Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-7d8f8d645b-p72pn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2023-05-28T17:32:14.969Z Has data issue: false Feature Flags: { "useRatesEcommerce": true } hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 August 2018

Eric Alston
Affiliation:
University of Colorado Boulder
Lee J. Alston
Affiliation:
Indiana University
Bernardo Mueller
Affiliation:
University of Brasilia
Tomas Nonnenmacher
Affiliation:
Allegheny College, Pennsylvania
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Institutional and Organizational Analysis
Concepts and Applications
, pp. 353 - 384
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2018

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abdal-Haqq, Irshad. 2002. “Islamic Law: An Overview of Its Origin and Elements.” Journal of Islamic Law and Culture 7(1): 2782.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron. 2003. “Why Not a Political Coase Theorem? Social Conflict, Commitment, and Politics.” Journal of Comparative Economics 31(4): 620–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron and Robinson, James A.. 2006. Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron and Robinson, James A. 2012. Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty. New York, NY: Crown Business.Google Scholar
Ahmed, Dawood I. and Ginsburg, Tom. 2014. “Constitutional Islamization and Human Rights: The Surprising Origin and Spread of Islamic Supremacy in Constitutions.” Virginia Journal of International Law 54(3): 616–95.Google Scholar
Akerlof, George A. 1970. “The Market for ‘Lemons’: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 84(3): 488500.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alchian, Armen A. 1965. “Some Economics of Property Rights.” Il Politico 30: 816–29.Google Scholar
Alchian, Armen A. 1977. Economic Forces at Work. Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Press.Google Scholar
Alchian, Armen A. and Demsetz, Harold. 1972. “Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization.” American Economic Review 62(5): 777–95.Google Scholar
Alesina, Alberto and Giuliano, Paola. 2015. “Culture and Institutions.” Journal of Economic Literature 53(4): 898944.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, Douglas W. 1991. “What Are Transaction Costs?Research in Law and Economics 14: 118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, Douglas W. 1998. “Property Rights, Transaction Costs and Coase: One More Time.” In Coasean Economics: Law and Economics and the New Institutional Economics, edited by Medema, Steven G., 105–18. Boston, MA: Kluwer.Google Scholar
Allen, Douglas W. 2000. “Transaction Costs.” In Encyclopedia of Law and Economics, edited by Bouckaert, Boudewijn and Geest, Gerrit De, 893926. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Allen, Douglas W. 2006. “Theoretical Difficulties with Transaction Cost Measurement.” Division of Labour and Transaction Costs 2(1): 114.Google Scholar
Allen, Douglas W. 2014. “The Coase Theorem: Coherent, Logical, and Not Disproved.” Journal of Institutional Economics 11(2): 112.Google Scholar
Allen, Douglas W. and Lueck, Dean. 2003. The Nature of the Farm: Contracts, Risk, and Organization in Agriculture. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Almendares, Nicholas and Le Bihan., Patrick 2015. “Increasing Leverage: Judicial Review as a Democracy-Enhancing Institution.” Quarterly Journal of Political Science 10: 357–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, Eric. 2018. “Ecuador’s 2008 Constitution: The Political Economy of Securing an Aspirational Social Contract.” Constitutional Studies 3 (June).Google Scholar
Alston, Lee J., Eggertson, Thráinn, and North, Douglass C., eds. 1996. Empirical Studies in Institutional Change. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, Lee J. and Ferrie, Joseph P.. 1993. “Paternalism in Agricultural Labor Contracts in the U.S. South: Implications for the Growth of the Welfare State.” American Economic Review 83(4): 852–76.Google Scholar
Alston, Lee J. and Ferrie, Joseph P. 1999. Southern Paternalism and the American Welfare State: Economics, Politics, and Institutions in the South, 1865–1965. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, Lee J. and Gallo, Andres A.. 2010. “Electoral Fraud, the Rise of Peron and Demise of Checks and Balances in Argentina.” Explorations in Economic History 47(2): 179–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, Lee J. and Gillespie, William. 1989. “Resource Coordination and Transaction Costs: A Framework for Analyzing the Firm/Market Boundary.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 11(2): 191212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, Lee J., Harris, Edwyna, and Mueller, Bernardo. 2012. “The Development of Property Rights on Frontiers: Endowments, Norms, and Politics.” Journal of Economic History 72(3): 741–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, Lee J. and Higgs, Robert. 1982. “Contractual Mix in Southern Agriculture since the Civil War: Facts, Hypotheses, and Tests.” Journal of Economic History 42(2): 327–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, Lee J., Libecap, Gary D., and Mueller, Bernardo. 1999a. “A Model of Rural Conflict: Violence and Land Reform Policy in Brazil.” Environment and Development Economics 4: 135–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, Lee J., Libecap, Gary D., and Mueller, Bernardo 1999b. Titles, Conflict, and Land Use: The Development of Property Rights and Land Reform on the Brazilian Amazon Frontier. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, Lee J., Libecap, Gary D., and Mueller, Bernardo 2000. “Land Reform Policies, the Sources of Violent Conflict, and Implications for Deforestation in the Brazilian Amazon.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 39(2): 162–88.Google Scholar
Alston, Lee J., Libecap, Gary D., and Mueller, Bernardo 2010. “Interest Groups, Information Manipulation in the Media, and Public Policy: The Case of the Landless Peasants Movement in Brazil.” NBER Working Paper No. 15865, www.nber.org/papers/w15865.
Alston, Lee J., Mattiace, Shannan, and Nonnenmacher, Tomas. 2009. “Coercion, Culture, and Contracts: Labor and Debt on Henequen Haciendas in Yucatán, Mexico, 1870–1915.” The Journal of Economic History 69(1): 104–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, Lee J., Melo, Marcus André, Mueller, Bernardo, and Pereira, Carlos. 2006. “Political Institutions, Policymaking Processes and Policy Outcomes in Brazil.” Latin American Research Network Working Paper R–509. Washington, DC: Research Division, Inter-American Development Bank.
Alston, Lee J., Melo, Marcus André, Mueller, Bernardo, and Pereira, Carlos 2016. Brazil in Transition: Beliefs, Leadership, and Institutional Change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Alston, Lee J. and Mueller, Bernardo. 2006. “Pork for Policy: Executive and Legislative Exchange in Brazil.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 22(1): 87114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alt, James E. and Lassen, David D.. 2008. “Political and Judicial Checks on Corruption: Evidence from American State Governments.” Economics and Politics 20(1): 3361.Google Scholar
Amar, Akhil Reed. 1989. “Marbury, Section 13, and the Original Jurisdiction of the Supreme Court.” University of Chicago Law Review 56(2): 443–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ames, B. 1995. “Electoral Rules, Constituency Pressures, and Pork Barrel: Bases of Voting in the Brazilian Congress.” The Journal of Politics 57(2): 324–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ames, B. 2001. The Deadlock of Democracy in Brazil. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, Erin and Schmittlein, David C.. 1984. “Integration of the Sales Force: An Empirical Examination.” The Rand Journal of Economics 15(3): 385–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, Terry L. and Hill, Peter J.. 1975. “The Evolution of Property Rights: A Study of the American West.” Journal of Law and Economics 18(1): 163–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, Terry L. and Hill, Peter J. 2004. The Not So Wild, Wild West: Property Rights on the Frontier. Redwood City, CA: Stanford University Press.Google ScholarPubMed
Aoki, Masahiko, Binmore, Kenneth, Deakin, Simon, and Gintis, Herbert, eds. 2012. Complexity and Institutions: Markets, Norms and Corporations. London: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Argersinger, Peter H. 1980. “‘A Place on the Ballot’: Fusion Politics and Antifusion Laws.” The American Historical Review 85(2) (April): 287306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Argersinger, Peter H. 1991. Structure, Process, and Party. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1951. Social Choice and Individual Values. New York, NY: Wiley.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1963. Social Choice and Individual Values. 2nd edn. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1968. “The Economics of Moral Hazard: Further Comment.” American Economic Review 58(3): 537–39.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1985. “The Economics of Agency.” In Principals and Agents: The Structure of Business, edited by Pratt, John W. and Zeckhauser, Richard J., 3751. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Arruñada, Benito. 2012. “Property as an Economic Concept: Reconciling Legal and Economic Conceptions of Property Rights in a Coasean Framework.” International Review of Economics 59(2): 121–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arruñada, Benito, and Andonova, Veneta. 2005. “Market Institutions and Judicial Rulemaking.” In Handbook of New Institutional Economics, edited by Ménard, Claude and Shirley, Mary, 229–50. New York, NY: Springer.Google Scholar
Austen-Smith, D. and Riker, William H.. 1987. “Asymmetric Information and the Coherence of Legislation.” American Political Science Review 81(3): 897918.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Backhouse, Roger E. and Medema, Steven G.. 2009. “Retrospectives: On the Definition of Economics.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 23(1): 221–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baker, George P., Gibbons, Robert, and Murphy, Kevin J.. 2008. “Strategic Alliances: Bridges between ‘Islands of Conscious Power.’” Journal of the Japanese and International Economies 22(2): 146–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banks, Jeffrey S. 1991. Signaling Games in Political Science. Chur, Switzerland: Harwood Academic Publishers.Google Scholar
Barbera, S. and Jackson, M. O.. 2004. “Choosing How to Choose: Self-Stable Majority Rules and Constitutions.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 119(3): 1011–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, David P. 1989. “Service-Induced Campaign Contributions and the Electoral Equilibrium.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 104(1): 4572.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, David P. 1994. “Electoral Competition with Informed and Uninformed Voters.” American Political Science Review 88(1): 3347.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, David P. 2002. “Review of Grossman and Helpman’s Special Interest Politics.” Journal of Economic Literature 40 (December): 1221–29.Google Scholar
Baron, David P. 2005. “Competing for the Public through the News Media.” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 14(2): 339–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barzel, Yoram. 1989. Economic Analysis of Property Rights. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Barzel, Yoram 1997. Economic Analysis of Property Rights. 2nd edn. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baum, Lawrence. 2009. Judges and Their Audiences: A Perspective on Judicial Behavior. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumgartner, F. R., Jones, B. D., and Mortensen, P. B.. 2014. “Punctuated Equilibrium Theory: Explaining Stability and Change in Public Policy Making.” In Theories of the Policy Process, edited by Sabatier, P. A. and Weible, C. M., 59104. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1983. “A Theory of Competition among Pressure Groups for Political Influence.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 98(3): 371400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Marc. 2011. “Correa, Indigenous Movements, and the Writing of a New Constitution in Ecuador.” Latin American Perspectives 38(1): 4762.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Marc 2013. “The Stormy Relations between Rafael Correa and Social Movements in Ecuador.” Latin American Perspectives 40(3): 4362.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bentley, Arthur F. 1908. The Process of Government. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Bernheim, B. Douglas and Whinston, Michael D.. 1986. “Common Agency.” Econometrica 54(4): 923–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernstein, Lisa. 1992. “Opting Out of the Legal System: Extralegal Contractual Relations in the Diamond Industry.” Journal of Legal Studies 21(1): 115–57.Google Scholar
Bernstein, Lisa 2015. “Beyond Relational Contracts: Social Capital and Network Governance in Procurement Contracts.” Journal of Legal Analysis 7(2): 561621.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bertrand, Elodie. 2006. “The Coasean Analysis of Lighthouse Financing: Myths and Realities.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 30(3): 389402.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, Timothy and Burgess, Robin. 2001. “Political Agency, Government Responsiveness and the Role of the Media.” European Economic Review 45(4–6): 629–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, Timothy, Burgess, Robin, and Prat, Andrea. 2002. “Mass Media and Political Accountability.” In The Right to Tell: The Role of Mass Media in Economic Development, edited by Islam, Roumeen, 4560. Washington, DC: World Bank Institute.Google Scholar
Bettencourt, Luis M. A. 2013. “The Origins of Scaling in Cities.” Science 340: 1438–41.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bird, R. M. 1992. Tax Policy and Economic Development. Baltimore, MD: John Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Black, D. 1958. The Theory of Committees and Elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bolt, J. and van Zanden, J. L.. 2014. “The Maddison Project: Collaborative Research on Historical National Accounts.” The Economic History Review 67(3): 627–51.Google Scholar
Borjas, George J. 1978. “Discrimination in HEW: Is the Doctor Sick or Are the Patients Healthy?Journal of Law and Economics 21(1): 97110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Botero, Juan C. and Ponce, Alejandro. 2010. “Measuring the Rule of Law.” The World Justice Project – Working Paper Series WPS No. 001, Washington, DC.
Boudreaux, Donald J. 2014. “Liberty Matters: Deirdre McCloskey and Economists’ Ideas about Ideas.” Liberty Fund. http://oll.libertyfund.org/titles/2628.
Bowen, James D. 2010. “Ecuador’s 2009 Presidential and Legislative Elections.” Electoral Studies 29(1): 186–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bresnahan, Timothy and Levin, Jonathan. 2013. “Vertical Integration and Market Structure.” In The Handbook of Organizational Economics, edited by Gibbons, Robert and Roberts, John, 853–90. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Broadberry, Stephen and Wallis, John Joseph. 2016. “Growing, Shrinking and Long Run Economic Performance: Historical Perspectives on Economic Development.” Working Paper.
Brousseau, Eric and Glachant, Jean-Michel, eds. 2002. The Economics of Contracts: Theories and Applications. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brousseau, Eric and Glachant, Jean-Michel eds. 2008. New Institutional Economics: A Guidebook. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M. 1985. “The Moral Dimension of Debt Financing.” Economic Inquiry 23 (January): 16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M. and Tullock, Gordon. 1962. The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calabresi, Guido. 1965. “The Decision for Accidents: An Approach to Nonfault Allocation of Costs.” Harvard Law Review 78(4): 713–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caldeira, Gregory A., and Wright, John R.. 1998. “Lobbying for Justice: Organized Interests, Supreme Court Nominations, and the United States Senate.” American Journal of Political Science 42(2): 499523.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Canes-Wrone, B. 2003. “Bureaucratic Decisions and the Composition of the Lower Courts.” American Journal of Political Science 47(2): 205–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cappelletti, Mauro. 1989. The Judicial Process in Comparative Perspective. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Carugati, Federica. 2018. “Constitution and Consensus: The Institutional Foundations of Democratic Stability.” Working Paper, Ostrom Workshop, Indiana University.
Center for Constitutional Transitions. 2013. “Justice Albie Sachs Discusses His Role ‘Judging the Judges after Transition’ in Kenya.” April 16. http://constitutionaltransitions.org/albie-sachs-summary/.
Cheibub, J. A. 2006. Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, and Democracy. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cheibub, J. A., Elkins, Z., and Ginsburg, T.. 2013. “Beyond Presidentialism and Parliamentarism.” British Journal of Political Science 44(3): 515–44.Google Scholar
Cheung, Steven. 1983. “The Contractual Nature of the Firm.” Journal of Law and Economics 26(1): 121.Google Scholar
Cheung, Steven 1989. “Economic Organization and Transaction Costs.” In Allocation, Information and Markets, edited by Eatwell, John, Milgate, Murray, and Newman, Peter, 7782. London: MacMillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Choi, Stephen J., Mitu Gulati, G., and Posner, Eric A.. 2010. “Professionals or Politicians: The Uncertain Empirical Case for an Elected rather than Appointed Judiciary.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 26(2): 290336.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, Tom S. 2011. “The Public and Judicial Independence.” In The Politics of Judicial Independence, edited by Peabody, Bruce, 123–46. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1937. “The Nature of the Firm.” Economica 4: 386405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1960. “The Problem of Social Cost.” Journal of Law and Economics 3 (October): 144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1974. “The Lighthouse in Economics.” Journal of Law and Economics 17(24): 357–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1988. The Firm, the Market, and the Law. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1992. “The Institutional Structure of Production.” American Economic Review 82(4): 713–19.Google Scholar
Coate, Stephen and Morris, Stephen. 1995. “On the Form of Transfers to Special Interest.” Journal of Political Economy 106(6): 1210–35.Google Scholar
Comparative Constitutions Project. 2016. http://comparativeconstitutionsproject.org/.
Constitution of Kenya Review Commission. 2005. “The Final Report of the Constitution of Kenya Review Commission.” Nairobi: Government Printer.
Constitution of the Republic of Kenya, 1963 (as amended to 2008), art. 61, par. 2.
Cooter, Robert D. and Ulen, Thomas. 2011. Law and Economics. 6th edn. Boston, MA: Addison Wesley.Google Scholar
Costello, George. 2005. “The Supreme Court’s Overruling of Constitutional Precedent: An Overview.” Congressional Research Service Report for Congress.
Cox, Gary W. 1997. Making Votes Count: Strategic Coordination in the World’s Electoral Systems. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Gary W. and McCubbins, Matthew D.. 2000. “The Institutional Determinants of Economic Policy Outcomes.” In Presidents, Parliaments, and Policy, edited by Haggard, Stephan and McCubbins, Mathew, 2163. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary W. and McCubbins, Matthew D. 2005. Setting the Agenda: Responsible Party Government in the U.S. House of Representatives. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Gary W. and McCubbins, Matthew D. 2007. Legislative Leviathan: Party Government in the House. 2nd edn. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crawford, Sue E. S. and Ostrom, Elinor. 1995. “A Grammar of Institutions.” American Political Science Review 89(3): 582600.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cross, H. L. 1953. The People’s Right to Know: Legal Access to Public Records and Proceedings. New York, NY: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Crouch, Melissa and Lindsey, Tim, eds. 2014. Law, Society and Transition in Myanmar. London: Bloomsbury Publishing.Google Scholar
CRP (Center for Responsive Politics). 2015. “Money in Marijuana.” November. www.opensecrets.org/news/issues/marijuana/.
Culp, Peter W., Glennon, Robert Jerome, and Libecap, Gary. 2014. Shopping for Water: How the Market Can Mitigate Water Shortages in the American West. Washington, DC: Island Press.Google Scholar
Dahlman, Carl J. 1979. “The Problem of Externality.” Journal of Law and Economics 22(1): 141–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Daly, Yvonne M. 2011. “Judicial Oversight of Policing: Investigations, Evidence and the Exclusionary Rule.” Crime, Law and Social Change 55(2): 199215.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Danziger, Shai, Levav, Jonathan, and Liora, Avnaim-Pesso. 2011. “Extraneous Factors in Judicial Decisions.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 108(17): 6889–92.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Della Paolera, Gerardo and Taylor, Alan M.. 1998. “Finance and Development in an Emerging Market: Argentina in the Interwar Period.” In Latin America and the World Economy since 1800, edited by Coatsworth, John H. and Taylor, Alan M., 139–70. Series on Latin American Studies. Cambridge, MA: David Rockefeller Center for Latin American Studies; distributed by Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Della Paolera, Gerardo and Taylor, Alan M. 1999. “Economic Recovery from the Argentine Great Depression: Institutions, Expectations, and the Change of Macroeconomic Regime.” Journal of Economic History 59(3): 567–99.Google Scholar
Della Paolera, Gerardo and Taylor, Alan M. 2001. “Bailing Out: Internal versus External Convertibility.” In Straining at the Anchor: The Argentine Currency Board and the Search for Macroeconomic Stability, 1880–1935, edited by Paolera, Gerardo della and Taylor, Alan M., 165–87. National Bureau of Economic Research Series on Long-Term Factors in Economic Development. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Del Rosal, Ignacio. 2011. “The Empirical Measurement of Rent-Seeking Costs.” Journal of Economic Surveys 25(2): 298325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Demsetz, Harold. 1967. “Toward a Theory of Property Rights.” American Economic Review 57 (May): 347–59.Google Scholar
Denzau, Arthur T. and Munger, Michael C.. 1986. “Legislators and Interest Groups: How Unorganized Interests Get Represented.” American Political Science Review 80(1): 89106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Soto, Hernando. 1989. The Other Path: The Invisible Revolution in the Third World. New York, NY: HarperCollins.Google Scholar
De Soto, Hernando 2000. The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else. New York, NY: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Diaz Alejandro, Carlos F. 1970. Essays on the Economic History of the Argentine Republic. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Dixit, Avinash. 1996. The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Downs, Anthony. 1957. “An Economic Theory of Political Action in a Democracy.” Journal of Political Economy 65(2): 135–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downs, Anthony 1967. Inside Bureaucracy. Boston, MA: Little, Brown.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drobak, John N. and Nye, John V. C., eds. 1997. The Frontiers of the New Institutional Economics. Cambridge, MA: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Dunbar, R. I. M. 1993. “Coevolution of Neocortical Size, Group Size and Language in Humans.” Behavioral and Brain Sciences 16(4): 681735.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dunleavy, P. 2012. “Duverger’s Law Is a Dead Parrot. Outside the USA, First-Past-the-Post Voting Has No Tendency At All to Produce Two Party Politics.” http://blogs.lse.ac.uk/politicsandpolicy/duvergers-law-dead-parrot-dunleavy/.
Dunleavy, P. and Diwakar, R.. 2013. “Analysing Multiparty Competition in Plurality Rule Elections.” Party Politics 19(6): 855–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duverger, Maurice. 1963. Political Parties: Their Organization and Activity in the Modern State. New York, NY: Wiley.Google Scholar
Eggertsson, Thráinn. 1990. Economic Behavior and Institutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eggertsson, Thráinn 2005. Imperfect Institutions: Possibilities and Limits of Reform. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elkins, Zachary, Ginsburg, Tom, and Melton, James. 2009. The Endurance of National Constitutions. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ellickson, Robert C. 1991. Order without Law: How Neighbors Settle Disputes. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Elliott, Mark. 2001. The Constitutional Foundations of Judicial Review. Oxford: Hart Publishing.Google Scholar
Ellis, Joseph J. 2015. The Quartet: Orchestrating the Second American Revolution, 1783–1789. New York, NY: Knopf.Google Scholar
Elster, Jon. 2007. Explaining Social Behavior: More Nuts and Bolts for the Social Sciences. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engdahl, David E. 1992. “John Marshall’s ‘Jeffersonian’ Concept of Judicial Review.” Duke Law Journal 42: 279339.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engerman, Stanley L. and Sokoloff, Kenneth L.. 2012. Economic Development in the Americas since 1500: Endowments and Institutions. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Engstrom, Erik J. and Kernell, Samuel. 2005. “Manufactured Responsiveness: The Impact of State Electoral Laws on Unified Party Control of the Presidency and House of Representatives, 1840–1940.” American Journal of Political Science 49(3): 531–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, D. and O’Halloran, S.. 2001. “Legislative Organization under Separate Powers.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 17(2): 373–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, L., Landes, W. M., and Posner, R. A.. 2013. The Behavior of Federal Judges. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Epstein, Richard. 1990. “The Independence of Judges: The Uses and Limitations of Public Choice Theory.” Brigham Young University Law Review 1990(3): 827–55.Google Scholar
Eskridge, William N. 1991. “Overriding Supreme Court Statutory Interpretation Decisions.” Yale Law Journal 101: 331455.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst and Gintis, Herbert. 2007. “Human Motivation and Social Cooperation: Experimental and Analytical Foundations.” Annual Review of Sociology 33: 4364.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferejohn, John A. 1995. “Foreword.” In Positive Theories of Congressional Institutions, edited by Shepsle, Kenneth A. and Weingast, Barry R., ixxiii. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Figueiredo, A. C. and Limongi, F.. 1996. “Congresso Nacional: Organização, Processo Legislativo e Produção Legal.” Cadernos de Pesquisa 5.
Figueiredo, A. C. and Limongi, F. 2000. “Presidential Power, Legislative Organization and Party Behavior in Brazil.” Comparative Politics 32: 151–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Flyvbjerg, Bent. 2014. “What You Should Know about Megaprojects and Why: An Overview.” Project Management Journal 45(2): 619.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fon, Vincy and Parisi, Francesco. 2006. “Judicial Precedents in Civil Law Systems: A Dynamic Analysis.” International Review of Law and Economics 26(4): 519–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foss, Nicolai J., Lando, Henrik, and Thomsen, Steen. 2000. “The Theory of the Firm.” In Encyclopedia of Law and Economics, Volume 3: The Regulation of Contracts, edited by Bouckaert, Boudewijn and Geest, Gerrit De, 631–58. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Frisman, P. 2008. “Connecticut’s Littering Law.” OLR Research Report, May 20, 2008, www.cga.ct.gov/2008/rpt/2008-R-0314.htm.
Fuller, Lon L. 1977. The Morality of Law. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Furubotn, Eirik G. and Richter, Rudolf, eds. 1991. The New Institutional Economics: A Collection of Articles from the Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics. Heidelberg, Germany: Mohr Siebeck.Google Scholar
Furubotn, Eirik G. and Richter, Rudolf. 2005. Institutions and Economic Theory: The Contribution of the New Institutional Economics. 2nd edn. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gabaix, Xavier. 2016. “Power Laws in Economics: An Introduction.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 30(1): 185206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gainer, Maya. 2016. “Transforming the Courts: Judicial Sector Reforms in Kenya, 2011–2015.” OGP-ISS Case Study. https://successfulsocieties.princeton.edu/sites/successfulsocieties/files/MG_OGP_Kenya.pdf.
Galiani, Sebastian and Sened, Itai, eds. 2014. Institutions, Property Rights, and Economic Growth: The Legacy of Douglass North. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gardbaum, Stephen. 2014. “Separation of Powers and the Growth of Judicial Review in Established Democracies.” American Journal of Comparative Law 62(3): 613–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gardner, Bruce. 1983. “Efficient Redistribution through Commodity Markets.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 65(2) (May): 225–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garlicki, Lech. 2007. “Constitutional Courts versus Supreme Courts.” International Journal of Constitutional Law 5(1): 4468.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garoupa, Nuno and Ginsburg, Tom. 2015. Judicial Reputation: A Comparative Theory. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gathii, James Thuo. 2016. The Contested Empowerment of Kenya’s Judiciary, 2010–2015: A Historical Institutional Analysis. Sheria Publishing House.Google Scholar
Gely, Rafael and Spiller, Pablo T.. 1990. “A Rational Choice Theory of Supreme Court Statutory Decisions with Applications to the ‘State Farm’ and ‘Grove City Cases’.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 6(2): 263300.Google Scholar
Gerken, H. K. 2013. “Exit, Voice, and Disloyalty.” Duke Law Journal 62: 1349–86.Google Scholar
Gibbons, Robert. 2005. “Four Formal(Izable) Theories of the Firm?Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 58(2): 200–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gibbons, Robert and Henderson, Rebecca. 2012. “What Do Managers Do?” In The Handbook of Organizational Economics, edited by Gibbons, Robert and Roberts, John, 680731. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Gibbons, Robert and Roberts, John, eds. 2013. The Handbook of Organizational Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilardi, Fabrizio. 2005. “The Institutional Foundations of Regulatory Capitalism: The Diffusion of Independent Regulatory Agencies in Western Europe.” Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 598(1): 84101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilligan, T. W. and Krehbiel, K.. 1987. “Collective Decisionmaking and Standing Committees: An Informational Rationale for Restrictive Amendment Procedures.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 3(2): 287335.Google Scholar
Ginsburg, Tom. 2003. Judicial Review in New Democracies: Constitutional Courts in Asian Cases. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ginsburg, Tom 2010. “Public Choice and Constitutional Design.” In Research Handbook on Public Choice and Public Law, edited by Farber, Daniel and O’Connell, Anne Joseph, 261–82. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Ginsburg, Tom 2011. “Pitfalls of Measuring the Rule of Law.” Hague Journal on the Rule of Law 3(2): 269–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ginsburg, Tom and Huq, Aziz. 2018. “The Theory and Practice of Constitutional Implementation.” In From Parchment to Practice. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ginsburg, Tom and Simpser, Alberto, eds. 2013. Constitutions in Authoritarian Regimes. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ginsburg, Tom and Versteeg, Mila. 2014. “Why Do Countries Adopt Constitutional Review?Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 30(3): 587622.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glaeser, Edward L. and Shleifer, Andrei. 2003. “The Rise of the Regulatory State.” Journal of Economic Literature 41(2): 401–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glynn, Adam and Sen, Maya. 2015. “Identifying Judicial Empathy: Does Having Daughters Cause Judges to Rule for Women’s Issues?American Journal of Political Science 59(1): 3754.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gode, Dhananjay K. and Sunder, Shyam. 1997. “What Makes Markets Allocationally Efficient?Quarterly Journal of Economics 112(2): 603–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Godinho, Vitorino M. 1965. Os Descobrimentos e a Economia Mundial. Vols. I, II, III. Lisbon: Editora Arcádia.Google Scholar
Goldberg, Victor P. and Erickson, John R.. 1987. “Quantity and Price Adjustment in Long-Term Contracts: A Case Study of Petroleum Coke.” Journal of Law and Economics 30(2): 369–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1993. “Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders’ Coalition.” American Economic Review 83(3): 525–48.Google Scholar
Greif, Avner 2006. Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner and Kingston, Christopher. 2011. “Institutions: Rules or Equilibria?” In Political Economy of Institutions, Democracy, and Voting, edited by Schofield, N. and Caballero, G., 1343. Berlin: Springer-Verlag.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Groseclose, T. 1994. “Testing Committee Composition Hypotheses for the U.S. Congress.” The Journal of Politics 56(2): 440–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Groseclose, T. and King, D. C.. 2001. “Committee Theories Reconsidered.” In Congress Reconsidered, 7th edn., edited by Dodd, L. C. and Oppenheimer, B. I.. Washington, DC: CQ Press.Google Scholar
Grossman, Gene M. and Helpman, Elhanan. 2001. Special Interest Politics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Grossman, Sanford J. and Hart, Oliver D.. 1986. “The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration.” Journal of Political Economy 94(4): 691719.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guardiola, Jorge and Fernando, Garcia-Quero. 2014. “Buen Vivir (living well) in Ecuador: Community and Environmental Satisfaction without Household Material Prosperity?Ecological Economics 107: 177–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gudynas, Eduardo. 2009. “The Political Ecology of the Biocentric Turn in Ecuador’s New Constitution.” Revista de Estudios Sociales no. 32 (January/April): 3446.Google Scholar
Guerra, Kristine. 2016. “‘Intolerable’: Judge Reprimanded After She ‘Berated and Belittled’ Domestic-Violence Victim.” Washington Post, September 1.
Hadfield, Gillian K. 2005. “The Many Legal Institutions that Support Contractual Commitments.” In Handbook of New Institutional Economics, edited by Ménard, Claude and Shirley, Mary, 175203. New York, NY: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hadfield, Gillian K. 2016. Rules for a Flat World. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hadfield, Gillian K. and Weingast, Barry R.. 2012. “What Is Law? A Coordination Model of the Characteristics of Legal Order.” Journal of Legal Analysis 4(2) (December): 471514.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hadfield, Gillian K. and Weingast, Barry R. 2013. “Law without the State: Legal Attributes and the Coordination of Decentralized Collective Punishment.” Journal of Law and Courts 1(1): 334.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haidt, Jonathan. 2012. The Righteous Mind: Why Good People Are Divided by Politics and Religion. New York, NY: Pantheon Books.Google Scholar
Hall, J. A. 1985. Powers and Liberties: The Causes and Consequences of the Rise of the West. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Hallerberg, M. and Marier, P.. 2001. “Executive Authority, the Personal Vote, and Budget Discipline in Latin American and Caribbean Countries.” ZEI Working Paper. ZEI – Center for European Integration Studies.
Hammond, T. H. and Knott, J. H.. 1996. “Who Controls the Bureaucracy?: Presidential Power, Congressional Dominance, Legal Constraints, and Bureaucratic Autonomy in a Model of Multi-Institutional Policy-Making.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 12(1): 119–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shugerman, Handelsman, Jed, . 2012. The People’s Courts: Pursuing Judicial Independence in America. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansmann, Henry. 1988. “Ownership of the Firm.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 4(2): 267304.Google Scholar
Hansmann, Henry 1996. The Ownership of Enterprise. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hansmann, Henry 2013a. “All Firms Are Cooperatives – and So Are Governments.” Journal of Entrepreneurial and Organizational Diversity 2(2): 110.Google Scholar
Hansmann, Henry 2013b. “Ownership and Organizational Form.” In The Handbook of Organizational Economics, edited by Gibbons, Robert and Roberts, John, 891917. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hansmann, Henry 2016. “Firm Ownership: The Legacy of Grossman and Hart.” In The Impact of Incomplete Contracts on Economics, edited by Aghion, Phillipe, Dewatripont, Mathias, Legros, Patrick, and Zingales, Luigi, 307–14. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hanssen, F. Andrew. 2004. “Is There a Politically Optimal Level of Judicial Independence?American Economic Review 94(3): 712–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, H. L. A. 2012. The Concept of Law. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, Oliver D. 1995. Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, Oliver D. and Moore, John. 1990. “Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm.” Journal of Political Economy 98(6): 1119–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. 1945. “The Use of Knowledge in Society.” American Economic Review 35: 519–30.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. 1978. The Constitution of Liberty. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayes, Thomas C. 1990. “Confrontation in the Gulf: The Oilfield Lying Below the Iraq-Kuwait Dispute.” New York Times, September 3.
Helmholz, Richard. 2009. “Bonham’s Case, Judicial Review, and the Law of Nature.” Journal of Legal Analysis 1(1): 325–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Helper, Susan and Henderson, Rebecca. 2014. “Management Practices, Relational Contracts, and the Decline of General Motors.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 28(1): 4972.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hennart, Jean-Francois. 1993. “Explaining the Swollen Middle: Why Most Transactions Are a Mix of ‘Market’ and ‘Hierarchy’.” Organization Science 4(4): 529–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Higgs, Robert. 1996. “Legally Induced Technical Regress in the Washington Salmon Fishery.” In Empirical Studies in Institutional Change, edited by Alston, Lee J., Eggertsson, Thráinn, and North, Douglass C., 247–79. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hirschl, Ran. 2009. Towards Juristocracy: The Origins and Consequences of the New Constitutionalism. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hirschman, Albert O. 1970. Exit, Voice, and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations and States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hirschman, Albert O. 1984. “Against Parsimony: Three Easy Ways of Complicating Some Categories of Economic Discourse.” American Economic Review 74(2): 8996.Google Scholar
Hochfelder, David. 1999. “Taming the Lightning: American Telegraphy as a Revolutionary Technology, 1832–1860.” PhD diss., Case Western Reserve University.
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. 1988. Economics and Institutions: A Manifesto for a Modern Institutional Economics. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. 2003. Recent Developments in Institutional Economics. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. 2007. “Meanings of Methodological Individualism.” Journal of Economic Methodology 12(2): 211–26.Google Scholar
Hoekstra, V. and LaRowe, N.. 2013. “Judging Nominees: An Experimental Test of the Impact of Qualifications and Divisiveness on Public Support for Nominees to the Federal Courts.” Justice System Journal 34(1): 3861.Google Scholar
Hohfeld, Wesley Newcomb. 1913. “Some Fundamental Legal Conceptions as Applied in Judicial Reasoning.” The Yale Law Journal 23(1): 1659.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hohfeld, Wesley Newcomb. 1917. “Fundamental Legal Conceptions as Applied in Judicial Reasoning.” The Yale Law Journal 26(8): 710–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holmström, Bengt and Milgrom, Paul. 1991. “Multitask Principal-Agent Analysis: Incentive Contracts, Asset Ownership, and Job Design.” Special issue, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 7: 2451.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holmström, Bengt and Milgrom, Paul 1994. “The Firm as an Incentive System.” American Economic Review 84(4): 972–91.Google Scholar
Howard, R. M. and Nixon, D. C.. 2002. “Regional Court Influence over Bureaucratic Policymaking: Courts, Ideological Preferences, and the Internal Revenue Service.” Political Research Quarterly 55(4): 907–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Howard, R. M. and Nixon, D. C. 2003. “Local Control of the Bureaucracy: Federal Appeals Courts, Ideology, and the Internal Revenue Service.” Washington University Journal of Law and Policy 13: 233–56.Google Scholar
Howell, William G. 2003. Power without Persuasion: The Politics of Direct Presidential Action. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, J. D. and Shipan, C. R.. 2002. Deliberate Discretion? New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hughes, Jonathan R.T. 1976. Social Control in the Colonial Economy. Charlottesville: University Press of Virginia.Google Scholar
Inman, R. and Fitts, M.. 1990. “Political Institutions and Fiscal Policy: Evidence from the US Historical Record.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 6: 79132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iyigun, Murat and Rubin, Jared. 2017. “The Ideological Roots of Institutional Change.” IZA Working Paper No. 10703, April. Bonn, Germany: IZA – Institute of Labor Economics.
Jackson, Vicki. 2012. “Judicial Independence: Structure, Context, Attitude.” In Judicial Independence in Transition: Strengthening the Rule of Law in the OSCE Region, edited by Seibert-Fohr, Anja, 1986. New York, NY: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacob, Brian A. and Levitt, Steven D.. 2003. “Rotten Apples: An Investigation of the Prevalence and Predictors of Teacher Cheating.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 118(3): 843–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jarrell, Gregg A. 1978. “The Demand for State Regulation of the Electric Utility Industry.” Journal of Law and Economics 21(2) (October): 269–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jefferson, Thomas. 19041905. “To William Charles Jarvis [September 28, 1820].” In The Works of Thomas Jefferson, Federal Edition, vol. 12. New York and London: G. P. Putnam’s Sons.Google Scholar
Jensen, Michael C. and Meckling, William H.. 1976. “Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure.” Journal of Financial Economics 3(4): 305–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, R. N. and Libecap, G. D.. 1994. The Federal Civil Service System and the Problem of Bureaucracy: The Economics and Politics of Institutional Change. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, Bryan D. and Baumgartner, Frank R.. 2005. The Politics of Attention: How Government Prioritizes Problems. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Jones, E. L. 1981. The European Miracle: Environments, Economies, and Geopolitics in the History of Europe and Asia. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Joskow, Paul L. 1985. “Vertical Integration and Long-Term Contracts: The Case of Coal-Burning Electric Generating Plants.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 1(1): 3380.Google Scholar
Joskow, Paul L. 1987. “Contract Duration and Relationship-Specific Investments: Empirical Evidence from Coal Markets.” American Economic Review 77(1): 168–85.Google Scholar
Joskow, Paul L. and Noll, Roger G.. 1981. “Regulation in Theory and Practice: An Overview.” In Studies in Public Regulation, edited by Fromm, Gary, 178. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Judges and Magistrates Vetting Board. 2016. “Vetting of Judges and Magistrates in Kenya: Final Report.” www.jmvb.or.ke/?wpdmdl=1270.
Judiciary Transformation Framework: 2012–2016.” 2012. Registrar of the Judiciary. www.judiciary.go.ke/portal/assets/downloads/reports/Judiciary’s%20Tranformation%20Framework-fv.pdf.
Kalt, Joseph P. and Zupan, Mark A.. 1984. “Capture and Ideology in the Economic Theory of Politics.” American Economic Review 74(3) (June): 279300.Google Scholar
Kalt, Joseph P. and Zupan, Mark A. 1990. “The Apparent Ideological Behavior of Legislators: Testing for Principal-Agent Slack in Political Institutions.” Journal of Law and Economics 33(1) (April): 103–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplow, Louis. 1986. “An Economic Analysis of Legal Transitions.” Harvard Law Review 99(3): 517–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kastellec, Jonathan P., Lax, Jeffrey R., and Phillips, Justin H.. 2010. “Public Opinion and Senate Confirmation of Supreme Court Nominees.” The Journal of Politics 72(3): 767–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaufmann, Patrick J. and Lafontaine, Francine. 1994. “Costs of Control: The Source of Economic Rents for McDonald’s Franchisees.” Journal of Law and Economics 37(2): 417–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keele, Denise M., Malmsheimer, Robert W., Floyd, Donald W., and Zhang, Lianjun. 2009. “An Analysis of Ideological Effects in Published versus Unpublished Judicial Opinions.” Journal of Empirical Legal Studies 6(1): 213–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kennedy, J. B. 2015. “‘Do This! Do That!’ and Nothing Will Happen: Executive Orders and Bureaucratic Responsiveness.” American Politics Research 43(1): 5982.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Khan, Zorina. 2005. The Democratization of Invention: Patents and Copyrights in American Economic Development, 1790–1920. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Khan, Zorina and Sokoloff, Kenneth L.. 2001. “The Early Development of Intellectual Property Institutions in the United States.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 15(3): 233–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kiewiet, R. D. and McCubbins, M. D.. 1994. The Logic of Delegation: Congressional Parties and the Appropriations Process. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Kim, Jongwook and Mahoney, Joseph T.. 2005. “Property Rights Theory, Transaction Costs Theory, and Agency Theory: An Organizational Economics Approach to Strategic Management.” Managerial and Decision Economics 26(4): 223–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
King, , The Honourable L. J., AQ CQ. 20022003. “Removal of Judges.” Flinders Journal of Law Reform 6(2): 169–83.Google Scholar
Kiser, Edgar and Barzel, Yoram. 1991. “The Origins of Democracy in England.” Rationality and Society 3(4): 396422.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, Benjamin. 1980. “Transaction Cost Determinants of ‘Unfair’ Contractual Arrangements.” American Economic Review 70(2): 356–62.Google Scholar
Klein, Benjamin, Crawford, Robert G., and Alchian, Armen A.. 1978. “Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process.” Journal of Law and Economics 21(2) (October): 297326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, Peter G. 2005. “The Make-Or-Buy Decision: Lessons from Empirical Studies.” In Handbook of New Institutional Economics, edited by Ménard, Claude and Shirley, Mary M., 435–64. New York, NY: Springer.Google Scholar
Klein, Peter G. and Sykuta, Michael E.. 2010. The Edward Elgar Companion to Transaction Cost Economics. Cheltenham, UK: Edgar Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kosová, Renatá and Lafontaine, Francine. 2012. “Much Ado about Chains: A Research Agenda.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 30(3): 303–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krehbiel, K. 1992. Information and Legislative Organization. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Kuran, Timur. 2011. The Long Divergence: How Islamic Law Held Back the Middle East. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Lakner, Christoph and Milanovic, Branko. 2016. “Global Income Distribution: From the Fall of the Berlin Wall to the Great Recession.” World Bank Economic Review 30(2): 203–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Landes, D. S. 1998. The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some Are So Rich and Some So Poor. New York, NY: Norton.Google Scholar
Landes, Elisabeth M. 1982. “Insurance, Liability, and Accidents: A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation of the Effect of No-Fault Accidents.” Journal of Law and Economics 25(1) (April): 4965.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
La Porta, Rafael, Lopez-de-Silanes, Florencio, Pop-Eleches, Cristian, and Shleifer, Andrei. 2004. “Judicial Checks and Balances.” Journal of Political Economy 112 (April): 445–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
La Porta, Rafael, Lopez-de-Silanes, Florencio, and Shleifer, Andrei. 2008. “The Economic Consequences of Legal Origins.” Journal of Economic Literature 46(2): 285332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Law, David S. and Versteeg, Mila. 2011. “The Evolution and Ideology of Global Constitutionalism.” California Law Review 99: 1163–257.Google Scholar
Law, David S. and Versteeg, Mila 2013. “Sham Constitutions.” California Law Review 101(4): 863952.Google Scholar
Leflar, Robert A. 1961. “Some Observations Concerning Judicial Opinions.” Columbia Law Review 61(5): 810–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levy, Brian and Spiller, Pablo T.. 1996. Regulations, Institutions, and Commitment: Comparative Studies of Telecommunications. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, David K. 1969. Convention: A Philosophical Study. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Libecap, Gary D. 1989. Contracting for Property Rights. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Libecap, Gary D. 1992. “The Rise of the Chicago Packers and the Origins of Meat Inspection and Antitrust.” Economic Inquiry 30(2): 242–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Libecap, Gary D. 2007. “The Assignment of Property Rights on the Western Frontier: Lessons for Contemporary Environmental and Resource Policy.” The Journal of Economic History 67(2): 257–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lijphart, Arend. 1977. Democracy in Plural Societies: A Comparative Exploration. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Lijphart, Arend 1999. Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Lim, Claire S. H. 2013. “Preferences and Incentives of Appointed and Elected Public Officials: Evidence from State Trial Court Judges.” American Economic Review 103(4): 1360–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Linneman, Peter. 1980. “The Effects of Consumer Safety Standards: The 1973 Mattress Flammability Standard.” Journal of Law and Economics 23(2) (October): 461–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Linz, J. 1990. “The Perils of Presidentialism.” Journal of Democracy 1(1) (Winter): 5169.Google Scholar
Lott, John R., Jr. 1997. “Does Political Reform Increase Wealth?: Or, Why the Difference between the Chicago and Virginia Schools Is Really an Elasticity Question.” Public Choice 91(3/4): 219–27.Google Scholar
Ludington, Arthur C. 1911. American Ballot Laws, 1888–1910. Albany: New York State Library.Google Scholar
Lueck, Dean and Miceli, Thomas. 2007. “Property Law.” In Handbook of Law and Economics, edited by Polinsky, A. Mitchell and Shavell, Steven, 183257. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Mainwaring, Scott. 1993. “Presidentialism, Multipartism, and Democracy: The Difficult Combination.” Comparative Political Studies 26(2): 198228.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mainwaring, Scott 1999. Rethinking Party Systems in the Third Wave of Democratization: The Case of Brazil. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Mainwaring, Scott and Shugart, Matthew S.. 1997. Presidentialism and Democracy in Latin America. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Makadok, Richard and Coff, Russell. 2009. “Both Market and Hierarchy: An Incentive-System Theory of Hybrid Governance Forms.” The Academy of Management Review 34(2): 297319.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maliti, Tom. 2012. “Four Kenyan Appeals Court Judges Declared Unfit for Office.” International Justice Monitor. www.ijmonitor.org/2012/04/four-kenyan-appeals-court-judges-declared-unfit-for-office/.
Manne, Henry. 1997. “The Judiciary and Free Markets.” Harvard Journal of Law and Public Policy 21(1): 1137.Google Scholar
Marchand, James R. and Russell, Keith P.. 1973. “Externalities, Liability, Separability, and Resource Allocation.” American Economic Review 63(4): 611–20.Google Scholar
Martimort, D. 1996. “Exclusive Dealing, Common Agency, and Multiprincipals Incentive Theory.” RAND Journal of Economics 27(1): 131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Masten, Scott E. 1988. “A Legal Basis for the Firm.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 4(1): 181–98.Google Scholar
Masten, Scott E. and Snyder, Edward A.. 1993. “United States versus United Shoe Machinery Corporation: On the Merits.” Journal of Law and Economics 36(1): 3370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mattiace, Shannan and Nonnenmacher, Tomas. 2014. “The Organization of Hacienda Labor during the Mexican Revolution: Evidence from Yucatán.” Mexican Studies-Estudios Mexicanos 30(2): 366–96.Google Scholar
McCarty, Nolan. 2004. “The Appointments Dilemma.” American Journal of Political Science 48(3): 413–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCloskey, Deidre. 1998. “The So-Called Coase Theorem.” Eastern Economic Journal 24(3): 367–71.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Deidre 2006. The Bourgeois Virtues: Ethics for an Age of Commerce. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCloskey, Deidre 2010. Bourgeois Dignity: Why Economics Can’t Explain the Modern World. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCloskey, Deidre 2016. Bourgeois Equality: How Ideas, Not Capital or Institutions, Enriched the World. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
McCubbins, Matthew D., Noll, Roger G., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1987. “Administrative Procedures as Instruments of Control.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 8(2): 243–77.Google Scholar
McCubbins, Matthew D., Noll, Roger G., and Weingast, Barry R. 1989. “Structure and Process, Politics and Policy: Administrative Arrangements and the Political Control of Agencies.” Virginia Law Review 75(2): 431–82.Google Scholar
McCubbins, Mathew D. and Schwartz, Thomas. 1984. “Congressional Oversight Overlooked: Police Patrols versus Fire Alarms.” American Journal of Political Science 28(1): 165–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McGuire, Robert A. 2003. To Form a More Perfect Union: A New Economic Interpretation of the United States Constitution. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
McKelvey, Richard D. 1976. “Intransitivities in Multidimensional Voting Bodies.” Journal of Economic Theory 12: 472–82.Google Scholar
McKelvey, Richard D. 1979. “General Conditions for Global Intransitivities in Formal Voting Models.” Econometrica 47(5): 1085–112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McNamara, Paul. 2006. “Deontic Logic.” In The Handbook of the History of Logic, vol. 7: Logic and the Modalities in the Twentieth Century, edited by Gabbay, Dov and Woods, John, 197288. Amsterdam, Netherlands: Elsevier Press.Google Scholar
Medema, Steven G. 1999. “Legal Fiction: The Place of the Coase Theorem in Law and Economics.” Economics and Philosophy 15(2): 209–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Medema, Steven G. and Zerbe, Richard O. Jr. 2000. “The Coase Theorem.” In Encyclopedia of Law and Economics, Volume 1: The History and Methodology of Law and Economics, edited by Bouckaert, Boudewijn and Geest, Gerrit De, 836–92: Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Ménard, Claude. 2013. “Hybrid Modes of Organization: Alliances, Joint Ventures, Networks, and Other Strange Animals.” In The Handbook of Organizational Economics, edited by Gibbons, Robert and Roberts, John, 10661108. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Ménard, Claude and Raynaud, Emmanuel. 2010. “Ulysses and the Sirens: Hands-Tying Governance in Hybrid Forms.” Working Paper, Centre d’Economie de la Sorbonne.
Ménard, Claude and Shirley, Mary M., eds. 2005. Handbook of New Institutional Economics. New York, NY: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Merrill, Thomas W. and Smith, Henry E.. 2011. “Making Coasean Property More Coasean.” Journal of Law and Economics 54(4): S77S104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, Paul and Roberts, John. 1990. “Bargaining Costs, Influence Costs, and the Organization of Economic Activity.” In Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, edited by Alt, James E. and Shepsle, Kenneth A., 5789. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, Gary J. 2005. “The Political Evolution of Principal-Agent Models.” Annual Review of Political Science 8: 203–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mishan, E. J. 1967. “Pareto Optimality and the Law.” Oxford Economic Papers 19(3): 255–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moe, Terry M. 1985. “Control and Feedback in Economic Regulation: The Case of the NLRB.” American Political Science Review 79(4): 1094–116.Google Scholar
Moe, Terry M. 1987. “An Assessment of the Positive Theory of ‘Congressional Dominance’.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 12(4): 475520.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moe, Terry M. 2013. “Delegation, Control, and the Study of Public Bureaucracy.” In The Handbook of Organizational Economics, edited by Gibbons, Robert and Roberts, John, 1148–81. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Moe, Terry M. and Howell, William G.. 1999a. “The Presidential Power of Unilateral Action.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 15(1): 132–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moe, Terry M. and Howell, William G. 1999b. “Unilateral Action and Presidential Power: A Theory.” Presidential Studies Quarterly 29(4): 850–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moe, Terry M. and Wilson, S.. 1994. “Presidents and the Politics of Structure.” Law and Contemporary Problems 57 (Spring): 144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mokyr, Joel. 2012. The Enlightened Economy: An Economic History of Britain 1700–1850. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Mokyr, Joel 2017. A Culture of Growth: The Origins of the Modern Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Moser, Petra. 2005. “How Do Patent Laws Influence Innovation? Evidence from Nineteenth-Century World’s Fairs.” American Economic Review 95(4): 1214–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mossoff, Adam. 2014. “O’Reilly v. Morse.” George Mason University Law and Economics Research Paper no. 14–22. www.law.gmu.edu/assets/files/publications/working_papers/1422.pdf.
Mueller, Bernardo. 1998. “The Economic Theory of Regulation: The Case of Agrarian Reform Legislation in Brazil.” Revista Brasileira de Economia 52(1) (January/March): 83110.Google Scholar
Mueller, Bernardo and Ayello Leite, João Gabriel. 2016. “Coevolution of Institutions and Culture in 16th Century Portuguese Empire.” Working Paper, University of Brasilia.
Mueller, Dennis C. 2003. Public Choice III. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Muris, T. J. 1986. “Regulatory Policymaking at the Federal Trade Commission: The Extent of Congressional Control.” Journal of Political Economy 94(4): 884–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myerson, R. B. 2008. “Perspectives on Mechanism Design in Economic Theory.” American Economic Review 98(3): 586603.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neustadt, R. E. 1990. Presidential Power and the Modern Presidents. New York, NY: Free Press.Google Scholar
Nichols, Lionel. 2015. The International Criminal Court and the End of Impunity in Kenya. New York, NY: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Niskanen, William A. 1971. Bureaucracy and Representative Government. New York, NY: Aldine-Atherton.Google Scholar
Niskanen, William A. 1975. “Bureaucrats and Politicians.” Journal of Law and Economics 18 (December): 617–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
“Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences, 1991 – Press Release.” Nobel Media. www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economic-sciences/laureates/1991/press.html.
Noll, Roger G. 1989a. “Comments on Peltzman’s: ‘The Economic Theory of Regulation after a Decade of Deregulation’.” Special issue, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: 48–58.
Noll, Roger G. 1989b. “Economic Perspectives on the Politics of Regulation.” In Handbook of Industrial Organization, Volume 2, edited by Schmalensee, R. and Willig, R. D., 1253–87. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.Google Scholar
Noonan, John Thomas. 2005. A Church that Can and Cannot Change: The Development of Catholic Moral Teaching. Notre Dame, IN: University of Notre Dame Press.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1989. “Institutions and Economic Growth: An Historical Introduction.” World Development 17(9): 1319–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1992. “Institutions and Economic Theory.” The American Economist 36(1) (Spring): 36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. 2005. Understanding the Process of Economic Change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. and Thomas, Robert P.. 1973. The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C., Wallis, John Joseph, and Weingast, Barry R.. 2009. Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. and Weingast, Barry R.. 1989. “Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England.” The Journal of Economic History 49(4): 803–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ober, Josiah. 2017. Demopolis: Democracy before Liberalism in Theory and Practice. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Ordeshook, Peter C. and Shvetsova, Olga V.. 1994. “Ethnic Heterogeneity, District Magnitude, and the Number of Parties.” American Journal of Political Science 38(1): 100–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ortiz Crespo, Santiago. 2008. “Citizen Participation: The Constitution of 1998 and the New Constitutional Project.” Revista de Ciencias Sociales 32 (September): 1317.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor 2005. Understanding Institutional Diversity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Vincent. 1991. The Meaning of American Federalism: Constituting a Self-Governing Society. San Francisco, CA: ICS Press.Google Scholar
Overby, L. M., Henschen, B. M., Walsh, M. H., and Strauss, J.. 1992. “Courting Constituents? An Analysis of the Senate Confirmation Vote on Justice Clarence Thomas.” American Political Science Review 86(4): 9971003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Owens, Ryan J., Walters, Daniel E., Black, Ryan C., and Madonna, Anthony. 2014. “Ideology, Qualifications, and Covert Senate Obstruction of Federal Court Nominations.” University of Illinois Law Review 2014(2): 347–88.Google Scholar
Ozielo, Ojonnia. 2010. “Judicial Integrity and the Vetting Process in Kenya.” Amani Papers 1(6). UNDP Kenya. www.ke.undp.org/content/dam/kenya/docs/Amani%20Papers/AP_Volume1_n6_Sept2010.pdf.Google Scholar
Pachano, Simón. 2010. “Ecuador: New Political System into Operation.” Revista de Ciencia Política 30(2): 297317.Google Scholar
Parisi, Francesco and Fon, Vincy. 2009. The Economics of Lawmaking. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parliament of Australia. 2012. “Completed Inquiries 2010–2013: Chapter 1.” Senate Standing Committees on Legal and Constitutional Affairs. www.aph.gov.au/Parliamentary_Business/Committees/Senate/Legal_and_Constitutional_Affairs/Completed_inquiries/2010–13/judicialcomplaints/report/c01.
Pashigian, Peter P. 1976. “Consequences and Causes of Public Ownership of Urban Transit Facilities.” The Journal of Political Economy 84(6) (August): 1239–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pashigian, Peter P. 1985. “Environmental Regulation: Whose Self-Interests Are Being Protected?Economic Inquiry 23 (October): 551–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pauly, Mark V. 1968. “The Economics of Moral Hazard: Comment.” American Economic Review 58(3): 531–37.Google Scholar
Paz, y Miño Cepeda, Juan. 2009. “El Gobierno de Rafael Correa: Un nuevo ciclo en la historia de Ecuador” [The government of Rafael Correa: A new cycle in the history of Ecuador]. Metapolítica 65: 7176.Google Scholar
Peabody, Bruce. 2011. The Politics of Judicial Independence. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Peltzman, Sam. 1973. “An Evaluation of Consumer Protection Legislation: The 1962 Drug Amendments.” Journal of Political Economy 81(5): 1049–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peltzman, Sam 1975. “The Effects of Automobile Safety Regulation.” Journal of Political Economy 83(4): 677726.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peltzman, Sam 1976. “Toward a More General Theory of Regulation.” Journal of Law and Economics 19 (August): 211–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peltzman, Sam 1989. “The Economic Theory of Regulation after a Decade of Deregulation.” Special issue, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: 159.
Pereira, Carlos and Mueller, Bernardo. 2000. “Uma teoria da preponderância do poder Executivo: O sistema de comissões no Legislativo brasileiro.” Revista Brasileira de Ciências Sociais 15(43): 4567.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pereira, Carlos and Mueller, Bernardo 2004. “The Cost of Governing Strategic Behavior of the President and Legislators in Brazil’s Budgetary Process.” Comparative Political Studies 37(7): 781815.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peretti, Terri Jennings. 2002. “Does Judicial Independence Exist?: The Lessons of Social Science Research.” In Judicial Independence at the Crossroads: An Interdisciplinary Approach, edited by Burbank, Stephen B. and Friedman, Barry, 103–33. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.Google Scholar
Pinker, Steven. 2011. The Better Angels of Our Nature: Why Violence Has Declined. New York, NY: Viking.Google Scholar
Plott, Charles R. 1967. “A Notion of Equilibrium and Its Possibility under Majority Rule.” American Economic Review 57: 787806.Google Scholar
Plum Book. 2012. Policy and Supporting Positions. Washington, DC: Committee on Oversight and Government Reform.
Popper, Karl. 1963. Conjectures and Refutations: The Growth of Scientific Knowledge. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Posin, Daniel Q. 1990. “The Coase Theorem: If Pigs Could Fly.” Wayne Law Review 37(1): 89120.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1974. “Theories of Economic Regulation.” The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 5(2): 335–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1998. “Rational Choice, Behavioral Economics, and the Law.” Stanford Law Review 50: 1551–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 2005. “Judicial Behavior and Performance: An Economic Approach.” Florida State University Law Review 32: 1259–79.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard A. and Parisi, Francesco, eds. 1997. Law and Economics, Volume 1: Theoretical and Methodological Issues. Cheltenham, UK: Edgar Elgar.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard A. and Rasmusen, Eric. 1999. “Creating and Enforcing Norms, with Special Reference to Sanctions.” International Review of Law and Economics 19: 369–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poterba, J. M. 1994. “State Responses to Fiscal Crises: The Effects of Budgetary Institutions and Politics.” Journal of Political Economy 102(4): 799821.Google Scholar
Prendergast, Canice. 2007. “The Motivation and Bias of Bureaucrats.” American Economic Review 97(1): 180–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Przeworski, A., Alvarez, M. E., Cheibub, J. A., and Limongi, F.. 2000. Democracy and Development: Political Institutions and Well-Being in the World. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Radcliffe, Sarah A. 2012. “Development for a Postneoliberal Era? Sumak Kawsay, Living Well and the Limits to Decolonisation in Ecuador.” Geoforum 43: 240–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rakove, Jack, Ruttan, Andrew, and Weingast, Barry R.. 2004. “Ideas, Interests, and Credible Commitments in the American Revolution.” Working Paper, Hoover Institution, Stanford University, August.
Report of the Committee of the Administration of Justice. 1998. Nairobi: Government Printer.
Report of the Integrity and Anticorruption Committee. 2003. Nairobi: Government Printer.
Richter, Rudolf. 2015. Essays on New Institutional Economics. New York, NY: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Riker, William H. 1980. “Implications from the Disequilibrium of Majority Rule for the Study of Institutions.” American Political Science Review 74(2): 432–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Riker, William H. 1982. “The Two-Party System and Duverger’s Law: An Essay on the History of Political Science.” American Political Science Review 76(4): 753–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Riker, William H. 1984. “The Heresthetics of Constitution-Making: The Presidency in 1787, with Comments on Determinism and Rational Choice.” American Political Science Review 78(1) (March): 116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, David T. and Stuart, Toby E.. 2006. “Network Effects in the Governance of Strategic Alliances.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 23(1): 242–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, J. A. and Torvik, R.. 2011. “Institutional Comparative Statics.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series No. 17106.
Rodrik, Dani, Subramanian, Arvind, and Trebbi, Francesco. 2009. “Institutions Rule: The Primacy of Institutions over Geography and Integration in Economic Development.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series No. 9305.
Rothbard, Murray. 1995. Economic Thought before Adam Smith: An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought, Volume I. Brookville, VT: Ashgate.Google Scholar
Roubini, N. and Sachs, J. D.. 1989. “Political and Economic Determinants of Budget Deficits in the Industrial Democracies.” European Economic Review 33 (April): 903–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rourke, Francis E. 1984. Bureaucracy, Politics, and Public Policy. New York, NY: Harper Collins.Google Scholar
Rowley, Charles K. and Schneider, Friedrich, eds. 2004. The Encyclopedia of Public Choice. 2 vols. Boston, MA: Kluwer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubin, Paul H. 2005. “Legal Systems as Frameworks for Market Exchanges.” In Handbook of New Institutional Economics, edited by Ménard, Claude and Shirley, Mary, 205–28. New York, NY: Springer.Google Scholar
Rudalevige, A. 2012. “The Contemporary Presidency: Executive Orders and Presidential Unilateralism.” Presidential Studies Quarterly 42: 138–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm. 1994. Institutions in Economics: The Old and the New Institutionalism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Salvador Tamayo, Estefanía. 2014. “The Understanding of Development in Ecuador through Institutions and Beliefs, 1950–2014.” Masters Economics Thesis, Lund University.Google Scholar
Scarrow, Howard A. 1986. “Duverger’s Law, Fusion, and the Decline of American ‘Third’ Parties.” Western Political Quarterly 39(4) (December): 634–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scartascini, C., and Crain, W. M.. 2002. “The Size and Composition of Government Spending in Multi-Party Systems.” SSRN Electronic Journal (April).
Schelling, Thomas C. 1960. The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Schenk, Karl-Ernst. 2003. Economic Institutions and Complexity. Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Schlag, Pierre. 2015. “How to Do Things with Hohfeld.” Law and Contemporary Problems 78(1–2): 185234.Google Scholar
Schofield, Norman. 1993. “Political Competition and Multiparty Coalition Governments.” European Journal of Political Research 23: 133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schofield, Norman 2006. Architects of Political Change: Constitutional Quandaries and Social Choice Theory. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schofield, Norman 2008. The Spatial Model of Politics. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Schultz, P. Wesley, and Stein, Steven R.. 2009. “Litter in America: National Findings and Recommendations.” Keep America Beautiful.
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1942. Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy. New York, NY: Harper & Brothers.Google Scholar
Scott, James C. 1985. Weapons of the Weak: Everyday Forms of Peasant Resistance. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Segal, Jeffrey A., Cameron, Charles M., and Cover, Albert D.. 1992. “A Spatial Model of Roll Call Voting: Senators, Constituents, Presidents, and Interest Groups in Supreme Court Confirmations.” American Journal of Political Science 36(1): 96121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Segal, Jeffrey A. and Spaeth, H. J.. 2002. The Supreme Court and the Attitudinal Model Revisited. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
SENPLADES. 2010. “Los nuevos retos de América Latina: Socialismo y Sumak Kawsay” [The new challenges of Latin America: Socialism and Sumak Kawsay]. Quito: SENPLADES.
Shear, Michael D. 2016. “Ruth Bader Ginsburg Expresses Regret for Criticizing Donald Trump.” New York Times, July 14.
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 2008. “Old Questions and New Answers about Institutions: The Riker Objection Revisited.” In The Oxford Handbook of Political Economy, edited by Weingast, Barry R. and Wittman, Donald A., 1031–49. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 2010. Analyzing Politics: Rationality, Behavior, and Institutions. 2nd edn. New York, NY: Norton.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 2017. Rule Breaking and Political Imagination. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. and Weingast, Barry R.. 1981. “Structure-Induced Equilibrium and Legislative Choice.” Public Choice 37(3): 503–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. and Weingast, Barry R. 1987. “The Institutional Foundations of Committee Power.” American Political Science Review 81(1): 85104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. and Weingast, Barry R. 1995a. “Positive Theories of Congressional Institutions.” In Positive Theories of Congressional Institutions, edited by Shepsle, Kenneth A. and Weingast, Barry R., 535. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. and Weingast, Barry R. eds. 1995b. Positive Theories of Congressional Institutions. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shipan, Charles R. 1997. Designing Judicial Review: Interest Groups, Congress, and Communications Policy. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Shirley, Mary M., Wang, Ning, and Claude, Ménard. 2015. “Ronald Coase’s Impact on Economics.” Journal of Institutional Economics 11(2): 227–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shugart, M. and Carey, J.. 1992. Presidents and Assemblies: Constitutional Design and Electoral Dynamics. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Siaroff, A. 2009. Comparing Political Regimes: A Thematic Introduction to Comparative Politics. Toronto, Canada: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. 1957. Models of Man. New York, NY: Wiley.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. 1961. Administrative Behavior: A Study of Decision-Making Processes in Administrative Organization. 2nd edn. New York, NY: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. 1991. “Organizations and Markets.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 5(2): 2544.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skaaning, Svend-Erik. 2010. “Measuring the Rule of Law.” Political Research Quarterly 63(2): 449–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Adam. [1776] 2007. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Edited by S. M. Soares. MetaLibri Digital Library. www.ibiblio.org/ml/libri/s/SmithA_WealthNations_p.pdf.
Smith, Henry E. 2000. “Semicommon Property Rights and Scattering in the Open Fields.” Journal of Legal Studies 29(1) (January): 131–69.Google Scholar
Smith, J. Allen. 1914. “Effect of State Regulation of Public Utilities upon Municipal Home Rule.” Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 53: 8593.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sobbrio, Francesco. 2011. “Indirect Lobbying and Media Bias.” Quarterly Journal of Political Science 6(3–4): 235–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sokoloff, Kenneth L. and Engerman, Stanley L.. 2000. “Institutions, Factor Endowments, and Paths of Development in the New World.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 14(3): 217–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spence, Michael. 1973. “Job Market Signaling.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 87(3): 355–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spiller, Pablo T. 1990. “Politicians, Interest Groups, and Regulators: A Multiple-Principals Agency Theory of Regulation, or ‘Let Them Be Bribed.’” Journal of Law and Economics 33(1): 65101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spiller, Pablo T. and Gely, Rafael. 1992. “Congressional Control or Judicial Independence: The Determinants of U.S. Supreme Court Labor Relations Decisions, 1949–1988.” Rand Journal of Economics 23: 463–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spiller, Pablo T. and Gely, Rafael 2009. “Strategic Judicial Decision-Making.” Oxford Handbooks Online. www.oxfordhandbooks.com/view/10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199208425.001.0001/oxfordhb-9780199208425-e-3.
Spiller, Pablo T. and Liao, Sanny. 2008. “Buy, Lobby or Sue: Interest Groups’ Participation in Policy Making: A Selective Survey.” In New Institutional Economics: A Guidebook, edited by Brousseau, Eric and Glachant, Jean-Michel, 307–27. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Starrett, David A. 1972. “Fundamental Nonconvexities in the Theory of Externalities.” Journal of Economic Theory 4(2): 180–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steensgaard, Niels. 1974. The Asian Trade Revolution of the Seventeenth Century: The East India Companies and the Decline of the Caravan Trade. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Stevens, John Paul. 1986. “The Third Branch of Liberty.” University of Miami Law Review 41(2): 277–93.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J. 1971. “The Theory of Economic Regulation.” The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2(1): 321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, George J. ed. 1988. Chicago Studies in Political Economy. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J. and Friedland, Claire. 1962. “What Can Regulators Regulate? The Case of Electricity.” Journal of Law and Economics 5 (October): 116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E. 1975. “The Theory of ‘Screening,’ Education, and the Distribution of Income.” American Economic Review 65(3): 283300.Google Scholar
Stromberg, David. 2004. “Mass Media Competition, Political Competition, and Public Policy.” Review of Economic Studies 71: 265–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. 1989. “On the Costs and Benefits of Aggressive Judicial Review of Agency Action.” Duke Law Journal 1989(3): 522–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tadelis, Steven and Williamson, Oliver E.. 2013. “Transaction Cost Economics.” In The Handbook of Organizational Economics, edited by Gibbons, Robert and Roberts, John, 159–89. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Tridimas, George. 2005. “Judges and Taxes: Judicial Review, Judicial Independence and the Size of Government.” Constitutional Political Economy 16: 530.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tullock, Gordon. 1965. The Politics of Bureaucracy. Washington, DC: Public Affairs Press.Google Scholar
Tullock, Gordon 1967. Toward a Mathematics of Politics. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Tullock, Gordon and Brennan, Geoffrey. 1981. “Why So Much Stability.” Public Choice 37(2): 189204.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tushnet, Mark V. 2003. Slave Law in the American South: State v. Mann in History and Literature. Lawrence: University Press of Kansas.Google Scholar
Umbeck, John. 1981. “Might Makes Rights: A Theory of the Formation and Initial Distribution of Property Rights.” Economic Inquiry 19(1): 3859.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
US Department of Agriculture. 1936. Agricultural Statistics 1936. Washington, DC: US Department of Agriculture.
van der Schyff, Gerhard. 2010. Judicial Review of Legislation: A Comparative Review of the United Kingdom, the Netherlands, and South Africa. New York, NY: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
van Zandt, David E. 1993. “The Lessons of the Lighthouse: ‘Government’ or ‘Private’ Provision of Goods.” Journal of Legal Studies 22(1): 4772.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Viscusi, Kip W., Harrington, Joseph E. Jr., and Vernon, John M.. 2005. Economics of Regulation and Antitrust. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Voigt, Stefan. 1997. “Positive Constitutional Economics: A Survey.” Public Choice 90(1/4): 1153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Voigt, Stefan 2008. “The Economic Effects of Judicial Accountability: Cross-Country Evidence.” European Journal of Law and Economics 25(2) (April): 95123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Voigt, Stefan 2011. “Positive Constitutional Economics II – A Survey of Recent Developments.” Public Choice 146(1–2) (January): 205–56.Google Scholar
Volden, C. 2002. “A Formal Model of the Politics of Delegation in a Separation of Powers System.” American Journal of Political Science 46(1): 111–33.Google Scholar
Wallis, John Joseph. 2018a. “Leviathan Denied: Rules, Governments, and Social Dynamics.” Unpublished book manuscript.
Wallis, John Joseph. 2018b. “What Institutions Are: The Difference between Norms and Institutions, Rules and Enforcement.” Working Paper, University of Maryland, January.
Weingast, Barry R. 1979. “A Rational Choice Perspective on Congressional Norms.” American Journal of Political Science 23(2) (May): 245–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weingast, Barry R. 1998. “Political Stability and Civil War: Institutions, Commitment, and American Democracy.” In Analytic Narratives, edited by Bates, Robert et al., 148–93. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry R. 2015. “Capitalism, Democracy, and Countermajoritarian Institutions.” Working Paper, Stanford University. https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2639793.
Weingast, Barry R. 2016. “Exposing the Neoclassical Fallacy: McCloskey on Ideas and the Great Enrichment.” Scandinavian Economic History Review 64(3): 189201.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weingast, Barry R. and Marshall, W. J.. 1988. “The Industrial Organization of Congress; Or, Why Legislatures, Like Firms, Are Not Organized as Markets.” Journal of Political Economy 96(1): 132–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weingast, Barry R. and Moran, Mark J.. 1983. “Bureaucratic Discretion or Congressional Control? Regulatory Policymaking by the Federal Trade Commission.” Journal of Political Economy 91(5): 765800.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wellisz, Stanislaw. 1964. “On External Diseconomies and the Government-Assisted Invisible Hand.” Economica 31(124): 345–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whinston, Michael. 2003. “On the Transaction Cost Determinants of Vertical Integration.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 19(1): 123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wiggins, Steven N. and Libecap, Gary D.. 1985. “Oil Field Unitization: Contractual Failure in the Presence of Imperfect Information.” American Economic Review 75(3): 368–85.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1971. “The Vertical Integration of Production: Market Failure Considerations.” American Economic Review 61(2): 112–23.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. New York, NY: Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting. New York, NY: Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1990. “The Firm as a Nexus of Treaties: An Introduction.” In The Firm as a Nexus of Treaties, edited by Aoki, Masahiko, Gustafsson, Bo, and Williamson, Oliver E., 125. London: Sage.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1996. The Mechanisms of Governance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 2000. “The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead.” Journal of Economic Literature 38(3): 595613.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 2002. “The Theory of the Firm as Governance Structure: From Choice to Contract.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 16(3): 171–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, James Q. 1980. The Politics of Regulation. New York, NY: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Wilson, James Q. 1989. Bureaucracy: What Government Agencies Do and Why They Do It. New York, NY: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Wittman, Donald A. 1989. “Why Democracies Produce Efficient Results.” Journal of Political Economy 97(6): 1395–424.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
World Bank. 2017. World Databank. http://databank.worldbank.org/data/home.aspx.
Yandle, Bruce. 1983. “Bootleggers and Baptists: The Education of a Regulatory Economist.” Regulation 7(3): 1216.Google Scholar
Young, H. Peyton. 1996. “The Economics of Convention.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 10(2): 105–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yu, Zhihao. 2005. “Environmental Protection: A Theory of Direct and Indirect Competition for Political Influence.” Review of Economic Studies 72: 269–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zelder, Martin. 1998. “The Cost of Accosting Coase: A Reconciliatory Survey of Proofs and Disproofs of the Coase Theorem.” In Coasean Economics: Law and Economics and the New Institutional Economics, edited by Medema, Steven G., 3094. New York, NY: Springer Science.Google Scholar