve collective political goals or to correct the structural inequities and violence that reproduce the vulnerability of immigrant populations. Migrant and smuggler improvisations generate protean power, but cannot direct or use it to achieve such goals. Despite the fact that they often prove to be capable of resisting and transgressing borders, migrants also experience policing and violence as profoundly disempowering. Therefore, we unpack these consequences for a variety of actors who populate the migration corridor into the United States: migrants, smugglers, crime bosses, and law enforcers. In conclusion, we caution against a celebration of the emancipatory potential of protean power, even as we acknowledge and explore its effect.

The Ambiguities of Power

The level of analysis matters crucially for how we understand this ambiguous outcome of intensified border policing. On the one hand, we can see the resilience of the border crossings when we look at the aggregate. The migration stream continues to flow north, simply changing direction and adapting to the policing with new clandestine practices. Indeed, at the aggregate level, this outcome is easily predictable; the specific form of criminal displacement may be unanticipated, but the general pattern is expected. It is a policy failure foretold. Accepting the inevitability of this general pattern, policymakers have for several decades now pursued border policing that pushes migration routes to less visible terrain and practices.Footnote 9 Policymakers traffic in images of control, premised on assumptions of risk management.

On the other hand, migrants may fail to cross the border and, sometimes, they die in the attempt. During their journey from their homeland, migrants sometimes fall victim to treacherous physical terrain or criminal activity, such as kidnappings, extortions, murders, robberies, and rapes.Footnote 10 Changes in policing often aggravate migrants’ exposure to these dangers.Footnote 11 At the level of the individual, the lived experience of the border is very different. The individual experience and personal consequences of the border are not predictable; migrants must function under both conditions of high uncertainty and risk, depending on the situation.Footnote 12 Migrants also experience both risk and uncertainty, feeling buffeted both by increased probabilities of some dangers and the sheer unpredictability of other dangers. From their perspective, policing and subsequent adjustments in smuggling circuits require an improvised response, adapting with agility to changing conditions. Smugglers and migrants traffic in creative subversions of state control, choosing their conduct based on assumptions of uncertainty, as well as risk.

In the risk scenario, the past experiences of friends and family members can offer a reliable guide for future journeys. However, there is little stability in the strategic setting of the clandestine route as experienced by migrants.Footnote 13 The diffusion of survival information renders it suspect when criminal predators or state authorities can manipulate it to their advantage. A once-trodden path cannot necessarily be safely traversed a second time. A once-trusted guide cannot necessarily be relied upon a second time. Under these conditions, the trustworthiness of information has an immediate expiration date. In this reality, both migrants and smugglers engage in a reflexive and strategic process throughout the journey. They do not simply rely on information gleaned at the outset of their journey through their existing social networks, but instead improvise new understandings en route. In other words, migrants and smugglers, confronted with a mix of experienced risk and uncertainty, as well as an underlying context that combines risk and uncertainty, exude an extraordinarily malleable protean power.

Indeed, the level of analysis dictates how we see and experience power itself. Control power becomes most apparent when we look from the top down. Control power is the primary instrument of organized collective actors and institutions. However, when we work at the level of individual experience, protean power comes into view, as something that circulates among creative individuals. If we view the state itself through the lens of practice, we can see how protean power constitutes and compliments the exercise of the state’s control power, through a myriad of flexible everyday actions conducted by state agents and bureaucrats.Footnote 14 Frontline border patrol agents adapt and innovate on the ground, giving rise to protean power that facilitates control. While criminal bosses exercise control power over their territory, their henchmen give rise to protean power as they implement their orders. In other words, depending on whether we look at smuggling gangs and other criminal groups through the lens of an organization or as individuals within that organization, different power dynamics come into view. In contrast, migrants can be understood only as an unchoreographed collection of people engaged in collective practice, not even an approximate of a unified actor. Among the actors caught in this border collision, they are uniquely vulnerable and marginalized, depending almost entirely on protean power as a “weapon of the weak.”Footnote 15 Thus, this chapter pays close attention to how we view the ambiguous consequences of power.

The chapter is organized chronologically. We take the reader through the collision over time, in order to highlight the dynamic between protean and control power. We trace the evolution of border policing policies from the late nineteenth century to the present, showing how such policing has been premised upon assumptions of risk and the projection of an image of control. Against this policy backdrop, we juxtapose the innovations of migrants and smugglers as they adapt to changes in policing over time. Migrants and their smugglers make assumptions of uncertainty and subvert control through improvisation.

However, the alliance between migrants and their smugglers is often an uneasy marriage of convenience and complicated by pressures from other criminal actors and the state. While migrants often improvise together with their smugglers to achieve the shared goal of clandestine passage, migrants also sometimes generate protean power as they resist their smugglers. Indeed, the complexity of these relationships requires us to disentangle the sometimes compatible, sometimes divergent interests of migrants, their smugglers, criminal terrain bosses, and the state. Creative moments emerge from actors’ negotiation of these complex relationships and their contradictions. Border control unwittingly spawns new types of criminal characters, who seem to exude both kinds of power to exploit migrants. In Mexico, these struggles have culminated in the arrival of criminal bosses who more effectively control passage across their territory than the state. The existence of multiple actors with cross-cutting interests and capabilities complicates the effects of power.

The Collision in Historical Perspective

The collision between protean and control power across the US–Mexico border is hardly new, though it has certainly intensified over time.Footnote 16 Many of the border dynamics of immigration law enforcement and evasion we see today can be viewed as representing the latest chapter in an old story that dates back at least a century – a story that does not simply repeat itself, but nevertheless has a remarkably consistent and recognizable theme: through their interaction, protean and control power have stimulated and reinforced each other. Periods of low control power have typically also been periods of low protean power; likewise, as the exercise of control power by the state has increased, so too has the presence of protean power. Indeed, protean power is integral to the functioning of control power. Thus, ironically, while seemingly in opposition to each other, these two forms of power have also been symbiotic, creating space for one another.

Given all the attention today over the influx of Mexicans and Central Americans across the border, it is especially striking that the first unauthorized immigrants crossing the border from Mexico viewed by US authorities as a problem were actually Chinese. Efforts to prohibit Chinese immigration in the late nineteenth century mark the beginning of the federal government’s long and tumultuous history of trying to keep out “undesirables.” The Chinese Exclusion Act of 1882 barred the entry of Chinese laborers, who until then were mostly coming in by steamship to San Francisco. But while this front-door entry was closing, back doors were opening, especially via the US–Canada border and the US–Mexico border. The federal government had no stand-alone immigration control apparatus when the Chinese Exclusion Act was passed, but enforcement of the law would stimulate the creation of entirely new federal administrative capacities.

The US–Mexico border, long a gateway for smuggled goods, was now also becoming a gateway for smuggled people. In 1900, there were just a few thousand Chinese in Mexico, but less than a decade later nearly 60,000 Chinese migrants had departed to Mexico. Some stayed, but the United States was a far more attractive destination.Footnote 17 In his investigations, US Immigration Inspector Marcus Braun witnessed Chinese arriving in Mexico and reported that “On their arrival in Mexico, I found them to be provided with United States money, not Mexican coins; they had in their possession Chinese–English dictionaries; I found them in possession of Chinese–American newspapers and of American railroad maps.”Footnote 18 In 1907, a US government investigator observed that between twenty and fifty Chinese arrived daily in the Mexican border town of Juarez by train, but that the Chinese community in the town never grew. As he put it, “Chinamen coming to Ciudad Juarez either vanish into thin air or cross the border line.”Footnote 19 Foreshadowing future developments, a January 1904 editorial in the El Paso Herald-Post warned that “If this Chinese immigration to Mexico continues it will be necessary to run a barb wire fence along our side of the Rio Grande.” The El Paso immigration inspector stated in his 1905 annual report that migrant smuggling is the sole business of “perhaps one-third of the Chinese population of El Paso.”Footnote 20

Some historians note that border smuggling operations involved cross-racial business collaborations, with white male smugglers often working with Chinese organizers and Mexicans serving as local border guides. A 1906 law enforcement report on Chinese smuggling noted, “All through northern Mexico, along the lines of the railroad, are located so-called boarding houses and restaurants, which are the rendezvous of the Chinese and their smugglers, and the small towns and villages throughout this section are filled with Chinese coolies, whose only occupation seems to be lying in wait until arrangements can be perfected for carrying them across the border.”Footnote 21

As US authorities tightened enforcement at urban entry points along the California–Mexico border, smugglers shifted to more remote parts of the border further east in Arizona, New Mexico, and Texas. And this provided the rationale to deploy more agents to these border areas (this dynamic would repeat itself again at the end of the century). In addition to hiring more port inspectors, a force of mounted inspectors was set up to patrol the borderline by horseback. As smugglers in later years turned to new technologies such as automobiles, officials also pushed for the use of the same technologies for border control.Footnote 22

Chinese migrants were not the only ones coming through the back door; they were simply at the top of a growing list of “undesirables” that included paupers, criminals, prostitutes, “lunatics,” “idiots,” polygamists, anarchists, “imbeciles,” and contract workers in general. Japanese laborers were banned in 1907. Illiterates were banned from entry in 1917. As seaports became more tightly regulated and policed, immigrants who feared being placed in one of these excludable categories increasingly turned to the back door. Those groups that were disproportionately being turned away at the front-door ports of entry – among them Lebanese, Greeks, Italians, Slavs from the Balkans, and Jews – found Mexico to be a convenient back-door alternative.Footnote 23

The popularity of the Mexican back door received a major boost by new US restrictions on European immigration through the national origins quotas in 1921 and 1924. Passport rules left over from the First World War formalized in the Passport Act of 1918, also now required immigrants to secure visas at US consulates abroad. The Mexico smuggling route offered a way to sidestep these new numerical restrictions and documentation requirements. This sparked alarm in Washington and provided political ammunition for calls for more border enforcement. The commissioner-general of immigration reported in 1923 that each new entry restriction “promoted the alien smuggling industry and furnished new and multiplied incentives to illegal entry.”Footnote 24 The commissioner’s report the following year predicted that the Immigration Law of 1924 “Will result in a further influx of undesirable European aliens to Mexico with the sole object in view of affecting illegal entry into the United States over the Rio Grande.”Footnote 25

Local media reports reinforced these concerns. A December 22, 1924 article in El Paso’s Spanish-language newspaper La Patria pointed to the booming cross-border business for “contrabandistas de carne humana” (“smugglers of human meat”) in the wake of the new US immigration restrictions.Footnote 26 The article (with the headline “Foreigners who want to cross over to the United States have invaded the city of Juarez”) described Juarez as a depot for foreigners waiting to enter the United States.Footnote 27 The US Congress greatly expanded the immigration bureau’s personnel powers to search and arrest along and near the borderline. In a country otherwise wary of increasing the power and reach of government, border control was clearly one realm where there was a push to bolster federal authority.

Political pressure had been building up for a number of years to create a uniformed border patrol force. The US Border Patrol was formed in 1924 with a $1 million budget and a total force of some 450 officers. Its primary mission was to keep out illegal immigrants, especially the smuggling of Europeans. Wesley Stile, one of the first border patrol agents hired in the summer of 1924, later recalled, “the thing that established the Border Patrol was the influx of European aliens.” Border patrolmen “didn’t pay much attention to the Mexicans” because they were considered merely cheap seasonal farm labor that returned to Mexico when no longer needed.Footnote 28 This meant that the growing influx of unauthorized Mexican workers was largely tolerated and overlooked – at least for the time being.

For Mexicans, crossing the border illegally was relatively simple and largely ignored – successful entry did not require much creative agility. Up to half a million Mexicans may have come to the United States in the first decade of the century. The Mexican Revolution, US labor shortages during the First World War, and the continued expansion of agriculture in the southwest fueled a further influx. There was a growing disconnect between the formal entry rules handed down from a distant capital and the realities, needs, and practices along the border. In other words, the “control power” called for in national immigration laws did not translate into its application on the ground.

As a substitute for European and Asian workers, employers considered Mexicans an ideal labor force: flexible, compliant, and temporary – or so it seemed at the time. Millions of unauthorized Mexican migrants would eventually settle in the United States, becoming a vital source of labor for agriculture and other sectors of the economy but also the main rationale for more intensive border enforcement. It was not until 1929 that US border inspectors even made any real effort to regulate the entry of Mexican nationals; even as late as the 1980s, border controls remained at token levels. US Border Patrol agents could cover only about 10 percent of the nearly 2,000-mile border, and most of those apprehended were simply sent back across the line to try again. Most smugglers caught were simply let go, and those who were not were charged with a misdemeanor.Footnote 29

Anemic enforcement (a bare minimum exercise of control power) meant that illegal entry across the border remained a relatively simple and inexpensive activity: migrants either smuggled themselves across the border or hired a local coyote. The use of a professional smuggler remained more of a convenience than a necessity. Hiring the services of a smuggler generally meant a faster and safer trip across the line. Use of a smuggler did involve personal risks (there was the potential for theft and physical abuse), but attempting the border crossing without such help increased the likelihood of assault by border bandits and abuse by authorities.

The long if uneasy border equilibrium between relatively low levels of control power and protean power became unsustainable in the midst of a growing domestic anti-immigrant backlash that culminated in the 1990s, with California (home to an estimated half of the nation’s unauthorized migrant population) at the epicenter. Just as the late nineteenth-century backlash against Chinese immigrants began in California, so too did the backlash against Mexican immigrants in the late twentieth century – with the fallout spreading across the entire border.

In the heated early and mid-1990s policy debates about illegal immigration and a seemingly “out of control” border, in which politicians from across the political spectrum were scrambling to outdo each other in proposing tough new immigration-control measures, the federal government launched a high-profile border enforcement crackdown. Long viewed as the neglected stepchild of the Department of Justice, the Immigration and Naturalization Service (INS) suddenly became one of the fastest-growing federal agencies. The INS budget grew from $1.5 billion in fiscal year 1993 to $4 billion in fiscal year 1999, with border enforcement by far the single largest line item. The size of the Border Patrol more than doubled along the border by the end of the decade. The new border enforcement campaign also included an influx of new equipment, ranging from night-vision scopes and low-light TV cameras to ground sensors, helicopters, and all-terrain vehicles. The military also played a supporting role by assisting with the operation of night scopes, motion sensors, and communications equipment, as well as building and maintaining roads and fences.Footnote 30

Congress assured that the border build-up would continue by passing the Illegal Immigration Reform and Immigrant Responsibility Act of 1996. The sweeping law sharply increased the penalties against migrant smugglers, and authorized the hiring of 1,000 Border Patrol agents a year, reaching a total force of more than 10,000 by 2001. Most of these agents would be deployed to the most popular urban entry points for unauthorized migration, such as El Paso and San Diego, with the goal of disrupting and deterring the flow. Left out of this immigration-control offensive was any meaningful focus on workplace controls – in other words, the application of “control power” was highly selective and focused. It was highly visible, but also extremely thin.

Not surprisingly, tighter border controls in El Paso and San Diego pushed migrants to attempt entry elsewhere along the border. These shifts in human traffic, in turn, generated further political pressures and bureaucratic rationale to geographically expand the border-policing campaign. Consequently, a Border Patrol force that had already more than doubled in the 1990s more than doubled again in the first decade of the twenty-first century.

In order to cross a now much more intensively patrolled border successfully, migrants increasingly turned to professional smugglers. As INS commissioner Doris Meisner acknowledged, “as we improve our enforcement, we increase the smuggling of aliens that occurs, because it is harder to cross and so therefore people turn more and more to smugglers.”Footnote 31 And as the risks and smuggling fees jumped (from hundreds of dollars to thousands of dollars per crossing), smuggling became a much more organized and sophisticated business. Breaking up the traditional routes and methods of clandestine entry turned the once relatively simple illegal act of entry without inspection into a more complex underground web of illegality. Put differently, the greater control power exercised by the state made migrants more dependent on protean power and smugglers.

In turn, US officials went to great lengths to portray migrants as the victims of smugglers, and they used this both to deflect criticism and to provide a further rationale to crack down on smuggling. But this was a much too simple and convenient a characterization of smugglers. Migrants generally viewed smugglers as simply a “necessary evil,” a clandestine business transaction in which they willingly engaged to evade the expanding border enforcement net. Within Mexico, many considered migrant smuggling a shady business, but one that was providing a high-demand service. Smugglers could be abusive and reckless, and their efforts to bypass law enforcement could place migrants at great risk; hundreds were dying every year in trying to cross the border in the harsh and remote terrain where border enforcement was thinnest. Yet smugglers were hired precisely because they generally provided a safer, faster, and more reliable border-crossing experience.

Smugglers also became more skilled as border enforcement became more intensive. Although some of the local freelance entrepreneurs who once dominated migrant smuggling along the border were being squeezed out by the border-enforcement offensive, they were replaced by better organized and more skilled migrant-smuggling organizations. This, in turn, was used to justify tougher laws and tougher enforcement. The number of smugglers being prosecuted mushroomed, and more punitive sentencing guidelines significantly increased the length of prison terms for smugglers. But this did not translate into a shortage of smugglers. More risks translated into higher smuggling fees. And as the risks for smuggling rose, so too did the incentive for smugglers to use more dangerous methods to avoid law enforcement.

The Lived Experience of Today’s Collision

As we have seen, although the collision between protean and control power along the US–Mexico divide is not new, it has intensified. Contemporary relationships between the state, migrants, smugglers, and criminal terrain bosses are themselves an outcome of over a century of these power collisions at the US border. However, the latest chapter of this old story further complicates simple narratives about the interactions of these actors and their relative power. Drawing on ethnographic materials collected in a study of clandestine Central American migration to the United States,Footnote 32 we trace the power dynamics within these relationships. This tracing reveals the sometimes contradictory and sometimes symbiotic connections between protean and control power. It also reveals the lived contradictions of protean power, as experienced by migrants themselves.

The on-the-ground experience of the US government control agenda is a story of protean power. The everyday practice of policy implementation requires discretion and deft maneuvers on the part of the street-level bureaucrats.Footnote 33 Border control is not an exception to this general rule; it too generates protean power. Routines must be adapted to a lived reality, or they are rendered useless; patrols cannot keep a strict schedule and unchanging route without becoming predictable and easy to evade by smugglers. Frontline immigration agents must rely on discretion,Footnote 34 their wits, innovations and improvisations on protocols and stereotypesFootnote 35 to adapt to unforeseen events at the border.Footnote 36 A border official explained the gut feeling that develops with experience, “But people develop a sense. It’s like at the border. The agents can see a car coming from half a mile away. Maybe the mannerisms are just not right. It’s just that something doesn’t feel right. The agents have a difficult time articulating the probable cause. They just know who to stop.” After further questioning, the border official explained that, “In law enforcement, we call it profiling.”Footnote 37 Indeed, the US courts implicitly recognize the necessary role of protean power, by granting border patrol agents greater discretion in their job than any other law enforcement agent.Footnote 38 In order to empower them to make judgments and act on their wits at the border, the courts have defined standards for probable cause loosely for US Border Patrol. As the state attempts to increase its control power at the border, this discretion, which creates a space for border agents to exercise their protean power, plays an increasingly vital role in the national security agenda.

In response to the increased control power exercised by the state, smugglers and migrants generate a collective protean power. Indeed, smugglers and migrants sometimes co-improvise migration strategies to achieve their common objectives. The most reputable smugglers behave as service providers, treating migrants as valued customers, protecting them from criminal predators, or settling disputes among travel companions. In turn, migrants generally agree to keep the smuggler’s identity secret if they are apprehended by border patrol. For their part, experienced migrants may be called upon to assist smugglers, helping to guide or maintain order in the travel group. Indeed, the boundary between smuggler and migrant may be blurred, when these migrants accept travel discounts, receive upgraded treatment, or other payments for such auxiliary support. Experienced migrants may begin to work as guides. Sometimes migrants co-innovate new migration tactics. As Maria’s story from the introduction illustrates, collective brainstorming or migrant–smuggler partnerships to devise new ways around unexpected barriers to mobility are not uncommon.

When Maria and her smuggler had devised the plan to sing gospel, she and her companions did not know that far greater dangers awaited them in northern Mexico. At a point just north of Puebla, Maria’s guide slipped into the secret compartment alongside the migrants. If stopped, he would pass as one of them, and they had all sworn to protect his identity. His decision to conceal himself among loyal clients proved to be fortuitous. A new guide drove the banana truck in which they were hidden. Squatting in these cramped quarters in the hidden compartment, Maria heard the three gunshots that killed the driver. They had been stopped by a heavily armed group of bandits, dressed in black. Based on their paramilitary appearance and ruthless behavior, Maria presumed these men and women to be the Zetas. Having recently taken control of the territory, this criminal group had not received the appropriate passage fee from the Salvadoran smugglers. Thus, the bandits kidnapped the migrants and held them until family members or friends paid for their delivery. And the bandits began to negotiate with Maria’s hometown smuggler for a more regular fee to cross their territory. The kidnappers treated Maria and her travel companions harshly, but Maria was fortunate because this criminal group delivered her to New York in exchange for the smuggling payment. Every year thousands of migrants are not so lucky; kidnappers often release migrants in Mexico, rather than the United States, or turn them over to Mexican migration authorities for deportation after receiving ransoms. Sometimes they keep their victims indefinitely, breaking promises and demanding ever more money from desperate family members. Luckily for Maria, she arrived and lived in New York for several years, before returning home to El Salvador as a local success story. She saved the money to build her dream home and open a restaurant near the center of town, until extortion demands and threats from a Salvadoran street gang forced her to migrate a second time.

When Maria made the return journey to the United States in 2010, she contracted with the same hometown smuggler for the second passage from El Salvador to New York. She did so despite the killing of the guide he had subcontracted and her subsequent kidnapping during the first journey. However, Maria made this choice of smuggling service provider not primarily to avoid US border agents or Mexican migration authorities, but because the hometown smuggler probably knew which criminals to pay to cross Mexico safely. She was primarily frightened of the Zetas drug-trafficking organization operating in Mexico, which had acquired infamy for their kidnapping of migrants for ransom. Ultimately, Maria and her family crossed Mexico, but were captured by the US border patrol.

They immediately filed an asylum claim based on the criminal gang-based persecution they had suffered in El Salvador, and this claim was eventually granted. Indeed, an increasing number of Central Americans turn themselves in to US border agents or allow themselves to be captured in order to file asylum claims. Some smugglers instruct their clients to do so, improvising upon the legal resources made available to migrants by the state. While many of these claims are in fact well-founded asylum cases, smugglers and migrants nevertheless deftly leverage the state’s own institutions against its control power. Thus, the “cracks and contradictions” of institutions (Reus-Smit, Chapter 3, pp. 60, 61, 66, 68) provide opportunities for improvisation and innovation; in this case, borders and the refugee protection regime collide, demonstrating how, at the right moment, migrants and smugglers can exploit the nexus of “co-existing, overlapping, but often discordant singular institutions” (Reus-Smit, Chapter 3, p. 61).

In the contemporary context of the escalation of the Mexican drug war (post-2006), Central American migrants like Maria no longer only pay smugglers to resist the control power of the state. Instead, these migrants also pay smugglers to help them negotiate a perilous passage across territory controlled by Mexican criminal terrain bosses. For Central Americans, the danger of Mexican criminal terrain bosses is the primary motivation for contracting a smuggler. Well-informed migrants often pay smugglers not because they know their way around US border patrol efforts, but because their smugglers know which criminal to pay for safe passage.Footnote 39 As explained by one migrant, “A good coyote is well connected; he knows who and how to bribe.”Footnote 40 The control power of Mexican criminal territory bosses, who extort crossing fees from both migrants and smugglers, guarantees that the profession of smuggling will remain profitable. This shift in control to criminal territory bosses illustrates the dynamic between control and protean power over time, and it signals how actors may be impacted by multiple forms of power depending on which relationship they engage.

When the drug war erupted spectacularly in 2006, Mexican territory began to change hands quickly and without warning among competing criminal gangs. The Mexican crime groups splintered with fighting between and within. These gangs began to kidnap northbound migrants for profit. They also kidnapped migrants to renegotiate passage fees with Central American human smugglers. The fees for criminal crossing increased in tandem with the intensification of violence, rapid shifts in criminal control, the breaking of old business protocols, and the fragmentation of terrain among competing gangs.

At the same time, beginning in the aftermath of September 11 and continuing into the present, bilateral US–Mexican cooperation for contraband interdiction has intensified.Footnote 41 Most recently, in 2014, Mexico launched a reinvigorated “Plan Sur” primarily policing the southern train routes that the poorest and most vulnerable migrants often board like hobos to get to the United States. To give a sense of the magnitude of this policing effort, the number of Central Americans deported from Mexico has exceeded the number deported from the United States.Footnote 42 Such immigration enforcement operations have made migrants ever-more reliant on hiring smugglers for successful arrival in the United States.

Despite this massive Mexican enforcement campaign, as well as ongoing fighting within and between gangs, criminals have proven to be more adept at controlling clandestine traffic through their territory than the state. Working through both civilian informants and corrupt state officials, their intelligence networks actively identify smugglers and migrants who have not paid the requisite passage fee. The efficiency of these stealthy networks is legendary among migrants, who sometimes whisper about the spies who travel alongside them to collect information for criminals. Even if US border enforcement were to disappear, human smuggling would now persist as a profession, because migrants – especially non-Mexican migrants – need the smugglers’ contacts to negotiate passage across criminal terrain. Ironically, Mexican criminal bosses generate protean power; they deftly manipulate expansive social networks, fluid shifting alliances, the recruitment of former soldiers and police with counterinsurgency skills, violent stagecraft and message murders that project an intimidating reputation, and other flexible tactics. In so doing, the Mexican criminal bosses impose greater control power along smuggling routes than do states.

The ruthlessness of the Mexican criminal bosses is infamous by design, not unlike modern-day terrorist organizations that capitalize on their violent and powerful image with carefully publicized acts (Mendelsohn, Chapter 9). As the drug war has intensified during the past decade, criminal groups have employed increasingly brutal methods to extract money from Central American smugglers and their migrant clients. Capture by border patrol may force migrants to begin the journey again, a terrible prospect after coming so far from home. For migrants with criminal records or multiple crossing attempts, capture by the border patrol may even be punished with a lengthy prison sentence. However, these consequences pale in comparison with the torture, trafficking, rape, ransom demands, and, sometimes, murders that occur at the hands of Mexican criminal territory bosses, such as the Zetas or the so-called “Gulf cartel.” Ransoms generally cost migrants’ families thousands of dollars, often money that had been borrowed to pay smugglers for the delivery of migrants in the United States. Without the migrant to work off the debt in the United States, immigrant families that pay these ransoms may be left financially destitute. To extract sufficient information to make these ransom demands or to intimidate migrants into submission, kidnappers sometimes cut off their victim’s fingers or beat them with wooden boards. Female migrants may be trafficked for sex work rather than ransomed. Conditions in the drop houses where migrants are held for ransom can only be described as deplorable. When thinking about making a clandestine journey, US border policing is often the least of Central American migrants’ worries.

Criminal territory bosses are not the only non-state actors who attempt to dominate migrants. Despite their shared enemies of the state and dangerous criminal terrain bosses, smugglers have also long been infamous for the exploitation of their clients, imposing control over migrants. This is perhaps even truer today than in the past. Even in early periods of border crossing, smugglers had been known to threaten and intimidate female migrants into having unwanted sexual relations. Smugglers may not keep promises about travel and living conditions en route, subjecting migrants to more suffering than expected. Smugglers sometimes steal from and cheat migrants, abandoning them in dangerous places along the route. They may sell their human cargo to traffickers. Smugglers may collaborate with kidnappers, who demand ransoms from family members in the United States without delivering them there. Finally, smugglers may suddenly attempt to renegotiate their contract with the migrant at a vulnerable moment during the journey, extorting more money than the original agreement had entailed.

At some point during the journey, virtually all Central American migrants experience a deprivation of liberty at the hands of their smuggler, even when the migrant–smuggler contract is consensual, rather than the outcome of a kidnapping.Footnote 43 Migrants may be locked inside a hidden compartment of a vehicle, incapable of escaping if conditions turn dangerously hot or oxygen-deprived. They may be locked in an unsanitary drop house with other migrants for days or weeks to wait for an opportune moment to make the next segment of the journey, or to wait for a payment to the smuggler from US-based relatives.

It should be pointed out that this predatory protean power, benefiting smugglers as well as other criminal organizations, ultimately contributes to the US policy goal of making the border harder for migrants to cross (even as migrants rely on smugglers and the bribing of criminal organizations to make it across the border). In this way, predatory protean power serves as an unintended accomplice in control power objectives. Nevertheless, migrants are not powerless. They resist smugglers and kidnappers. Escape stories abound, as migrants flee buildings that are poorly equipped to hold hundreds of captives or take advantage of drunken debauchery during football matches or holidays to slip past inebriated guards. In interviews, a migrant found a window in a bathroom, another carefully learned the schedule of his captors, and yet another broke through a shoddily constructed wall to find freedom. Acts of collective resistance also erupt in these drop houses, and in one particularly dramatic story, migrants grabbed pitchforks and shards of broken glass to defend themselves against armed assailants.Footnote 44 Migrants may submit to their captors outwardly in appearance only, but continue to conspire quietly to regain their freedom.

However, protean power comes at a terrible cost for many migrants. The Honduran man, Maynard, who told the dramatic story of resisting kidnappers with pitchforks and broken glass wept when he remembered how the kidnappers beheaded his co-conspirator; their plan had been discovered prematurely, because a particularly hungry captive had informed on them in exchange for food rations. It had been the second time Maynard had been betrayed by another migrant; a Honduran “friend” had sold him to the kidnappers. Other migrants who survived kidnappings wept, rather than congratulate themselves on their impressive feats of resistance and wit, as they thought of the people left behind or the expense of the ransoms to their families. Migrants often do not experience a sense of empowerment from their capacity to negotiate a humiliating, morally compromising and physically difficult journey.

The physical sacrifices of the journey are common knowledge across the region, leaving lasting scars on the bodies of border crossers. For those that survive the passage, the price of protean power still potentially includes extreme hunger and malnutrition, exposure to the elements or wildlife, illness from contaminated water, suffering assaults, disembodiment from falls from the train, and injuries in the desert. However, these scars often run deeper than the skin and bones of a migrant.

The trauma of the journey can leave lasting social and moral traces in the psyche of border crossers. Even the most successful border crossers must lie or alienate themselves from loved ones to survive. A Salvadoran woman, Ana, traveled with her two small children and a military-age nephew across Mexico in the late 1980s.Footnote 45 She tearfully described the ethical dilemmas she faced in transit. Her husband had already fled due to political persecution during the civil war. Her nephew had been a low-ranking infantryman, and he deserted to flee the violence. On the way north, they boarded a bus, pretending to be Mexican. The guide kept them separate, and told them that they must all act like strangers. Her nephew was sitting a few seats from her when police boarded the bus and took him away. At this point in the story, Ana wept remembering how she could only assume that he was being led away to his death, “Imagine pretending you don’t know your own nephew … But that is how it is on the road.” To survive, she had to momentarily disavow her kin, silently watching him be led to potential slaughter.Footnote 46 She thereby maintained her disguise and continued north, exercising her power to move and protecting her children, but at a terrible emotional and, in Ana’s interpretation, moral cost. Her power to migrate was inexorably tied to her acceptance of her powerlessness to help her nephew.

Later in the journey, Ana traveled in a private car with her children and smuggler. Before passing through the highway migration checkpoint, Ana and her smuggler had to coach her young son. The smuggler instructed the boy to say he was his father if anyone asked. The seven-year-old boy became indignant at the suggestion, “You are not my father! My father is in the US and we are going to him!” The smuggler was patient, but the situation was critical. The boy had to be taught how to lie. While interviewing her, Ana shook her head with sadness at the memory of threatening her son to dissuade him from telling the truth. While she did not say it aloud, perhaps, her thoughts briefly skipped ahead to the rebellious young man he later became, a regret that she had discussed on other occasions. Deception is part of the power that migrants can draw upon, but they do so at a cost. In Ana’s estimation, she paid with her son’s virtue and her own responsibility as his mother. Teaching her son to lie went against her principles as a mother and a devout Catholic, but morality must be bent (in this case, somewhat gently) in the realm of protean power.

However traumatizing the journey might be for Ana, telling lies to migration police is one of the lesser moral quandaries that migrants face in transit today. In the contemporary context, migrants may be forced to collaborate with criminal terrain bosses and kidnappers. A small minority of migrants become spies infiltrating the migration stream. They lead groups of migrants into ambush or monitor the activities of human rights activists, smugglers, and other migrants for criminal bosses. These co-opted migrants become the eyes and feet of criminal networks along the smuggling route. Migrants’ capacity to go undetected among their co-nationals is a form of protean power that comes from the ability to cleverly disguise intentions and improvise upon social expectations and stereotypes to forge new relationships. In turn, this protean power serves as a resource for criminal territory bosses to exert control power over the smuggling route. Such protean power enables the migrant’s survival and mobility, but at the expense of others.

This form of collaboration represents neither outright resistance nor acceptance of the control power of the state. Such collaboration on the part of migrants is a survival tactic that mirrors relationships that form across a variety of violent settings, generating what Primo Levi calls a “grey zone,” where distinctions between victims and perpetrators become blurry.Footnote 47 The fact that this power comes at the price of solidarity among Central Americans and an increase in the suffering of a vulnerable population does not go unnoticed by migrants. As a Honduran woman ruefully lamented, “They are us, same as us: Hondurans, Guatemalans, Salvadorans. My own paisanos are those that rob. That’s why you can’t trust people in the [Catholic migrant] shelter either.” The Honduran woman turned to a Guatemalan girl next to her, “You don’t know who they are, your own paisanos.”Footnote 48 Indeed, a sense of betrayal often accompanies the experience of the journey. A shadowy world of mistrust, chameleon-like characters, and ephemeral alliances is the price of protean power.

Conclusion: Protean Power and Predation

As this chapter has suggested, protean power should not simply be equated with “empowerment.” It is worth noting that migrants themselves do not celebrate protean power. They would much rather see a dramatic immigration policy change than be forced to improvise a terrible and dangerous clandestine journey. They would rather the state leave them alone than be forced to respond to it with agility and ingenuity. In fact, the practices in which they must engage during the journey are often experienced as profoundly disempowering and dehumanizing. As Maria’s and Ana’s stories suggest, survival often requires painful compromises of morality or extraordinary physical sacrifices.

Protean power is not a form of solidarity that promises to bring us to a more just or equitable world. It is a fragmented force that enables some individuals to navigate a path to the United States, but does not address the larger socio-economic and political structures that motivate migrant journeys and shape the migration route. Predatory patterns emerge from protean power generated by some migrants as they survive violence at the expense of their compatriots. Such predation may thwart some political projects and undermine a sense of shared identity. Furthermore, protean power seems better fit for creative resistance of control than to capturing and controlling the direction of state policy.

As far as migrants are concerned, “weapons of the weak” are a distant second best to a US immigration policy revolution. For this reason, Reece Jones calls everyday practices that transgress state boundaries, but without an overt political motivation, a form of “refusal” rather than “resistance.”Footnote 49 Such activities are disruptive and have structural effects, but their participants do not necessarily understand them as resistance or empowerment. Protean power clearly complicates control power. Nevertheless, control power also necessitates and, in an important sense, generates its own antithesis in protean power. Likewise, protean power constitutes control power. When viewed through the lens of experience, even the state requires the protean power of individuals to implement its control. Finally, given the perverse escalation spirals that sometimes emerge from the interaction of the two forms of power, the future structural effects of protean power remain unclear, and may ultimately reinforce control power rather than undermine it. Nevertheless, protean power is creative and, thus, a form of agency that cannot be overlooked if we wish to understand the dynamic process of control and evasion at the border.

Indeed, using different levels of analysis, we have explored the interaction of control power and protean power, showing how their collision has produced a humanitarian catastrophe at the border, not just a failure to curb migration. If we only look from the top down at the border, we see a mirage of control that might be heralded as a victory for policing. Nonetheless, it is a pyrrhic victory of control power, representing a decrease in the visibility of an otherwise continuous flow of unauthorized migrants across the US–Mexico line. Nor, however, can continued border crossings be heralded as a victory of protean power. If we look through an ethnographic lens from the bottom up, where protean power becomes visible for individuals, we have seen the true consequences of the attempt to impose control: dramatically intensified human suffering. The interaction of control with protean power produces this tragic outcome. Shifting the line of sight of our analysis brings the tragedy, as well as the victory, of protean power into focus. Border guards and border crossers both experience profound uncertainty and risk, and ethnographic methods bring this experiential level into view. Thus, for the contemporary period, we augment our historical analysis with ethnographic research on the day-to-day experience of Central American migrants attempting to clandestinely reach and cross the US–Mexico border.

From this analysis, we find that at key moments control power is constituted by protean power. We can see this complementarity when we move up and down the levels of analysis from collective actors to practice. At the level of practice, the state generates the protean power as its individual immigration agents exert control power at the border. These improvised practices constitute the state, and the protean power generated by individuals engaged in such improvisations constitutes the state’s control power. Similarly, organized gangs that control territory require the protean power of individual criminals, that is, the smugglers, look-outs, enforcers, and others. Moving up and down the levels of analysis shows us how protean power complements, and in some ways creates spaces for the operation of control power.

In other moments, control power and protean power of various actors interact, leading to a spiral of intensification with yet unpredictable outcomes. As the state exerts control power, it calls protean power into existence. Necessity is the mother of invention, and border control is the mother of improvised smuggling and migration practice. The protean power generated by migrants and smugglers then destabilizes the façade of control, justifying further control effort by the state. We see this interaction by moving across history.

Although beyond the scope of this chapter, this type of analysis could be extended to the recent plight of African and Middle Eastern migrants attempting to enter Europe. Attempts to control illegal traffic across the Mediterranean have had an ambiguous, and often counterproductive, impact on clandestine flows. An unrelenting unauthorized traffic drifts north from the northern African coastline. For the last two decades of policing intensification, the bodies of failed border crossers have washed ashore on European beaches alongside tourists. While a massive allocation of resources to fortify the European continent against these flows has not succeeded in stemming the tide of contraband and migration,Footnote 50 it has dramatically restructured the lived experience of migration in ways similar to those survived by Central American migrants seeking to enter the United States.Footnote 51 The geographic focal points,Footnote 52 social relationships, and smuggling networksFootnote 53 that underpin routes adapt to policing.

Since the 1990s, the Mediterranean crossing has grown more dangerous for unauthorized migrants,Footnote 54 especially in recent years. In response to the Syrian refugee crisis and a recent series of high-profile calamities suffered by boat migrants during clandestine passages, NATO ships have been deployed to the Aegean Sea to deter human smuggling.Footnote 55 Our analysis leads to the expectation that, despite its humanitarian justifications, these militarized deterrence efforts will lead to a formidable increase of suffering, but ultimately prove incapable of halting clandestine flows into Europe. Instead, the complex collision between the control power of the state and the protean power generated by migrants will likely continue to expand and intensify on the periphery of Europe.

Our chapter has shown how a ground-level line of sight helps us to sort out precisely these complex effects of power on diverse actors and their relationships. We find that different forms of power alternate, cross-cutting between empowerment and disempowerment at key moments in interactions between state actors, smugglers, migrants, and criminal territory bosses. Furthermore, the ground-level line of sight, at the level of experience, brings surprising instances of protean power into view, sometimes constituting the control power exerted by collective actors like the state. In this way, we complicate the dichotomy between state–non-state actors and their relationship to control–protean power. Recently, much to the chagrin of low-ranking smugglers, more powerful criminal actors have imposed control over clandestine flows through their terrain. The tightened control of terrain by criminal bosses represents a new iteration of, and increasingly complex interplay between, control and protean power. Migrants must sometimes resist the control of their own smugglers, and the very existence of smuggling as a profession is predicated on the imperfect but potent control power of the state and now criminal territory bosses. Power reverberates in often unpredictable ways through these layered and shifting relationships between the state, smugglers, territory bosses, and migrants, as experienced by the individuals implicated within them. Across the US–-Mexico border and across the globe, states have tightened enforcement, thereby restructuring these layered and shifting relationships, intensifying the experience of uncertainty along clandestine routes, and often unwittingly complicating (though not undoing) control power by calling protean power into existence.

6 High-Tech: Power and Unpredictability at the Technological Frontier and in Bitcoin

Lucia A. Seybert and Peter J. Katzenstein Footnote 1

In scientific inquiry and technological change the presence of uncertainty, linked to power, is explicitly acknowledged and actively explored. Innovation and improvisation define and constitute manifestations of protean power that are related closely to more familiar control power. The resulting technological and knowledge shifts have important consequences, as actors cope with questions and solutions that arise in the face of risk and uncertainty.

This chapter focuses on these dynamics. They unfold in especially interesting ways when the most relevant actors agree that uncertainty is pervasive and unavoidable. Two empirical illustrations, knowledge frontiers and bitcoin technology, explore the different manifestations of protean power in detail. The first example traces improvisation, learning, and advances in science and technology fields, taking us well beyond the narrow bounds of the “controlled” experiments on which they rest. The innovation fueling scientific discovery and start-up industries occurs in contexts so complex that the outcomes and underlying processes remain in the realm of unknown unknowns. The second example explores the bitcoin revolution that combines radical and operational uncertainty, the responses they elicit, and the co-evolution between control and protean power.

Knowledge Frontiers

The drive to improve the human condition unites innovators of all stripes. With each discovery or novel solution, new hurdles arise. Some obstacles can be the direct result, anticipated or not, of changes initially labeled as progress. A common theme across scientific disciplines and fields of innovation is the continuous debate about the adequacy of questions asked and the reliability of answers offered. When a scientist sets out to conduct a series of experiments, she or he cannot know whether she or he will get a publication or the Nobel Prize. When an entrepreneur presents the plans for a new start-up, the viability, profitability, and overall impact of his or her endeavor is unknown. What drives these actors is not a pre-determined risk calculation. Instead, curiosity, intuition, understanding of particular conditions, and the ability to spot opportunities as they arise fill the air in science laboratories and start-up incubators. The levels of eventual payoff, if any, are unrelated to actor expectations. The pursuit of solutions and improvements may bring about transformative change that falls well beyond the intended reach. The uncertainty surrounding such projects allows no guarantees; even highly promising projects can disappoint or turn into sources of danger.Footnote 2

This section draws on examples from the outer bounds of science and technology that illustrate the varying degree to which actors seek or relinquish control power. The question is particularly resonant in these areas. Innovators understand better than most that whatever projects they launch, deep-seated uncertainty is their constant companion. They do, however, opt for different approaches in their daily confrontations with unknown or unknowable unknowns. And this produces different types of relations between control and protean power in a context marked by different constellations of risk and uncertainty. The following episodes span the range from attempts at carving out as much control power as possible; to instances where its advantages are exploited with its limits fully recognized, and, finally, to situations where no control is sought in the first place.

DNA Editing

In the form of precision, reproducibility, and efficacy, control goes a long way in scientific experiments. It is therefore not surprising that CRISPR, a gene editing technique that meets all these requirements, swept through the world of molecular biology at unprecedented rates upon its initial publication in 2012. This reaction across many disciplines, led to an innovative and fundamentally agile implementation of the novel method and so endowed its creators with protean power. It altered how scientists handle both operational and radical uncertainty associated with studying living organisms. Without needing years of training or expensive equipment, scientists around the world can now use CRISPR to modify the DNA of any cell in an expedient and deliberate way.Footnote 3 Not long ago, such technology was a matter of far-flung ambitions or science fiction. Today, the ability to modify genes at will affects virtually all bio-engineering and medical fields, from disease resistance in crops to studying human cancer mutations. Mistakes in editing the genome have been reduced to a minimum. The enthusiasm for CRISPR might suggest full control as all uncertainty has been eliminated.

Yet, despite the impressiveness of this new technique, many scientists have issued stark warning calls to “think carefully about how we are going to use that power.”Footnote 4 One set of challenges falls into the category of unintended consequences. The “democratization” of gene editing resulting from this new-found accessibility of DNA modification threatens to put the technique into inexperienced hands, with consequences no one can foresee. Similarly, even if proper precautions are taken, there is still the possibility of CRISPR cutting the DNA in places other than those intended by researchers, threatening irreversible changes. Critics of widespread and unregulated CRISPR application refer also to the much discussed issue of matching the break-neck pace of CRISPR applications with ethical and safety standards.Footnote 5 Modifying the genetic code of malaria-carrying mosquitos to eliminate their ability to spread the disease or wiping out invasive species in delicate ecosystems has clear advantages.Footnote 6 At the same time, the conversation about unanticipated effects relates directly to actor experience of uncertainty, especially in uncertain contexts of inadequate regulation. Altering the germline of an organism is an inherently complex matter, necessitating separate oversight efforts for each species – fruit flies differ considerably from mosquitos. However, the everyday uncertainty of translating scientific insights and expertise is quickly overshadowed by considerations of the uncertainty that disrupted ecosystems would produce.

The desire to control something so fickle and expansive is strong. It is interesting to observe the various attempts at control clashing in the arena newly opened up by CRISPR. At first, scientists wanted better control over their laboratory tasks. Subsequently, the need to regulate both the process and outcomes of such activity brought another element of control to the forefront. And all along, the shocking novelty and broad applicability of CRISPR technology has fueled a fierce battle over patent ownership.Footnote 7 This is no minor matter. It affects the particular paths that subsequent developments take, as well as the point of contact at which scientific and regulatory control attempts meet.Footnote 8 The result: disregard for key unknowns and creation of space for newly creative solutions that may bypass this particular manifestation of protean power and replace it with new ones.

The quest for intellectual property rights is a matter of reaping large financial benefits from commercializing the technology at hand. In the language of power, that means gaining competitiveness in pharmaceutical markets and, importantly, financing additional research and innovation. The self-perpetuating model of research investments seems like it might be capable of bypassing the underlying uncertainty. In practice, however, the picture is not nearly so simple. First, once inventions are streamlined and scaled up to generate profit, the focus shifts away from agile creativity in finding resourceful answers to pressing questions toward generating protean power that is converted into control through the identification of material benefits. Exchange represents one move in the reversible relationship between the two power types. Movement in the opposite direction is fueled by the fact that initial impact of an invention in no way guarantees continued or future success. In the case of CRISPR, the interaction is further marked by regulatory uncertainty stemming from battles over patents and the particular policy stance that governments take on the technology.Footnote 9 It introduces pressures from researchers working on still newer methods to match or outperform CRISPR capabilities.

Paradoxically, then, the quest for control has produced additional uncertainty. Fighting for intellectual property rights has underscored the desirability of CRISPR technology and at the same time increased the incentive for others to come up with alternatives. Patent battles will likely result in the development of still newer methods that will bypass this avenue of progress altogether. All obstacles surrounding the adoption of CRISPR gene modification highlight the pervasiveness of uncertainty despite actors’ desire to control what limited aspects of it they can, either through patent adjudication or ethics and safety regulations. In this example, control power and protean power are deeply entangled in competitive relations. The shifts from one power type to the other have typically been shaped by actor experiences of their context and fleeting openings for intervention.

Ambitious Journeys

In frontier science, the fundamental interference with probability calculations arises from the very nature of the questions considered.Footnote 10 Scientists “control” what they can, but readily admit that an unknown set of unknowns may drive the ultimate success or failure of their work. As a result, many innovators make no pretenses about seeking control beyond a very limited point.Footnote 11 In fact, they deliberately open up the playing field for others, realizing that ideas and innovations cannot be forced but, if nudged along a specific path, may follow a semblance of the initial creators’ vision. Studies harnessing the immune system to fight cancer at the National Institutes of Health (NIH) are a case in point. Contrary to the common practice of making research information available only following formal publication, Dr. Steven Rosenberg of the National Cancer Institute, himself a pioneer of immunotherapy for more than three decades, has advocated the sharing of unpublished data to expedite progress.Footnote 12 Given the complexity and fluidity of both cancer and human immunity, there is too much to be learned from early discoveries. The job is simply too big for any one research team to tackle alone. Aware of the urgency of the endeavor and committed to scientific progress over personal profit, Dr. Rosenberg’s leadership acknowledges uncertainty and stops short of seeking to rein it in.Footnote 13

The race to produce human insulin in the late 1970s documents the unanticipated effects that uncertainty can have on the specific pathways scientific discovery takes. The task that would-be innovators faced at the time was to produce human insulin in the laboratory, as opposed to harvesting it from limited livestock pancreases. Several competing companies sought to reap the commercial rewards of reaching the goalpost first, but probabilities of success were incalculable. Scientists had to create a molecule of the insulin protein and find a way to produce it in vast quantities – both extremely high bars to clear. Overwhelming uncertainty and fluidity of actor interrelations shaped the eventual outcome: the race was won neither by major university laboratories nor industrial Goliaths wielding an abundance of conventional resources. Rather, the prize was claimed by Genentech, a start-up David who embraced the unknowns with agility and creative experimentation.Footnote 14 The scientists in this small company set up a laboratory in a converted warehouse. They did not work against dominant actors in the industry as they tried to solve a scientific puzzle, and ended up participating in the birth of bioengineering as a field. In what later proved to be a key move, they did not try to clone the insulin molecule from human DNA but instead assembled it “from scratch.” This decision put them in a position to bypass the exploding regulations requiring high-security laboratories for work combining human DNA with other (bacterial) organisms.Footnote 15 As for conventional resources, Genentech had relatively few and ended up generating protean power by not following predictable paths to either scientific or commercial success.

There is one final but important layer in the recombinant insulin story that quite possibly may characterize all potentially transformative scientific discoveries. In the 1970s, the scientific community deemed the uncertainty surrounding the impact of genetic engineering to be extremely high. It convened a conference of experts in 1975 to set out guidelines and limitations based on past laboratory practices and existing risk perceptions. Recombinant DNA work, however, was so fundamentally different that previous knowledge was not particularly useful for setting expectations. The Asilomar conference, along with a panicked public response, ended up temporarily tying the hands of many scientists.Footnote 16 Effectively, it choked the usefulness of conventional resources and benefited agile actors who did not have them in the first place. Although the rules were later relaxed, the unique mix of unknowns with which actors had to contend marks the late 1970s in both bioengineering and protean power history.

The products of innovation in early laboratory experiments are not driven by control power. It is only once relatively less complex elements of the initial scientific discovery become recognizable and manageable that they attract resources. Innovations in both science and industry have to be clearly visible if they are to be comprehensible to control power and the financial backing accompanying it. This entangles the relations between protean and control power against a background of deepening uncertainty about future success. Ultimately, this uncertainty is relieved only temporarily by impressions of predictability as solitary breakthroughs make news.Footnote 17

Start-ups

At first glance, there is a clear difference between how scientists and start-up developers approach the uncertain context in which they operate. Unlike the deliberately open, bottom-up, and unstructured attitudes surrounding the birth of new companies, strict methodological approaches like experimental design in natural sciences are meant to reduce most unknowns and offer some semblance of control over the world under study. However, scientists are the first to admit that what is observed in a petri dish does not readily translate into living organisms, and what is true in mice need not be true in humans. Conversely, unconventional office layouts and novel management strategies provide a surprisingly well-grounded approach to stimulating creativity and represent much less of a free-for-all world than we might assume. The key quality that these seemingly distinct fields share is the recognition that scientists and entrepreneurs both operate in a world that combines risk with uncertainty. It therefore pays to cover the bases of what is known to work. Yet by nature of the questions asked and objectives pursued, agility and openness to new discoveries, hunches, and even surprises, are needed to overcome constraints imposed by risk calculations.

In their driving quest, start-ups seek to identify opportunities in the realm of the unknown and unknowable. Their greatest hurdles lie in the incalculability of risk in a wide range of products and services that have great potential in national and global markets. All firms operate within the same environment. Working together in close proximity, as in Silicon Valley, these firms can generate important agglomeration externalities that serve the industry extremely well. Individually, however, start-ups seek to respond to some aspect of the uncertainty that their existing competitors and potential customers also experience. Although these ventures vie for market power, none have the illusion, at the outset, of controlling or dramatically transforming national or global markets, although some, like Google, Facebook, Airbnb, Uber, Tesla, or Chobani, eventually do. Neither the innovators nor their investors know whether any pay-offs will follow. Successful start-ups uncover needs that their prospective clients may not even realize exist. Located at the margins of technological innovation, countries like Peru also develop novel digital practices and global connections. These can yield alternative development trajectories that are truly innovative and do not merely replicate technological futures imagined as universal in Silicon Valley and other global centers of innovation.Footnote 18 When tracing the competition of control and protean power among start-ups on a global scale, we do not speak of filling gaps but of creating spaces for riding out the next wave of uncertainty, instead of being swept away by it.

Not attempting even limited control, a number of prominent start-ups deliberately abandon what would otherwise be valued capacities for a partial steering of relevant market segments. When Tesla offered its electric car technology patents for no-fee fair use by those interested in adopting the technology, it did so with the hope (but no guarantee) that everyone would eventually adopt the Tesla platform. The creation of a network of recharging and battery replacement stations is the only viable avenue Tesla has toward reaching big-company status. By giving up control, it effectively expanded the ranks of those working to make gasoline-powered transportation irrelevant. The source of Tesla’s power comes from the knowledge that it will continue to evolve together with other innovators who will participate in this spontaneously emerging network. If successful, the process could have a transformative impact on the operation of the car industry as a whole. Similarly, in the late 1980s Intel chose to put its resources behind building a platform for the chip and personal computer industries rather than pursuing a highly promising new product. Promoting a new standard and thus increasing demand provided Intel with a powerful run throughout the 1990s.Footnote 19

Similar tactics have been pursued by other start-ups. Responding to uncertainty by actively encouraging innovation, regardless of who reaps the direct benefits from new ideas, is at odds with traditional approaches to building market power by carefully guarding copyrights and patents. In other examples, “Apple, Google and Amazon are all racing to build computers we can talk to, that’ll understand us … but they face competition from a surprising place – small entrepreneurs using software they’re getting for free.”Footnote 20 Thousands of individual programmers, on nights and weekends, work together on mastering the transfer of human language to computer applications using Wit.Ai software. There is no single actor that possesses control over how the innovative process unfolds. Yet the work being done is something “that could end up ruling the technology universe.”Footnote 21

Recognizing the prevalence of everyday and radical uncertainty in global markets, start-ups cannot afford to ignore it, nor can they settle for merely chancing upon solutions that a continually stimulating environment may produce as it challenges established power configurations. Rather, as these examples illustrate, start-ups deliberately give up that control to fully embrace the uncertainty they know they cannot and do not wish to avoid. As Taylor Owen argues, the power that distinguishes high-tech and the digital world is formless, unstable, and collaborative.Footnote 22 We call it protean.

Bitcoin: Spinning Gold out of Straw?Footnote 23

Famously, the Grimm Brothers told the story of Rumpelstiltskin, an imp who helped a peasant girl spin straw into gold and could disappear into thin air. Updating this story for the twenty-first century requires only slight adjustments. Straw then is numbers now, crunched by tens of thousands of computers whirring 24/7 in electricity-rich, Icelandic-cold caves all over the world, but increasingly in China. The imp then disappearing into thin air when the girl guesses his name correctly, now is bitcoin’s anonymous Japanese-named creator, Satoshi Nakamoto, who published a paper detailing the bitcoin protocol in November 2008, developed the necessary software in 2009, and took her or his farewell in 2011.Footnote 24

Bitcoin is a cryptocurrency invented to bypass the political and financial centers of power. A prime example of protean power, it came on the scene in 2008–9 at the height of financial uncertainty and with the hope of undermining the state’s and financial sector’s control over currency. In the words of a former advisor on innovation to Secretary of State Hillary Clinton, Alex Ross, bitcoin illustrates a “wider trend towards networked and globalized power structures that tend to undermine the nation-state-based systems to which we have grown accustomed.”Footnote 25 Not so. What we have grown accustomed to is overlooking the protean power potentials that are lodged in the controls that the nation-state-based system has always harbored within itself. This case illustrates the close connections between protean and control power that run like a red thread through all the other cases reported in this book.

The resourceful initiatives of a broad assemblage of innovative actors – nerds, libertarians, and cyber-cosmopolitans – seeking to circumvent the control of financial institutions and financial actors undercuts the notion of the unchallenged control by any one sector or group of actors. Admittedly, the new currency may not have lived up fully to some of the more optimistic, initial expectations of revolutionizing the world of finance. Bitcoin’s underlying blockchain technology, however, has great potential for the creation of distributed, fully transparent ledgers that could revolutionize many practices of those exercising control in the fields of finance, government, and law. Ironically, banks and financial institutions, the primary targets of bitcoin’s mysterious inventor Satoshi Nakamoto and his or her libertarian allies, are beginning to exploit a new technology originally designed to undermine them. The story of bitcoin is one of multi-cornered political struggles, unanticipated effects, and the lack of control.Footnote 26

Bitcoin undercuts notions of money as an instrument of control developed, for example, by Talcott Parsons.Footnote 27 His consensus theory of power built on an analogy between the circulation of money in the economy and power in the polity. Interested in the nature of power more than its effects, Parsons downplayed conflict and imposed on an inchoate political reality a self-perpetuating practice of affirmation in the political legitimacy of established centers of authority. This perspective catches part of money’s power dynamics, but it overlooks both refusal and innovation that mark protean power’s disruption of financial and technological routines.

Instead of Parsons, many early users of bitcoin reflect the views of other theorists. Friedrich Hayek, for example, argued that government should not have a monopoly over the issuance of money.Footnote 28 Instead, there should be a competitive market in which currencies would be traded at variable exchange rates among both public and private actors. And currencies could be of different kinds: traditional gold- or silver-based, novel commodity-based, foreign, or virtual currencies like bitcoin. Currencies able to guarantee stable purchasing power, Hayek argued, would drive inflation-prone currencies out of business. Anticipating bitcoin by decades, Milton Friedman looked not to markets regulated by the Federal Reserve, but to a computer program as the preferred mechanism for increasing the money supply at a constant and well-publicized rate.Footnote 29

Understood as both currency and technology, bitcoin points to the interaction between protean and control power, as Hayek and Parsons argued. And that interaction is reflected in processes and practices of innovation and refusal as well as affirmation. In a world “where innovation expands and complicates choice … local forces are in constant motion.”Footnote 30 The bitcoin world provides a graphic illustration of local forces in motion – with the local here understood to be part of the virtual rather than the geographical world. A twenty-four-year-old bitcoin entrepreneur charged with money laundering and other crimes, Charlie Shrem, has likened Nakamoto to a second Columbus who “gave us the new world.”Footnote 31 One enthusiastic characterization argues that bitcoin is “about freeing people from the tyranny of centralized trust. It speaks to the tantalizing prospect that we can take power away from the center – away from banks, governments, lawyers … and transfer it to the periphery, to We, the People.”Footnote 32 In the words of a young Argentinian woman trading bitcoins, “It feels good, doing things that you are not supposed to, saying to the structures of power they don’t have power over you.”Footnote 33 In the summer of 2014 there existed reportedly 434 bitcoin meet-up groups with close to 50,000 members in 309 cities and 68 countries.Footnote 34

What is Bitcoin?

In broader historical perspective bitcoin is less radical than it may appear at first glance. Territorial money issued and guaranteed by states has been around for only a couple of centuries. Local and now electronic currencies have been central to financial systems for much longer. “Cross-border circulation of currencies was not only accepted but widespread, monetary policy as such did not exist, and private monies were commonplace.”Footnote 35 Even today, for monies and near-monies, the state is “primus inter pares and not the supreme ruler.”Footnote 36

Bitcoin is the most important of hundreds of electronic currencies.Footnote 37 It is an open-source, copyright-free, decentralized, online financial network that is easy to use for sending and receiving payments.Footnote 38 Three significant differences set bitcoin apart from more familiar financial networks such as VISA or PayPal that are owned by profit-seeking corporations. First, bitcoin is neither owned nor managed by anybody. It is a peer-to-peer network of computers that processes bitcoin transactions. Second, in contrast to existing financial networks, bitcoin is completely open. If an actor wishes to create new bitcoin-based financial services, no one’s permission or assistance is required. Finally, in contrast to existing financial networks that rely on conventional currencies such as dollars, this one comes with its own currency. While the value of bitcoin is uncorrelated with the value of the world’s major currencies, thus illustrating the unknowability of outcomes,Footnote 39 the denomination of its value in terms of dollars illustrates the close connection between protean and control power.

Bitcoins are electronic tokens created by miners. Collectively, miners keep a decentralized ledger called the blockchain. It is controlled by no one and creates bitcoins. Miners are rewarded for the cost of their computational labor in bitcoins. In the words of Benjamin Cohen “money can be made by making money.”Footnote 40 What started as individuals operating a few personal computers in their homes has evolved quickly into very large networks of computers, running into the tens of thousands that operate in different locations all over the world. In this manner dispersed, protean power very quickly has mutated into centralized, control power over a vital part of a functioning bitcoin payment system. Expensive chips powering large computer networks are necessary to solve the increasingly difficult mathematical problems that are rewarded by an ever-decreasing number of bitcoins.

Today huge amounts of computing power are needed to mine bitcoins. To receive 25 bitcoins valued at about 6,250 dollars in October 2015, miners must calculate roughly 10 quadrillion (one thousand million million) mathematical equations per second.Footnote 41 The computational and energy-intensive underpinnings of the bitcoin currency exist in tens of thousands of computers stretching from environmentally polluting Mongolia to environmentally green Sweden.Footnote 42 As early as 2013, the computational power behind bitcoin exceeded by a factor of 100 the combined performance of the world’s largest 500 supercomputers.Footnote 43 According to one estimate, by mid-century the computer capacities for solving the mathematical problems that would lead to the issuing of additional bitcoins will approach the size of the universe, operating at the speed of light.Footnote 44 One of the trickiest challenges in the evolution of bitcoin is to structure the incentives for large-scale miners so that they can make adequate profits and thus continue mining. With the dramatic expansion in the scale of mining operations, the dynamics of protean and control power have shifted. By 2016, four Chinese mining pools accounted for over 70 percent of transactions on the bitcoin network, with the vast proportion controlled by only two companies. China had “effectively assumed majority control of the Bitcoin network.”Footnote 45 With the price of bitcoin about doubling in 2016 and quadrupling in 2017, topping $4,000 in August 2017, in the second half of 2016 Renminbi transactions accounted for 98 percent of total global bitcoin trading.Footnote 46

Undergirding bitcoin, the currency, is the bitcoin technology. The bitcoin payment system is a protocol, a series of rules governing the exchange of information among interlinked computers. The protocol is a mathematical construct that cannot be forged. The computer code for the calculations that create bitcoins is open source and gradually evolving. Because any kind of application can be built on top of that protocol, this technology is important, even if bitcoin, the currency, were to fail altogether.Footnote 47

Like alternating currents travelling over the electrical grid, bitcoin’s blockchain is a foundational technological infrastructure. Without a roughly simultaneously emerging demand for its use, infrastructure technologies cannot develop. For the bitcoin payment system to evolve, a large and vigorous market for bitcoin currency is a necessity. The light bulb needed to be invented for the electric grid to become a worthwhile investment. Bitcoin currency in the twenty-first century plays the role of Edison’s light bulb in the nineteenth century. It makes possible the development of a payment system that bypasses billing processors, credit card associations, banks, and clearing-house networks managed by regional Federal Reserve banks. Thus, it may drastically reduce the need for and power of such intermediaries and the fees they charge, putting at risk billions of dollars of sunk costs and tens of thousands of jobs in existing payment systems.Footnote 48

In contrast to traditional payment systems run by private financial institutions or states, bitcoin technology has evolved with great speed. For one, the advantages of bitcoin are hard to deny. Final financial settlement time approaches near-real-time (an hour or less compared with 2–3 days) and at a fraction of current cost, 1 percent or less compared with 2–4 percent or more; international money transfer costs are even higher, varying between 5 and 11 percent.Footnote 49 As an optional form of payment bitcoin is now accepted by firms like IBM, Microsoft, Amazon, Expedia, iTunes, Dell, Bloomberg.com and many start-ups, including Bitpay and Coinbase. The number of American companies accepting bitcoin numbered about 140,000 by the end of 2015.Footnote 50 In the United States currently there exist an estimated 500,000–1 million digital currency accounts.Footnote 51 In 2014, bitcoins were used in daily transactions worth about $50 million (up from $1 million in June 2011), compared with PayPal’s $492 million and VISA’s $19 billion.Footnote 52 ATM machines offering conversion of bitcoins to dollars have started springing up in several North American cities, including a new bitcoin center near Wall Street.

Bitcoin and the Dynamics of Protean and Control Power

An example of protean power and the most pervasive of a large number of private, electronic forms of currencies, bitcoin was introduced in January 2009, followed by about 700 other cryptocurrencies. As in Wagner’s Rheingold, below the world of majestic daily global currency flows, measured in the trillions of dollars, many dwarfs were hammering away to create alternative currencies. Bitcoin saw the light of day when confidence in banking systems and central banks hit a nadir in 2008–9.Footnote 53 The financial crisis offered Nakamoto a fleeting opportunity for action that did not require having any special foreknowledge or concrete plans. At the height of that crisis, the control power of governments, banks, and large corporations over the economy had evaporated. Bitcoin became “a perfect object for the anxieties and enthusiasms of those frightened by the threats of inflation and currency debasement, concerned about state power and the surveillance state, and fascinated with the possibilities created by distributed, decentralized systems.”Footnote 54

Bitcoin was surrounded by plenty of uncertainty itself – about its feasibility, stability, and transparency. Supporters of bitcoin experienced first-hand that “there is no calculus of risk independent of an individual’s affective self-reliance to uncertainty.”Footnote 55 However, bitcoin was attractive apart from the escape it seemed to offer from an all-pervasive disregard of uncertainty. Individuals chose this new technological “infostructure” also because of the hope of reaping the benefits of a relatively egalitarian and open network and of immunity from hierarchical control by state and corporate elites.Footnote 56 What bitcoin supporters were seeking was perfect transparency. Thus, they adhered to a contradictory stance: total distrust in political and economic institutions, specifically governments and banks; total trust in social institutions, specifically networks mediated and facilitated by technology.

Actors such as Goldman Sachs, JP Morgan Chase, and NASDAQ who enjoy enormous control power in the world of finance are less interested in bitcoin the currency than in the blockchain technology on which it rests. UBS, Deutsche Bank, Santander, and BNY Mellon, for example, have teamed up to develop a form of digital cash to clear and settle financial trades.Footnote 57 This technology has the potential to replace middlemen and to make redundant all forms of verification in the transfer and recording of financial assets such as stocks, contracts, crowd-funding, property titles, and patents.Footnote 58 In addition, computational law may emerge as self-executing computer programs that largely reduce, even eliminate, the need for many ordinary legal services as counterparty risks disappear.Footnote 59 A recent report estimates the savings of distributed ledger technology to soon run to between $15 and $20 billion for cross-border payments, securities trading, and regulatory compliance.Footnote 60 About 20 percent of the users of a recent start-up, Chain, are developing non-financial blockchain applications, compared with less than 10 percent a year ago. And growing sums of venture capital are flowing into this market. It remains to be seen whether and how blockchain applications will affect or eliminate trusted intermediaries or entire legal, economic, and social structures that currently guarantee property rights. Apple Pay, a digital wallet, signals that bitcoin technology is beginning to reach mainstream consumers.Footnote 61 And as it does, the recalibration of protean and control power will proceed apace. Venture capitalists investing in this technology try to convert the uncertainty attending their investment decisions into risk by creating self-fulfilling prophecies. Giving speeches, convening workshops, and stressing emergent network effects are deliberate attempts at shaping beliefs about the blockchain technology that undergirds the bitcoin currency.Footnote 62

Most major banks and some large corporations and central banks, including the Federal Reserve and the Bank of England, have in-house teams that are exploring bitcoin’s underlying technology for their operations.Footnote 63 An association of big banks called the Clearing House is trying to develop a network among the big banks that would permit instantaneous transfers between all accounts of all network members, thus eliminating the risk and uncertainties of having billions of dollars in limbo for days while transactions are settled. In contrast to early bitcoin enthusiasts, these banks are interested in very large payments which account for most of the money moving around the world each day.Footnote 64 Harnessing the blockchain for managing transactions in foreign currency markets, for example, with their daily turnover of more than $5 trillion, would increase directly the control power of the financial sector and indirectly that of the state. Innovative applications of the bitcoin protocol to non-financial transactions are potentially far-reaching in fields as different as accounting, music, and law. But for the most part they remain today highly unpredictable.

Bitcoin is thus driven by the interaction of protean and control power as both speculators and investors alike must cope with calculable risk and incalculable uncertainty.Footnote 65 Bitcoin supporters thought they had discovered a sweet technological escape from the doomsday scenarios of a world riddled by uncertainties.Footnote 66 Yet increasingly bitcoin’s underlying technology is driven by the influx of venture capital seeking profitable commercial applications of the blockchain. For now, entrepreneurs can intuit only dimly different applications of the blockchain technology that extend well beyond electronic currencies and payment schemes, such as those for products and services. Despite that unavoidable impediment, in nominal dollars, blockchain technology attracted more than $1 billion in venture capital in 2014 and 2015, dwarfing the funds attracted by the internet at its dawn in 1995, when Newsweek ran an article titled “Why the Internet will Fail.”Footnote 67

Uncertainty and risk incite some actors to circumvent the reach of the state while at the same time inviting regulatory activities by the state. Bitcoin makes it difficult for governments to “follow the money.” It offers avenues for conducting undetectable transfers of funds, possibly for a variety of nefarious purposes.Footnote 68 Entrepreneurs like Pascal Reid, Michael Abner, and Charlie Shrem, for example, have been arrested on charges of facilitating money laundering. Bitcoin enthusiast Andreas Antonopoulas has an optimistic take on government efforts to control bitcoin: “first they ignore you, then they laugh at you, then they fight you, and then you win.”Footnote 69 At the same time, seeking to exercise control, governments are beginning to regulate bitcoin and other electronic currencies in an uncoordinated fashion.Footnote 70 For example, the US Internal Revenue Service (IRS) has classified bitcoin as property and thus assumed some regulatory control. The Chair of the Federal Reserve Board, Janet Yellen, in contrast, has declared that bitcoin is beyond the regulatory reach of the Federal Reserve since it has no ties to any bank. Congressional reactions to bitcoin have been similarly mixed.Footnote 71 Foreign governments have also reacted in different fashions. The German Finance Ministry, for example, has recognized bitcoin as a unit of account. In contrast, in 2013 China’s Central Bank prohibited the processing of transactions in cryptocurrencies and suspended trading on several bitcoin exchanges, thus causing a collapse in the price of bitcoin and shifting Chinese entrepreneurs, unexpectedly, to become the most important miners of bitcoins worldwide. Hong Kong meanwhile is trying to position itself as Asia’s center for bitcoin. Russia has followed the lead of the Chinese government without enjoying a Hong-Kong-style fallback option.Footnote 72

Conclusion

“Money is not some separate force, easily divided from other, more human, concerns. Money is changing now, very fast, but only because we are, too,” writes Adam Davidson.Footnote 73 Like language, bitcoin is a social technology that is spontaneously and rapidly evolving, and delivers outcomes through competition, imitation, and emulation that no one can anticipate. It undercuts the conventional presumption that only state-issued money is “real.” Alternatives to national currencies, typically minuscule, are often local: Ithaca hours and the Berkshare in the United States; Simecs in Italy; Auroracoins in Iceland; QQ in China; M-PESA in Kenya; Tem and Sano in Greece; Peaches, Bees, Wheels, Measures, and Soil in different parts of France; and similar varieties of currencies in Spain are different examples of local currencies that have sprung up, diminished in importance, vanished altogether, or lasted for decades.Footnote 74 In many rich countries alternative currencies, such as airline miles, have become durable complements to national currencies. Under-served by banks, poor markets in Africa have seen the emergence of “mobile-minutes” as alternatives to official currencies. In addition, there exist also supranational, regional currencies such as the Euro. Private electronic currencies such as bitcoin offer a global complement to state-issued currencies.

The collapse and utter failure of bitcoin the currency is possible.Footnote 75 The fact that its inventor, Nakamoto, remains anonymous should make anybody wary of possible insider trading and private information that could mark bitcoin as a gigantic Ponzi scheme that will at some time, somehow, and somewhere explode – unpredictably. Wild gyrations in the dollar value of bitcoin have shown that it is as vulnerable to speculative bubbles, as are other currencies or assets. And these gyrations have been reinforced by serious concerns about repeated incidences of large-scale fraud.Footnote 76 Investors on Wall Street and in Silicon Valley are guessing and betting that under risky and uncertain conditions bitcoin will somehow outgrow its current phase as a speculative investment object, while providing enough demand for further development of the underlying infrastructure technology for related and unrelated purposes. Even if bitcoin the currency were to fail altogether, bitcoin the technology, embodied in its central idea, the blockchain, will persist. Hopes for a dawn of democracy brought about by bitcoin the currency after 2008 have been disappointed. And so are the hopes of advocates of blockchain technology as a force for empowerment of the disempowered.Footnote 77 The empirical record suggests otherwise. For example, sharp disagreements among influential members of the bitcoin network about the currency’s technical protocol, specifically the size of a given block, illustrate the tension between “populists,” who are intent on broadening bitcoin’s commercial potential, and “elitists,” who are committed to posing a radical challenge to existing currencies. And this tension is acquiring an international dimension as it pits American against Chinese firms.Footnote 78 Disappointment and disillusionment hang in the air as hacking and even death threats are dividing what a few years earlier had been a tight community.Footnote 79 In short, the fight over the future of the blockchain technology illustrates how the co-evolution of currency and technology is shaped by the variable relation between protean and control power.

At the end of the Grimm Brothers’ tale, in a fit of total fury, the imp splits himself in half while the peasant-girl-turned-queen and her king live happily ever after. One recent, unconventional application of the blockchain was in fact made in the marriage market. Diamonds, it turns out, are not forever – blockchains are. At least that is what David Mondrus and Joyce Bayo decided when they became the first couple to use a bitcoin automated teller machine to record their written vows in front of fifty guests.Footnote 80 In the future, on the way to the altar, taxis may be both self-driving and self-owned – by bitcoin blockchains. Traditional wedding planners, and for that matter, all planners, take note!

Conclusion

The blending of control and protean power produces interesting outcomes in areas characterized by a consensus about procedures needed to minimize risk, while the majority of actors recognize that uncertainty, and therefore the futility of risk calculations, remains the overwhelming norm. The Cancer Moonshot and the efforts to pull off a “Mars-shot” illustrate a different blending of the control power tools that scientists wield and the agility and improvisation that they need. The research teams behind the CRISPR gene-editing technique resorted to extracting what limited control patent ownership might provide. Cancer and space-flight scientists use probability-based calculations sparingly and open their minds to fundamental unknowns. And start-ups do not set out to control the surrounding context at all. The knowledge frontier thus illustrates a range of responses that contradict the notion of effective control power. Seeking to challenge established patterns of (control) power, innovators are agile as they seek to harness potentialities that might help them to take the next step.

Rather than showing that control power has limitations, the bitcoin story is one of fighting fire with fire. The emergence of bitcoin, following the financial crisis of 2007–8, leveraged profound uncertainty about the future of global finance, further complicated by the intricate architecture of interdependent financial systems. Support of the blockchain technology came first from individuals seeking to bypass an irremediably crisis- and inflation-prone financial system and later from corporate actors who instead sought to increase its efficiency. Thus, the creation of an alternative and highly volatile currency was intended to undermine failing financial structures and practices, illustrating the limits to a world of exclusive risk calculations. At the same time, central banks and financial institutions quickly realized the potential of the underlying blockchain technology for future growth and profits.

This study of power in areas that, more than most, hinge on improvisation and innovation reveals that uncertainty affects power dynamics both by the nature of the questions asked and the degree to which actors appear satisfied with the answers they receive. The experience of uncertainty is associated with unexpected threats as much as the promise of novelty and improvement. Both stir human creativity. Accidental discovery, for example, unites the possibilities of a disciplined approach to science while allowing the possibility of interpretation and creative connections that determine its ultimate success. From a different angle, the bitcoin case shows creativity in two important ways. The mathematics undergirding bitcoin the currency was genuinely innovative. It was sprung on the world at a moment of great uncertainty at the height of a global financial crisis. Furthermore, the creativity shown by venture capitalists and bankers seeking to exploit and adapt bitcoin technology was impressively improvisational. It is impossible to know at the outset where such disruptive but generative efforts end up, yet acknowledging uncertainty throughout the process of invention alters the range of the actualization of power potentialities in important ways. We may still be far from finding a cure for cancer, a landing on Mars, or finding a reliable buffer against financial crises, but we can be sure that seeking opportunities in uncertainty mixes elements of protean and control power.

Footnotes

3 Protean Power and Revolutions in Rights

1 All social orders define and distribute entitlements, but these are not always defined in terms of rights and are not always allocated to individuals.

3 Krasner Reference Krasner1999: 72.

5 Footnote Ibid.: 18, 20.

6 The Guardian, August 11, 2015.

7 Adler-Nissen and Pouliot Reference Adler-Nissen and Pouliot2014.

9 Koskenniemi Reference Koskenniemi2005: 590–96.

10 Brooks and Wohlforth Reference Brooks and Wohlforth2008: 206.

11 On the challenges a unipole faces defining the terms of its own legitimacy, see Finnemore Reference Finnemore2009.

12 Reus-Smit Reference Reus-Smit2013: 37.

13 Reus-Smit Reference Reus-Smit1999: 13.

14 Adler and Pouliot Reference Adler and Pouliot2011: 42.

15 Heller Reference Heller1987: 239.

16 Alter and Meunier Reference Alter and Meunier2009; United Nations 2006; Young Reference Young2012.

18 Burke Reference Burke1908: 89.

19 Suchman Reference Suchman1995: 574.

20 Keene Reference Keene2002: 6.

22 Quoted in Reus-Smit Reference Reus-Smit2013: 156.

23 Quoted in Footnote ibid.: 154.

24 Footnote Ibid.: 41–42.

25 The classic works on this are Gong Reference Gong1984 and Adas Reference Adas1989.

27 United Nations 1949: 533.

28 Reus-Smit Reference Reus-Smit2013: 182–87.

29 United Nations 1951: 485.

30 United Nations 1952: preamble.

31 Reus-Smit Reference Reus-Smit2013: 165–71.

4 Protean Power in Movement: Navigating Uncertainty in the LGBT Rights Revolution

1 I thank Peter Katzenstein, Lucia Seybert, Steffano Guzzini, Aida Hozic, Jeffrey Isaac, Stephen Krasner, and Daniel Nexon for their incisive comments on earlier drafts; the remaining shortcomings are my own. The research for this chapter was supported by the Postsecular Conflicts Project, European Research Council Grant STG-2015-676804.

2 LGBT is an umbrella term referring to lesbian, gay, bisexual, and trans people. I use the umbrella term while acknowledging that the issues of bisexual and trans people have been excluded throughout much of the history of the gay and lesbian rights movement.

5 Anti-sodomy legislation was the early homosexual movement’s central battle. Beginning in 1868, leading up to German unification, Ulrichs spoke out against Prussia’s anti-sodomy legislation in fear that it would proliferate throughout unified Germany (via Prussia’s paragraph 175). Catholic Bavaria, for example, had already decriminalized sodomy following the French Revolution. Despite many near successes (both by Ulrichs and later by Hirschfeld and others), paragraph 175 did become the law of the land in 1871 and was intensified in 1935.

6 From Uranus, Greek god of the heavens. Beachy Reference Beachy2014.

13 See Kymlicka and Opalski Reference Kymlicka and Opalski2002 on minority rights in post-communist Europe generally.

15 European Values Study 1981–2008, 2011.

16 BBC News 2015.

23 Symons and Altman Reference Symons and Altman2015.

24 Ssebuyira and Kasasira Reference Ssebuyira and Kasasira2014.

25 Ayoub Reference Ayoub2015: 306. EU conditionality refers to the rules with which prospective member states must comply. A statistical analysis shows how this dynamic plays out. In new EU member states (2004 and 2007 waves), both the application for membership and actual accession to the EU did not have a significant effect on the introduction of higher levels of LGBT rights.

26 Confer findings for transnationally embedded LGBT organizations in Ayoub Reference Ayoub2015: 306.

28 In the diffusion model, commands are obeyed and disseminated because of an impetus from their original source, overlooking the translation work that actors on the ground depend on. Indeed, one problem with the concept of diffusion is the image of particles moving into empty spaces. Conceptualizing the translation process inherent to protean power acknowledges that such empty spaces do not exist in world politics. In the translation model, activists are attuned to the realities that remain invisible to actors wielding control power from the top.

29 Ayoub and Chetaille Reference Ayoub and Chetaille2018.

33 Ayoub Reference Ayoub2014. While I focus on Poland in this example, scholars have charted similar counter-movement frames of “threat to nation” across new adopter states in Europe. Swimelar Reference Swimelar, Slootmaeckers, Touquet and Vermeersch2016; Mole Reference Mole, Slootmaeckers, Touquet and Vermeersch2016.

34 Ayoub and Chetaille Reference Ayoub and Chetaille2018.

35 See at: www.znakpokoju.com.

36 Similarly, local Ugandan and Russian LGBT activists opposed the well-intended external activist calls for boycotts (of Western aid to Uganda, and calls for participation boycotts to Russia’s Sochi Olympics) in response to state homophobia.

37 Insights for Table 4.1 are derived from Ayoub and Chetaille’s Reference Ayoub and Chetaille2018 process-tracing work on the Polish movement’s framing strategies.

43 The same can be said of the constant movement across cells in the related Figure 1.1 in Chapter 1, p. 13, above.

44 Ayres and Eskridge Reference Ayres and Eskridge2014.

46 While this chapter focused on the protean power of human rights promoters, it addressed a multitude of different types of actors (for and against LGBT rights) practicing advocacy in different ways depending on their experience of the world as risky or uncertain. In fact, one set of actors that occasionally heightened operational uncertainty for activists on the ground were the well-intended international organizations and INGO allies that tried to advance the norm at the international level.

48 Currier Reference Currier2012. Paradoxically, colonial Britain introduced anti-sodomy laws to Africa.

5 Border Collision: Power Dynamics of Enforcement and Evasion across the US–Mexico Line

1 All names are pseudonyms. All quotes are reconstructed from shorthand taken during interviews. We return to Maria’s story later in the narrative.

2 Interview, El Salvador, December 22, 2009.

16 This section draws on Andreas Reference Andreas2013.

17 Ettinger Reference Ettinger2009: 99.

18 Quoted in Footnote ibid.: 100.

19 Quoted in Lee Reference Lee2003: 159.

20 Quoted in Reynolds Reference Reynolds1909: 368.

21 Quoted in Ettinger Reference Ettinger2009: 60.

22 Lee Reference Lee2003: 57–58.

23 Ettinger Reference Ettinger2009: 105.

24 Quoted in Siener Reference Siener2008: 60.

25 Quoted in McCullough Reference McCullough1992: 51–52.

26 Quoted in Footnote ibid.: 6.

27 Footnote Ibid.: 230–31.

28 Quoted in Ettinger Reference Ettinger2009: 162.

29 Andreas Reference Andreas2013: 415.

30 Andreas Reference Andreas2013: 301.

31 Quoted in Andreas Reference Andreas2013: 305.

34 Bouchard and Carroll Reference Bouchard and Carroll2002; Salter Reference Salter2008: 370.

36 Interview, El Salvador, September 2, 2010, also quoted in Brigden Reference Brigden2016.

37 Quoted in Brigden Reference Brigden2016.

38 On the role of discretion in the performance of Canadian state sovereignty, see Salter Reference Salter2008: 368–70.

40 Interview, El Salvador, January 24, 2010.

42 Dominguez Villegas and Rietig Reference Dominguez Villegas and Rietig2015; Lohmuller Reference Lockwood2015.

43 For an in-depth discussion of these moments of immobility during mobility during migrant journeys, see Brigden and Mainwaring Reference Brigden and Mainwaring2016.

44 Interview, Mexico, March 12, 2010.

45 Interviews, El Salvador, November 11, 2009 and January 14, 2010.

46 The nephew began the journey again as soon as he returned, and he arrived safely in the United States on his second try.

48 Interview, Mexico, April 11, 2010.

51 Brigden and Mainwaring Reference Brigden and Mainwaring2016.

52 Carr 2015.

54 Albahari Reference Albahari2015; Carling 2007; IOM 2014.

55 Schmidt and Chan Reference Schmidt and Chan2016.

6 High-Tech: Power and Unpredictability at the Technological Frontier and in Bitcoin

1 LS would like to thank David J. Chen, Isaac Kriley, Winnie Lo, and Eric Tran for illuminating conversations about uncertainty in medical science. PK would like to thank Benjamin Cohen, Eric Helleiner, and Jonathan Kirshner for critical comments on the second half of an earlier draft of this chapter.

8 For a related account about innovation in the context of power over information flows, see Marlin-Bennet Reference Marlin-Bennet2017.

10 As if the complexity of the questions considered was not enough, researchers face the uncertainty of continued existence of their laboratories. First, there exists a lag between the demonstrability of scientific principle and its commercialization, testing the patience of funding sources. Second, as the CRISPR episode illustrated, regulatory obstacles can have an impact on the survival of research programs themselves.

11 In the context of medical science such an attitude is particularly closely linked to clinical trials of new treatments and techniques. Chadi Reference Chadi2017.

12 Rosenberg and Barry Reference Rosenberg and Barry1992: 151–52.

17 Rosenberg and Barry Reference Rosenberg and Barry1992: 233.

19 Yoffie and Cusumano Reference Yoffie and Cusumano2015: 90–130.

22 Owen Reference Owen2015: 37–47.

23 The distinction between Bitcoin the technology, and bitcoin the currency, is sometimes marked in text by capitalizing the former, not the latter. For reasons of convenience and consistency, and because the context makes the difference between the two normally clear, we will refer to bitcoin in lowercase throughout

25 Owen Reference Owen2015: 71.

26 McKeen-Edwards and Porter Reference McKeen-Edwards and Porter2013: 24–26.

27 Parsons Reference Parsons1963. See also Barnes Reference Barnes1988, 12–20; Giddens Reference Giddens1977: 333–49; Kindleberger Reference Kindleberger1970: 3–16.

28 Cohen Reference Cohen2001; Hayek Reference Hayek1976; Rogojanu and Badea Reference Rogojanu and Badea2014: 104–5.

29 In contrast to Friedman’s proposal, bitcoin has a fixed supply of 21 million coins. In an era struggling with deflation rather than inflation, bitcoin’s deflationary bias is even more severe than the gold standard and may eventually become an insurmountable problem. Needless to say, bitcoin or other electronic currencies will have to find a way to circumvent this deflationary bias in some form without losing the transparency that the blockchain offers.

30 Shubik Reference Shubik2014: 11.

32 Vigna and Casey Reference Vigna and Casey2015: 8.

33 Popper Reference Popper2015d: 53.

35 Cohen Reference Cohen2001: 207. See also Helleiner Reference Helleiner2003: 42–79; Middlebrook and Hughes Reference Middlebrook and Hughes2015.

36 Shubik Reference Shubik2014: 3.

39 Wu and Pandey Reference Wu and Pandey2014: 48.

40 Cohen Reference Cohen2001: 201.

41 Kelly Reference Kelly2015: 84. Kelly Reference Kelly2015: 16 reports a figure of 50 quadrillion per second.

42 The Economist 2015a.

43 The Economist 2013. In the first five years of its existence, the computing power behind bitcoin reportedly consumed 150,000 megawatt-hours of electricity, enough to keep the Eiffel Tower lit for two and a half centuries (Clenfield and Alpeyev Reference Clenfield and Alpeyev2014).

44 Castronova Reference Castronova2014: 162–63.

46 Wildau Reference Wildau2017. Although it is by no means clear that the high correlation between the surge in the value of bitcoin and the weakening of the Chinese currency and capital outflows are causally linked, China’s two largest bitcoin exchanges stopped withdrawals of the electronic currency in February 2017, after a warning by the central bank about the necessity of enforcing rules on foreign exchange transactions and money laundering.

47 Hochstein Reference Hochstein2014: 20.

49 Hochstein Reference Hochstein2014: 20; Kalmadi and Dang Reference Kalmadi and Dang2015; Shubik Reference Shubik2014: 10.

52 Bitcoin can process only seven transactions per second, compared with tens of thousands for VISA. The average bitcoin transaction is about $500 compared with $80 for VISA. See Böhme et al. Reference Böhme, Christin, Edelman and Moore2015: 214; Velde Reference Velde2013.

54 Surowiecki Reference Surowiecki2011: 106.

55 Massumi Reference Massumi2015: 4.

56 Cohen Reference Cohen2001: 205; Hochstein Reference Hochstein2014: 21.

58 The Economist 2015a.

59 Hochstein Reference Hochstein2014: 23.

61 Castranova and Fairfield Reference Castronova and Fairfield2014.

62 With one-third of their investments failing, these rhetorical strategies are only partly successful. Susan Athey interview, April 14, 2015, Ithaca, NY.

66 Griffin Reference Griffin2014: 33.

70 Raymaekers Reference Raymaekers2015: 36.

71 The Economist 2013; Griffin Reference Griffin2014: 33.

72 The IMF seems ill-equipped to regulate electronic currencies like bitcoin. See Plassaras Reference Plassaras2013.

73 Davidson Reference Davidson2015b: 46.

74 Cohen Reference Cohen2001: 210; Rogojanu and Badea Reference Rogojanu and Badea2014: 105–7; Shubik Reference Shubik2014: 3–4.

77 Tapscott Reference Tapscott2016: 22–25, 86, 227.

Figure 0

Table 4.1 Innovative Framing by the Polish movement, 1990–2010

Source: Adapted from Ayoub and Chetaille 2018.

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×