Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-22dnz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-27T07:54:12.626Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Part IV - The Domestic Politics of Fossil Fuel Subsidies and Their Reform

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 August 2018

Jakob Skovgaard
Affiliation:
Lunds Universitet, Sweden
Harro van Asselt
Affiliation:
Stockholm Environment Institute
Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2018
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This content is Open Access and distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 https://creativecommons.org/cclicenses/

11 Fossil Fuel Subsidy Reform in Indonesia The Struggle for Successful Reform

Kathryn Chelminski
11.1 Introduction

Indonesia’s first attempt at fossil fuel subsidy reform following the 1997 Asian financial crisis exacerbated the already dire economic crisis for people across the country. The dramatic increase in fuel prices ignited protests and violent riots, representing the breaking point in public patience for the Suharto regime’s rampant corruption and poor governance; the weeks of unrest following the reforms contributed to Suharto’s resignation in 1998. Numerous fuel subsidy reforms were attempted in Indonesia in the following decades but with varying degrees of success. Indonesia makes an excellent case study for analysis because it is illustrative of the challenges involved in subsidy reform in developing countries – including corruption, vested interests, democratisation and domestic energy consumption dependent on fossil fuels.

Indonesia is often referenced in the fossil fuel subsidies literature as a case of successful reform. However, these reforms have been going on for 15 years, and subsidies are still offered. This chapter asks whether the Indonesia case provides an example of successful subsidy reform by analysing three periods of reform: (1) the aftermath of the Asian financial crisis under Presidents Suharto, Megawati and Wahid (1997–2003), (2) the introduction of social assistance programmes under President Susilo Bambang Yudhoyono, also known as SBY (2004–13) and (3) the most recent reforms under President Joko Widodo, also known as Jokowi (2014–15). The success of these reforms will be examined through several angles: the durability of the reforms, the economic effectiveness in reducing the amount of government expenditures to fossil fuel subsidies and the ability of the reforms to increase state revenue and improve the overall distribution of socio-economic benefits.

This case study of Indonesia examines how domestic political actors influence the outcomes of macroeconomic factors in determining the relative success of fuel subsidy reforms. This chapter observes how ideas and norms surrounding fuel subsidy reform have changed over the three periods of analysis. Using qualitative analysis, and adopting a political economy approach, this chapter looks at the factors of external crisis, political leadership and strong communication campaigns and social assistance and evaluates them across three periods of reforms using process tracing (Checkel Reference Checkel2006; Collier Reference Collier2011). Data were collected from primary and secondary documents, field research and semi-structured interviews.Footnote 1

11.2 Drivers of Successful Fossil Fuel Subsidy Reform

According to the International Energy Agency (IEA), Indonesia allocated approximately 64 trillion Indonesian rupiah (IDR) (USD 5 billion) in its 2016 budget, compared to IDR 240 trillion (USD 19.3 billion) in 2014 (IEA 2016). The IEA estimates that only 5 per cent of the poorest third of Indonesian households benefit from this budget or consume subsidised fuel; by contrast, 70 per cent of the wealthiest top third of households consume subsidised fuels.

In their joint report for the Group of 20 (G20) on the phase-out of fossil fuel subsidies, the IEA, the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) and the World Bank define an energy subsidy as ‘any government action that lowers the cost of energy production, raises the revenues of energy producers, or lowers the price paid by energy consumers’ (IEA et al. 2009: 5). This chapter will use this definition and hence only focus on policies that have an impact on fossil fuel prices (see also Chapter 2). Fossil fuel subsidies can be further broken down into production and consumption subsidies; this chapter focuses on the latter because it is the most politically significant kind of subsidy in Indonesia. In Indonesia, fossil fuel subsidies encourage energy consumption with cheap energy prices, distort energy markets, provide an opportunity for fuel smuggling and produce macroeconomic instability exacerbated by volatility in the currency exchange rates and global oil market (World Bank 2009; HSKIP 2013: 78–79; Bridle and Kitson Reference Bridle and Kitson2014; GSI 2014). Indonesia allocated subsidies to electricity and a range of fuels, including liquefied petroleum gas (LPG), kerosene, automotive diesel and gasoline.

It is important to distinguish between what qualifies as political reform and what drives successful reform. Hill (Reference Hill2013: 109) defines ‘successful reform’ as ‘durable and significant policy change that improves aggregate socioeconomic welfare, consistent also with an objective function that recognises distributional and environmental considerations’. ‘Durable’ implies that reforms are socially and politically acceptable or are not overturned by major political backlash.

The political economy literature has outlined several drivers of the degree of success of political reform or the decision to undertake such reform (see also Chapters 1 and 3). Macroeconomic factors such as economic crises and other kinds of crises provide the need and urgency to initiate required reforms that may be unpopular in stable economic times (Drazen and Grilli Reference Drazen and Grilli1993; Aswicahyono et al. Reference Aswicahyono, Bird and Hill2009; Hill Reference Hill2013). The role of public support for reforms – e.g. from community groups, industry associations and students – is important in determining the durability of political reforms (Basri and Hill Reference Basri and Hill2004). Agency in the shape of political leadership, informed by technical advisors, is important for building support for reforms, leading communication campaigns or persuading and incentivising diverging political interests to reach consensus (Hill Reference Hill2013; Wenzelburger and Horisch Reference Wenzelburger and Horisch2016). Political commitment to reform helps to mobilise action and enhances credibility and transparency for the changes (Garcia Villarreal Reference García Villarreal2010). Strategic communication campaigns that explain reforms and the policies for reducing negative impacts are an important element of successful reform, providing knowledge to ensure that the economic logic of the reforms is better understood by those most affected (Indriyanto et al. Reference Indriyanto, Lontah, Pusakantara, Siahaan and Vis-Dunbar2013; Pradiptyo et al. Reference Pradiptyo, Wirotomo, Adisasmita and Permana2015). This chapter aims to illuminate the political and economic factors that contributed to successful reform of fossil fuel subsidies in Indonesia.

The trouble with fossil fuel subsidy reform in Indonesia is that subsidies were originally implemented for poverty reduction purposes, yet they did not reach their targeted population. The World Bank found that for 2012, nearly 40 per cent of fuel subsidies went to the richest 10 per cent of households and less than 1 per cent went to the poorest 10 per cent, which makes fuel subsidies essentially ‘generous transfers of taxpayer money to the rich’ (Diop Reference Diop2014: 4). Indonesia’s fuel subsidies mainly covered transportation fuels, which largely benefited middle- to upper-class households that can afford vehicles (HKSIP 2013). Yet indirect impacts of fuel subsidy reforms negatively affected poor populations, since the increase in fuel prices created headline inflation, raising the overall cost of consumer goods and subsequent cost of living; this affects all consumers but hits the poor populations the hardest (Guillaume et al. Reference Guillaume, Zytek and Farzin2011; Beaton et al. Reference Beaton, Gerasimchuk and Laan2013; ADB 2015; Casier and Beaton Reference Casier and Beaton2015). Therefore, social assistance programmes were seen as a way to provide a cushion to the most vulnerable households against the indirect impacts of reforms. This is an important point in the case of Indonesia because it differs from other countries, where the populations directly affected by reforms receive compensation such as tax breaks or assistance through direct deposits into specific household or business bank accounts, as in the cases of India (see Chapter 12) and Iran (Guillaume et al. Reference Guillaume, Zytek and Farzin2011).

11.3 Political Economy of Fossil Fuel Subsidies in Indonesia

For the purpose of this chapter, fuel subsidy reform will be operationalised as the change in fuel prices to improve fiscal balances. However, the complete reform of these fossil fuel subsidies that are fixed below market prices requires the removal of price controls so that domestic fuel prices reflect global oil prices. A successful reform involves the achievement of socio-economic benefits as well as distributional considerations (Hill Reference Hill2013). Success is defined by the ability of the government to raise energy prices without overwhelming public protest, and to achieve economic objectives such as reducing government expenditures on subsidies and/or improving aggregate socio-economic welfare and development. In the case of Indonesia, this involves the reduction of budgetary deficits (Aldy Reference Aldy, Greenstone, Harris, Li, Looney and Patashnik2013), the redistribution of the budget to economic development and a buffer for poor populations affected by the negative externalities of fossil fuel subsidy reform (i.e. inflation and the rise in costs of consumer goods). While this buffer helps influence the social acceptability of reforms, it is arguably intertwined with what makes a reform durable. This section explores the case-study background and political economy of fuel subsidy reform in Indonesia.

11.3.1 Fossil Fuel Subsidies in Indonesia

Fossil fuel subsidies have had a major impact on Indonesia’s energy policy, development and overall economic health – but not in the way the government intended. Following the 1973 oil crisis, Indonesia benefited from rising global oil prices and domestic production. As Indonesia became a member of the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries and a major producer in the mid-1960s, the government began subsidising fossil fuels for domestic consumption to alleviate poverty, to reduce the impacts of inflation and as a basic public service obligation underlined in the Constitution (GOI 1945). Oil exports fuelled an economic boom throughout the 1980s and 1990s, but mismanagement, overproduction and corruption led to long-lasting negative impacts. One of the most significant impacts is Indonesia’s transition from a net oil exporter to net importer in 2004 due to decades of mismanagement and lack of investment in the oil sector; this change meant the government began subsidising imported fuels, a policy that quickly became economically unsustainable when combined with dramatic increases in domestic energy demands. Subsidies consumed up to 24 per cent of government expenditure and contributed to ongoing energy crises caused by insufficient supply, growing demand and much-needed infrastructure investment (HKSIP 2013). These challenges put pressure on the Indonesian government to prioritise energy diversification, reduce subsidies and raise fuel prices. Table 11.1 provides an overview of the history of fossil fuel subsidy reforms in Indonesia from 1997 to 2016.

Table 11.1 Timeline of fossil fuel subsidy reforms in Indonesia

DatePricing reform
1997Following the Asian financial crisis, government increased kerosene, diesel and gasoline prices by 2, 60 and 71 per cent, respectively.
2000Kerosene, diesel and gasoline prices were raised for households despite violent demonstrations.
2001Kerosene, diesel and gasoline prices were raised for industry.
2003An attempt was made to link movements in domestic fuel prices and international prices.
2005Prices increased by 29 per cent in March and 114 per cent in October. Industry was no longer eligible to access subsidised diesel.
2006Prices increased for industrial users.
2007Introduction of kerosene-to-LPG conversion programme encouraged LPG use, and the kerosene subsidy was phased out.
2008Prices increased in May of 33 per cent for gasoline, 28 per cent for diesel and 25 per cent for kerosene. Gasoline and diesel prices were lowered in December by 20 and 15 per cent, respectively, as international oil prices eased.
2009Prices lowered in January by 11 per cent for gasoline and 7 per cent for diesel, leaving gasoline prices the same as diesel prices (close to 2005 levels).
2013One-off price increase averaged 40 per cent.
2013Base tariff increased by 15 per cent over 2013 (households consuming more than 450 to 900 volt-amperes were not included).
January 2014An attempt was made to raise prices of 12-kilogram cylinders, but the price increase was rolled back.
November 2014Government initiated price increases of 31 per cent for gasoline and 36 per cent for diesel.
January 2015Subsidies for gasoline were entirely removed, but low oil prices result in a price decline of 12 per cent. Diesel subsidies reduced to IDR 1,000 per litre.
2016Diesel subsidy was removed.
(Sources: Beaton and Lontoh Reference Beaton and Lontoh2010; IMF 2013; ADB 2015; IEA 2016; Kojima Reference Kojima2016.)
11.3.2 Political Economy of Fuel Subsidy Reform and Actor Constellations

Indonesia’s political economy and governance capacity – to implement reforms, address corruption and clientelism and achieve economic development – provide the foundation that underlies the history of fuel subsidy reform in the country. The politics of fossil fuel subsidy reform are intertwined with Indonesia’s history of oil production, whereby the government redistributed wealth earned from oil revenues through subsidies to reduce poverty (IEA 2016). The public acceptability of the reforms is therefore interlinked with the belief that the public is entitled to a redistribution of wealth from the production of national resources, national patrimony through subsidies or government compensation for increasing fuel and commodity prices through other forms of social assistance (Lockwood Reference Lockwood2015). Throughout the periods examined in this chapter, the government of Indonesia’s provision of either subsidies or social assistance as a complement to fuel subsidy reform is used to increase political support for the government rather than provide development and poverty alleviation.

The political economy of fossil fuel subsidy reforms provides insights into the various special interest groups that benefit from fuel subsidies and may challenge or create obstacles to subsidy reform. One of the sizeable interest groups in the Indonesian middle class that has an interest in maintaining subsidised fuel increases is owners of motorbikes or scooters (referred to as ojeks in Bahasa). There are an estimated 76 million scooters in Indonesia, which is approximately one scooter for every three people (Schlogl and Sumner Reference Schlogl and Sumner2014). Indonesia is strongly reliant on private transportation, and the government has systemically promoted motorbike ownership through substantial subsidies for transportation fuels, underinvestment in public transportation or rail systems and ‘public-sector hostility to non-motorized modes of transportation’ (Hook and Repogle Reference Hook and Replogle1996: 80). The motorbike owners who benefit from subsidised fuels have vested interests in maintaining subsidies and have actively opposed and protested fuel price hikes, although their opposition has been manipulated by political parties to protest subsidy reform.

Vested interests in industries that benefit most from subsidised fuels – such as the state-owned oil company Pertamina, the Indonesian oil-trading lobby, vehicle manufacturers and distributors and freight and public transport – remain opposed or ambivalent towards reforms and have lobbied intensively against them (IEA 2016). Pertamina’s interest in maintaining the fuel subsidies relates to the company’s inability to compete effectively in the downstream market due to insufficient investment in the company’s refining capacity, as well as a reliance on the certainty of continued subsidies. According to the IEA (2016: 72), Pertamina’s management has indicated that liberalisation of the fuels market would probably need to be accompanied by some protection for the company. In other words, according to Pertamina management, a clear timeframe for reform would have to be accompanied by greater public investment in upgrading Pertamina’s refining capacity. Other vested interests include vehicle manufacturers – who are closely engaged with the Ministry of Industry – that have an interest in maintaining the supply and demand for vehicles, which run on low-octane fuels, such as the subsidised RON88 fuels (IEA 2016). Transitioning out subsidised low-octane fuels would require an upgrade of vehicles to run on non-subsidised fuels.

Indonesia’s history of oil production and fossil fuel subsidies has created the country’s ‘oil and gas mafia’, known for its corruption, including embezzlement of funds from the Ministry of Energy, extortion, tax fraud and smuggling (Cassin Reference Cassin2014; Sukoyo Reference Sukoyo2014). One of the issues is the black market created by subsidised fuels – cheap, subsidised oil is smuggled and sold at below-market prices for a profit – to businesses or consumers who are not eligible for the subsidy or need more than their quota. Fuel smuggling contributes to distorted fuel prices and is a frequent negative externality of fossil fuel subsidies (Sdralevich et al. Reference Sdralevich, Sab, Zouhar and Albertin2014).

These vested interests and overarching macroeconomic factors have affected decisions taken on the reform of fossil fuel subsidies. The next sections delve into the historical perspective of the aftermath of the Asian financial crisis in 1997, when the first attempt to reform subsidies was implemented. They then examine SBY’s reforms and the introduction of social assistance, as well as more recent reforms under President Jokowi. Socio-economic and macroeconomic factors play an important role in the durability of these reforms.

11.4 Policy Tools for Navigating Macroeconomic Factors
11.4.1 Managing the Asian Financial Crisis

In the six months following the Asian financial crisis between July 1997 and January 1998, the rupiah collapsed from 2,500 against the USD to nearly 10,000, dramatically increasing prices and halting imports (Pisani Reference Pisani2014: 47). To abate the financial crisis, President Suharto committed to a 50-point agreement with the International Monetary Fund (IMF) to qualify for an emergency loan (Beaton and Lontoh Reference Beaton and Lontoh2010; IMF 2013). Some of the points included dismantling state and private monopolies and cutting subsidies of basic commodities, including fossil fuels. While the IMF package envisioned a gradual phase-out of subsidies between 1998 and 1999, the government dramatically raised prices on kerosene (25 per cent), diesel (60 per cent) and gasoline (71 per cent) in May 1998, prior to the first IMF loan disbursement meeting (Beaton and Lontoh Reference Beaton and Lontoh2010). The government pursued severe austerity and dramatic increases in fuel prices, creating inflation, without adequate buffers for the public or vulnerable populations, demonstrating the urgency in reducing government expenditures.

The result was disastrous. Student groups in cities across Indonesia went to the streets in protest of rising prices, which they deemed as resulting from corruption. The subsidy reform and fuel price increases were the tipping point in discontent with the rampant corruption under Suharto’s regime. For three months, protestors demanded the resignation of Suharto and eventually occupied Parliament. Suharto resigned and handed power to his vice president, B.J. Habibie, in May 1998 (Mydans Reference Mydans1998). The new government had a steep agenda, as the economy was in a state of freefall with high inflation, food shortages, bankruptcies and economic paralysis due to the rupiah’s dramatic depreciation. Nearly all subsequent attempts to reform subsidies by Presidents Wahid and Sukarnoputri (Megawati) between 2000 and 2003 resulted in violent demonstrations as students and the public felt that the price increases were linked to powerful interest groups (Bacon and Kojima Reference Bacon and Kojima2006; Beaton and Lontoh Reference Beaton and Lontoh2010). The government promised to use budget savings to help low-income households, but in reality, subsidies for rice and education were low in this period, and many compensation programmes did not materialise (Bacon and Kojima Reference Bacon and Kojima2006; Beaton and Lontoh Reference Beaton and Lontoh2010).

During this period, the external shock of the Asian financial crisis and the conditionality attached to the IMF stabilisation loan were the major factors driving the adoption of fossil fuel subsidy reform. However, despite the fact that the economic crisis was important in creating the urgency for reforms, it was unsuccessful in shifting fuel subsidy reform to ‘low politics’; the problems with corruption of the government surrounding this period were too severe for reforms to be disassociated from the dissatisfaction with the political system. The legacy of corruption and lack of governance capacity had left the public in outrage. Nevertheless, the fossil fuel subsidies became a symbol of oil wealth redistribution, particularly in the absence of adequate policies to reinvest oil welfare in infrastructure development or social welfare programmes. Subsidy reform therefore represented to the public further failures of the government and its ongoing corruption. Lastly, there was an absence of social assistance or political leadership adequately explaining reforms during this period, which further demonstrated the poor implementation of reforms and lack of governance capacity.

11.4.2 Yudhoyono and the Beginning of Social Welfare Politics

As Indonesia grappled with the damage of the Asian financial crisis, the second period (2004–13) marked the beginning of a shift in Indonesian energy policy, whereby the need to reform subsidies overrode the lack of political favourability for reform. In this period, the Indonesian government began initiating a social welfare system to compensate poor populations for the indirect economic burden of subsidy reforms. These programmes were important in shifting popular opinion in favour of subsidy reform, which helped make substantial price changes possible.

In 2004, Susilo Bambang Yudhoyono was elected as the Indonesian president in the same year that Indonesia shifted from a net oil exporter to a net oil importer. The government’s subsidies on imported fuels had a disastrous impact on the budget and energy security; it exposed the government budget to major fluctuations in prices on the international market, to tariff barriers and to potential geopolitical vulnerabilities with security of supply. Spending on fossil fuel subsidies for gasoline, diesel and kerosene rose to USD 8 billion (out of total government expenditures of USD 374 billion; Beaton and Lontoh Reference Beaton and Lontoh2010: 8; World Bank 2017a). The SBY government was forced to remove fuel subsidies to alleviate the budget deficit (Interview 1). Fuel prices were increased in March by 29 per cent and then in October 2005 by 114 per cent, which reduced the deficit by USD 4.5 billion and then USD 10 billion, respectively (Beaton and Lontoh Reference Beaton and Lontoh2010).Footnote 2 This reform was politically possible – without major backlash from the public – arguably because of the introduction of social assistance programmes. These types of programmes not only provide a buffer for the resulting economic shocks from fuel prices increases, but they also provide credibility for the government’s commitment to social welfare (Perdana Reference Perdana2014).

The provision of social assistance also illustrates the government of Indonesia’s prioritisation of poverty alleviation and its shift towards a welfare state. In the early 2000s, in the post-Suharto era, the government became increasingly accountable to the public, and candidates in local and national elections promised ambitious social welfare assistance for education, poverty reduction and healthcare (Aspinall Reference Aspinall2013: 114). Social assistance became a salient issue in politics. SBY’s tremendous public support can be attributed to heavy investment in social programmes, which improved his poll figures (Mietzner Reference Mietzner2009). To overcome the political challenges of subsidy reform and to alleviate the burden of price increases on the poor, SBY’s administration started to provide cash-transfer and compensation programmes, including clean cookstove dispersals for kerosene-to-LPG conversion, and it increased spending on health, education and social welfare (Budya and Arofat Reference Budya and Arofat2011; World Bank 2013).

While this period showed the positive impacts of social welfare in shifting the political support for subsidy reform, increasing global oil prices also limited the fiscal impacts of fuel subsidy reforms. For example, in 2008 and 2011, when oil prices breached USD 100 per barrel, the fiscal burden of energy subsidies rose as well. In response to high oil prices, Indonesia attempted to initiate energy subsidy reforms and raise prices. In May 2008, the Indonesian government raised prices of diesel and kerosene and then lowered prices of diesel by 12 per cent, when international oil prices decreased (Beaton and Lontoh Reference Beaton and Lontoh2010; IMF 2013; ADB 2015). Although an unconditional cash transfer, a ‘rice for the poor’ programme and a loan-interest subsidy for small enterprises were dispersed through social assistance programmes, the fluctuations in oil prices were too volatile and affected prices at the pump; the subsidy reform was repealed (Figure 11.1).

Figure 11.1 Indonesia fuel prices compared to international oil market prices

(Sources: EIA 2017; World Bank 2017b.)

These reforms illustrated the importance of political leadership with strong communication campaigns and social assistance programmes as a buffer against the indirect effects of fuel subsidy reform. However, the government had not incorporated a buffer to reduce the overall impacts of international oil price fluctuations on the population, meaning the continued cycle of fossil fuel subsidy reforms, price shocks and public unrest necessitated social assistance programmes or the repeal of subsidies. To fully remove subsidies and price controls, better implementation of subsidy reform coupled with buffers and the reinvestment of the subsidies budget in development was still needed.

11.4.3 Oil Market Fluctuations and Widodo’s Subsidy Reform Policy

Energy subsidies on imported fuels leave fiscal policy vulnerable to fluctuations in global oil prices as well as currency exchange markets. A weakening of the rupiah means a higher price of energy products on the domestic market and subsequently a higher share of subsidies if domestic prices are not adjusted (Diop Reference Diop2014: 2). This was evident in the 2008 financial crisis, when the Indonesian rupiah lost 28 per cent of its value against the dollar between October and November 2008 (Basri and Rahardja Reference Basri, Rahardja, Ito and Parulian2011). Figures 11.1 and 11.2 show the response of the Indonesian government to volatility in the oil market through subsidisation.

Figure 11.2 Fuel subsidies in Indonesia (2006–15)

(Source: Prawiraatmadja Reference Prawiraatmadja2015.)

The Jokowi administration implemented its last series of reforms in 2014, under the rhetoric of the need to reallocate public finances towards infrastructure investment; the aim was to let domestic fuel prices follow the global oil market and to remove price controls (Interviews 2 and 3). In the lead-up to the implementation, the Ministry of Energy created the Oil and Gas Task Force to reform the oil and gas sector and reduce corruption, particularly within Pertamina. Faisal Basri was appointed as the head of the Task Force, and the technocratic team was made up of 11 members, including ministers, academics, bureaucrats and activists (Sipahutar Reference Sipahutar2014; Interview 4). The Task Force made the following recommendations for reforms in the oil and gas sector: the dissolution of Petral (Pertamina’s oil trading arm), the creation of the integrated supply chain unit within Pertamina to take over procurement of crude oil and petroleum products from Petral, a gradual fossil fuel subsidy phase-out with a social welfare programme, the creation of a buffer to better manage price fluctuations and more efficiency from upstream petroleum regulator SKK Migas (Cahyafitri Reference Cahyfitri2015; Interview 4). Fossil fuel subsidy reform would also be the most effective way to deal with the oil smuggling if domestic fuel prices matched international prices, as this would remove the incentive to smuggle fuels. Many of the recommendations of the Task Force were put in place, including the removal of gasoline subsidies from the budget (which de facto transferred the budget to pay off debts to Pertamina), the dissolution of Petral, increases in gasoline and diesel prices and other changes to address corruption in the oil and gas sector.

The major opposition to subsidy reform during this period was launched by Prabowo Subianto – Jokowi’s competitor in the 2014 elections and the son-in-law of Suharto (Kapoor Reference Kapoor2014). His ‘Red-White coalition’ opposes fuel subsidy reforms with a misleading argument that reforms are unnecessary in light of low oil market prices and the assertion that reforms will increase poverty (Wikipdr 2014). However, their opposition is likely linked to corruption and vested interests from the old so-called corruption, collusion and nepotism regime (commonly known as the ‘KKN’ regime) under Suharto (The Economist 2014).

The plans to fully reform fossil fuel subsidies in Indonesia preceded the crash of the global oil market in 2015. Scholars argued this was the best moment to implement the reforms because price shocks would be low (Benes et al. Reference Benes, Cheon, Urpelainen and Yang2015). The price for oil dropped to USD 30 per barrel in August 2015 but then rebounded to USD 49 per barrel in October 2016; in parallel, gas price fell from USD 400 to USD 318 per metric ton in June 2016, opening up the window for LPG subsidies reform (Lontoh and Toft Reference Lontoh and Toft2016). Furthermore, in 2015, the Indonesian rupiah depreciated to levels not seen since the Asian financial crisis, but then the currency rebounded in 2016 to IDR 13,271 against the USD from IDR 14,000/USD 1 (Nangoy and Suroyo Reference Nangoy and Suroyo2015; Lontoh and Toft Reference Lontoh and Toft2016).

The macroeconomic fluctuations have not led to dramatic changes in the subsidies policy in the budget, but there are changes in who bears the cost of subsidy policy and the transparency of the policy. Since the removal of subsidies was already signed into law in 2015, the 2016 budget did not include a budget line for gasoline subsidies, but it kept subsidies for 3-kilogram LPG tanks, diesel and new and renewable energy; a fixed diesel subsidy of IDR 1,000 per litre had a dramatic change in managing diesel subsidies (APBN 2016; Interviews 2 and 5). Between January and March 2015, the government implemented a series of prices changes, mainly decreasing domestic consumer prices in line with lower market prices. However, when international market prices increased, a price gap was created. The financial burden of the subsidies’ price gap was transferred to Pertamina, covering the difference from the production costs and market price of oil, which amounted to USD 1 billion (IDR 15 trillion; Otto Reference Otto2015; Samboh and Cahyafitri Reference Samboh and Cahyafitri2015; Witular Reference Witular2015). This was not a formal policy but rather seen as a response to the transitional period while the government continued to apply the three-month price adjustments (Interview 6). The government informally compensated Pertamina by keeping pump prices the same when global oil prices fell to account for price gaps and Pertamina’s deficit (Interview 6). While the long-term plan to peg the domestic pump prices to international prices will ameliorate this issue, there is still a great deal of policy support needed to make this transition. Stronger fiscal policy combined with investment in infrastructure and directed social assistance is still needed to successfully remove price controls and ensure the permanent reform of fossil fuel subsidies in Indonesia.

11.5 Drivers of Successful Reform of Indonesia’s Fossil Fuel Subsidies

From Suharto to SBY to Jokowi, the evolution of fossil fuel subsidy reform policies across the three periods of analysis help determine the factors contributing to the success and durability of reforms. The relevant drivers of successful fuel subsidy reforms in the case of Indonesia were agents actively promoting or opposing fossil fuel subsidy reform, as well as strategies comprising the provision of social assistance, political leadership and the framing of such reform. Macroeconomic factors, more precisely external crises, were also important influences in the success of fossil fuel subsidy reforms. The analysis that follows will discuss each factor in turn.

The largest factor influencing reforms in the case of Indonesia has been macroeconomic factors creating economic crises in Indonesia. Volatility in the oil market and currency exchange rates – as well as other external economic shocks – have had an enormous impact in driving fuel subsidy reforms in Indonesia. Macroeconomic factors included the Asian financial crisis, the shift of Indonesia from a net exporter of oil to a net importer in 2004, the 2008 global recession and increase in global oil prices and the depreciation of the rupiah in 2014. These external shocks have created economic crises and massive budget deficits in Indonesia because of subsidies on (especially imported) fuels. The shocks have driven the government of Indonesia to implement significant fuel subsidy reforms, even when they were extremely unpopular. While external shocks have played a large role in driving reforms, they also mitigate the effectiveness of reforms in general. Until the price controls are removed, fiscal policy will remain vulnerable to volatility in the oil and currency markets, creating pressure for increasing or reintroducing subsidies.

The provision of social assistance as a buffer to poor populations against the negative consequences of fuel subsidy reform is the most important factor in the success of reforms and can be considered a necessary condition. Social assistance became increasingly salient in political campaigns and has influenced the expectations of the public towards the provision of public goods by the government. While developmental states typically have a centralised policy of wealth redistribution and poverty alleviation, Indonesia’s fossil fuel subsidies can be viewed as an informal policy of ‘rent’ redistribution in exchange for political support (Khan Reference Khan, Khan and Jomo2000; Lockwood Reference Lockwood2015). The introduction of social welfare effectively reduced public protest to reforms by addressing the needs of the poor populations most impacted by the negative externalities of increased fuel prices. While social assistance provided a buffer against the impacts of the rise in fuel prices on the poorest populations in the short term, a long-term development strategy is needed to maintain macroeconomic stability.

Political leadership and strategic communication campaigns that increase the public’s knowledge of subsidy reforms are also necessary conditions for durable reforms. The political capital of SBY grew tremendously in 2006 and 2009 after the generous provisions of social assistance to compensate for fuel price increases. Likewise, Jokowi’s political leadership and agency in shifting the discourse of subsidy reforms to generate support and political backing was quite successful overall. In terms of economic effectiveness, some of the subsidy reforms have been more successful than others in relieving budgetary crises over deficits, which is mainly determined by the currency exchange rates and the prices of the oil market. The social acceptability and durability of the 2005–7 and 2013–15 reforms, combined with the alleviation of budgetary crises, make these two series of reforms the most successful. Many of the implemented reforms that were eventually retracted were still successful in temporarily relieving budgetary pressure by reducing government expenditures.

Overall, the leadership of reforms that combined social assistance and strategic communications lent legitimacy to the Indonesian government and generated support for the historically politically unpopular reforms. The last period of reforms under Jokowi demonstrated the success in shifting norms and ideas that previously depicted fuel subsidy reform as government corruption and inequitable wealth redistribution; such reforms are now seen as credible and necessary for fostering economic development through a focus on investment in infrastructure as a road to growth. Moving forward, there is still a need to further depoliticise fuel subsidy reforms and how fuel prices are set, which will require institutional reform in the government ministries that currently handle subsidy reforms.

11.6 Conclusion

Using a qualitative case-study analysis of fossil fuel subsidy reforms in Indonesia between the Asian financial crisis and recent reforms in 2015, this chapter investigated the factors that made successful, durable reform of fossil fuel subsidies possible. The major factors investigated were external shocks or economic crises, political leadership for reform, communication campaigns and social assistance. The analysis found that macroeconomic fluctuations leading to economic crises overwhelmingly drove reforms, but strong political leadership, strategic communication and social assistance were the most critical factors in facilitating durable reform in Indonesia – representing decisive political and economic policy choices. Two series of fuel subsidy reforms in Indonesia, first between 2005 and 2007 and then again between 2013 and 2015, were the most successful reforms because they achieved both social acceptability and economic objectives of alleviating government expenditures on fuel subsidies.

Indonesia’s history of fuel subsidy reforms offers insight into the tensions between political leadership for fuel subsidy reforms and vested interests in maintaining the status quo. The case study demonstrates that the domestic political drivers of successful and durable fuel subsidy reform determine the ultimate influence of macroeconomic factors such as financial crises and oil market volatility. The success of particular fuel subsidy reforms, particularly during periods of economic crisis, were influenced by the Indonesian government’s strong leadership in fostering support and lending credibility to politically unpopular energy price increases. The success in political leadership can be attributed in large part to the provision of social assistance and strategic communication of these programmes to the public.

Acknowledgements

The author gratefully acknowledges the generous support of the Swiss Network for International Studies, INOGOV, Graduate Institute Centre for International Environmental Studies, Swiss National Science Foundation and Harvard Kennedy School, which helped make this research possible. The author would also like to thank Henry Lee, Joe Aldy, Liliana Andonova and anonymous reviewers for their helpful comments.

12 Lessons from the World’s Largest Subsidy Benefit Transfer Scheme The Case of Liquefied Petroleum Gas Subsidy Reform in India

Abhishek Jain , Shalu Agrawal and Karthik Ganesan
12.1 Introduction

Consumer energy subsidies in developing countries are used in lieu of social security nets, aimed at shielding poor consumers from price shocks (Grubb et al. Reference Grubb, Hourcade and Neuhoff2014). However, energy subsidies are fiscally burdensome, crowd out social spending, disproportionately benefit richer people, distort energy markets and engender higher greenhouse gas emissions (Savatic Reference Savatic2016). Yet, reforming fossil fuel subsidies has been politically as well as administratively challenging. Several developing countries have made unsuccessful attempts at energy price reforms, sometimes with politically disastrous consequences (Salehi-Isfahani et al. Reference Salehi-Isfahani, Stucki and Deutschmann2015).

In view of the rising subsidy burden, the Indian government has undertaken a series of fossil fuel subsidy reforms over the last few years. For instance, the government successfully deregulated gasoline and diesel prices in June 2010 and October 2014, respectively (Ganguly and Das Reference Ganguly and Das2016). In 2012, to contain the subsidies for liquefied petroleum gas (LPG), the predominant ‘clean’ cooking fuel in India, the government restricted the subsidy benefit to six LPG cylinders (14.2 kilograms each) per household, which was subsequently raised to 12 due to political pressure (Nag Reference Nag2014).Footnote 1 Prior to 2012, there was no limit on the amount of subsidised LPG that a household could consume.

Reforming cooking fuel subsidies is particularly challenging due to opposition from poor households, as energy costs form a significant share of their expenditure budgets, even though they benefit disproportionately less than wealthier households (Savatic Reference Savatic2016). In 2013, the government of India introduced the Direct Benefit Transfer Scheme for LPG (DBTL scheme), a conditional cash-transfer scheme.

While cash transfers are a popular means of social assistance in developing countries, few countries have used them in the context of energy subsidies reform. In 2005 and 2014, the government of Indonesia implemented an unconditional but targeted cash-transfer programme to compensate poor families against fuel price rise (Savatic Reference Savatic2016; see Chapter 6). Iran implemented a uniform cash-transfer scheme in tandem with an energy price hike in 2010 to cushion its poor population and make the reform politically feasible (Salehi-Isfahani et al. Reference Salehi-Isfahani, Stucki and Deutschmann2015).

In the context of the global discourse on fossil fuel subsidy reform, the DBTL scheme is an interesting reform to look into for various reasons. First, unlike the conventional reforms for reducing the fossil fuel subsidy, the DBTL scheme focuses on improving the efficiency of the subsidy delivery mechanism to decrease the leakage of the subsidised commodity to unintended users and uses. Second, the DBTL scheme provides a platform for the government to selectively target the subsidy to specific groups of beneficiaries, instead of providing it universally (as was the case before it was introduced). Third, the sheer scale of the DBTL scheme, which covered about 139 million households in October 2015Footnote 2 – making it the largest benefit-transfer scheme in the world (MoPNG 2015e) – calls for its assessment, particularly because no comprehensive analysis currently exists.

This chapter presents the results of a performance evaluation of the DBTL scheme. It seeks to draw lessons from the overall experience of the scheme, focusing on the following three key questions: (1) How successful was the implementation process of the scheme, and what were the gaps in implementation, if any? (2) How successful was the scheme in achieving its stated objectives? (3) Why did the DBTL scheme achieve this degree of success? In answering these questions, we specifically focus on the key actors and stakeholder groups involved or affected by the scheme and on the strategies employed by each to design and administer the scheme as well as to overcome the challenges encountered during the scheme’s implementation.

The chapter begins with an overview of challenges associated with the LPG subsidy programme in India and the DBTL scheme. It then discusses the methodology adopted for the evaluation. Next, we discuss the results, focusing on efficacy of the implementation process, success of the DBTL scheme in achieving its stated objectives and the factors that made DBTL scheme implementation a success. We conclude with key lessons for fossil fuel subsidy reform processes for other countries while highlighting the next steps for DBTL scheme reform.

12.2 The LPG Subsidy and the DBTL Scheme in India

Several issues afflicting the LPG subsidy programme in India have been highlighted in the literature. These include (1) a rising subsidy burden, (2) a skewed distribution of the LPG subsidy (and of consumption) among urban versus rural areas and across income classes, (3) the diversion/leakage of subsidised LPG for unintended purposes,Footnote 3 (4) ownership of multiple connections by several households and (5) fake or ‘ghost’ connectionsFootnote 4 (Morris and Pandey Reference Morris and Pandey2006; Lang and Wooders Reference Lang and Wooders2012; Soni et al. Reference Soni, Chaterjee and Bandhopadhyay2012; MoPNG 2013; Clarke et al. 2014; Clarke and Sharma Reference Clarke and Sharma2014; Docherty Reference Docherty2014; Jain et al. Reference Jain, Agrawal and Ganesan2014). To address some of the challenges, these studies have proposed diverse reforms ranging from reducing the subsidy amount and imposing a realistic cap on a subsidised commodity (for each household) to implementing a direct cash transfer and targeting the beneficiaries.

To curb the diversion of subsidised LPG for unintended purposes and to ensure that the households received their subsidies, the government of India introduced the DBTL scheme. The scheme aimed to reduce leakages by achieving a common market price for LPG and by channelling the consumption-linked subsidy directly to the bank accounts of LPG consumers (MoPNG 2013). Under the scheme, households buy LPG at the market price (instead of the subsidised price) and receive the subsidy directly into their bank accounts (following the purchase, for a maximum of 12 cylinders of 14.2 kilograms each per household per year).

This scheme was first launched on 1 June 2013 and subsequently expanded to 291 districts in six phases covering 17 million people (Nag Reference Nag2014). The scheme was successful in curbing the leakages in the LPG distribution system, but it also suffered from numerous consumer grievances due to the speed at which it was rolled out and the requirement that a consumer should have an Aadhaar numberFootnote 5 to receive the subsidy (MoPNG 2014). In view of such issues, the DBTL scheme was suspended in early 2014, and an expert committee was established to review it.

Incorporating the recommendations of the committee, a modified DBTL scheme, also known as PaHaL (Pratyaksha Hastaantarit Laabh), was relaunched in 54 districts in November 2014 and expanded to the rest of the country in January 2015 (MoPNG 2015b). The modified scheme was launched with the following stated objectives (MoPNG 2015b): (1) protecting entitlement and ensuring that the subsidy reaches the consumer, (2) removing incentives for diversion, (3) weeding out fake/duplicate connections and (4) improving the availability/delivery of LPG cylinders for genuine users.

12.3 Methodology and Data Collection

To answer the research questions, we followed a mixed-methods approach that systematically integrates quantitative and qualitative research methods (Bamberger Reference Bamberger2013). Although the DBTL scheme is a pan-India scheme, we focused on three states, namely Gujarat, Haryana and Kerala, to get an in-depth picture of on-the-ground realities. We chose these states to capture diversity on three main criteria: (1) the proportion of households with an LPG connection, (2) the share of LPG consumers enrolled in the DBTL scheme and (3) the proportion of rural households in the state. The selected states also represent three different geographies (south, west and north). Most of the states in the eastern part of the country exhibit a low penetration of LPG and, due to limited resources, could not be included in the study.

For our assessment, we focused on all the key stakeholders involved in the scheme’s implementation, including

  1. 1. The Director (LPG) at the Ministry of Petroleum and Natural Gas (MoPNG) responsible for coordination and implementation of the entire scheme,

  2. 2. National sales heads of each of the three oil marketing companies (OMCs),

  3. 3. Field officers of OMCs supervising LPG distributors at district level,

  4. 4. Lead district managers (LDMs) of lead banks at district level responsible for coordination and implementation of the scheme from the banks’ end, and

  5. 5. LPG distributors who stock and deliver LPG to consumers.

We conducted unstructured in-person interviews of the first two stakeholders and semi-structured telephone interviews of field officers (nine) and LDMs (three). We focused our interview with the Director LPG on national-level challenges that the scheme’s implementation encountered and how the ministry tried to overcome them. We also discussed the details of the implementation strategy that the government followed. Finally, we discussed the roles and responsibilities of the various actors involved, as well as the coordination efforts undertaken between different actors and institutions. In our interviews with national sales heads of OMCs, we focused on operational issues, support and directives received from the ministry, as well as their perspective on findings from consumer and distributor surveys, to add further nuance and context to the findings and validate them. For LPG distributors, we conducted a structured telephone survey of 92 randomly selected distributors to ensure that our findings were representative. The interviews and survey were focused on understanding stakeholders’ perceptions of the adequacy of the support received from other stakeholders, difficulties faced and measures taken to overcome these difficulties during the scheme’s implementation. We used stakeholder perceptions along with the extent of consumer enrolment in the scheme as measures to assess the efficacy of the implementation process.

To assess the scheme’s success in meeting its stated objectives, we conducted a telephone survey of 1,270 randomly selected LPG consumers, proportionate to the market share of the three OMCs in each state. The survey focused on consumer awareness about the scheme’s objectives, ease of enrolment and perceived impact of the scheme on service delivery. Further, since distributors were responsible for enrolling the consumers in the DBTL scheme and directly engaged with them, we also enquired about their perception of the scheme’s impact on customers, diversion of subsidised LPG and fake connections. To validate the results obtained from the survey and stakeholder interviews, and to derive lessons learned from the scheme’s implementation, we supplemented our findings with an analysis of official data (on LPG sales) and secondary data sources, such as government press releases. All the engagements were conducted in May 2015 (see Jain et al. Reference Jain, Agrawal and Ganesan2016 for a detailed methodology).

12.4 Efficacy of the Implementation Process
12.4.1 Status of Consumer Enrolment in the Scheme

Results from the distributor survey indicated an enrolment rate of about 85 per cent, with the highest rate reported in Kerala (87 per cent), followed by Gujarat (85 per cent) and Haryana (81 per cent). The findings correspond well with official data reported by the MoPNG, validating the representativeness of the survey.

However, in the consumer survey, a higher proportion of households (94.6 per cent) reported being enrolled in DBTL. The higher reporting could be partly attributed to those households who had submitted their application and perceived themselves as being enrolled, even though the enrolment process was not yet completed for them. This is reflective of the scheme’s ongoing process but also highlights the lack of information of consumers regarding their state of enrolment.

Households that reported as not being enrolled in the DBTL scheme (5.6 per cent) stated that lack of interest in the subsidy and lack of awareness about the enrolment process were major reasons. Further, rejection of documents by the banks and lack of a bank account were other reasons. Non-enrolment due to a lack of interest indicates the scheme’s potential in weeding out households that do not need the subsidy, a positive externality. This provides an important lesson that instead of providing a subsidy as a default, the government should ask for enrolment to receive subsidy benefits, which can help weed out non-deserving populations to some extent.

Though very few respondents cited the absence of bank accounts as a reason for non-enrolment, it highlights the fact that households without bank accounts could be left out of the scheme and, hence, miss out on the subsidy benefits. The important lesson here is to keep the scheme design inclusive when drafting such reform.

12.4.2 Stakeholder Experiences during the Implementation Process
12.4.2.1 LPG Consumers

We found that a majority (73 per cent) of the enrolled households reported the enrolment process to be ‘easy’; only 2.5 per cent found the process to be ‘difficult’. This indicates that the process was largely smooth. This could be attributed to the constant improvement in the process by the OMCs and innovative approaches adopted by the distributors, among other reasons. For instance, we found out during the field officers’ interviews that distributors in some urban areas of Haryana delivered and collected enrolment forms at the doorsteps of the households through their deliverymen. This indicates the importance of designing the schemes to minimise consumer effort for enrolment, resulting in a positive perception of the process and rapid enrolment.

As per the government procedures for DBTL scheme enrolment, households had to make either two visits (for Aadhaar-based allocation of funds or seeding) or just one visit (for bank seeding). However, we found that 45 per cent of the households made three or more visits to the banks and distributors combined, indicating inefficiency in the implementation process. Despite a certain inefficiency in the process, the majority of customers did not find the enrolment process difficult. Admirably, less than 1 per cent of the households enrolled reported instances of corruption at the hands of distributors or bank officials, indicating a highly transparent process.Footnote 6

12.4.2.2 LPG Distributors

Given the strict timelines for the scheme’s implementation, 88 per cent of the surveyed distributors reported facing one or more challenges during implementation (Figure 12.1). We further found that 75 per cent of distributors reported that the Aadhaar-based seeding process was easier than the bank seeding process. Under the former, distributors have to enter only the Aadhaar number, whereas under the latter, they are required to enter several data fields related to bank account details, which is relatively tedious and error prone. This highlights the importance of simple and easy procedures for ensuring hassle-free programme implementation.

Figure 12.1 Challenges for distributors during the DBTL scheme rollout in India.

(Source: Authors’ analysis of survey data)

Document verification or form submission at banks was reported as the major challenge under both categories. Banks often delayed the verification process and rejected high volumes of applications due to spelling mismatches. This suggests the importance of considering the procedural details and the resulting challenges in order to put contingencies and flexibilities in places. In this case, to meet the scheme’s timeline, the MoPNG directed OMCs and distributors to enrol customers through direct bank seeding, skipping the banks’ verification process in the short run, and later conducted the verification retrospectively.Footnote 7 Although this significantly increased the rate of enrolment, it also led to wrong entries of bank details by the distributors and thus affected the effectiveness of the subsidy-transfer process.

The absence of bank accounts for customers also posed difficulties to the distributors. It put the onus of guiding the customers (about opening new accounts) on the distributors, who had strict timelines to achieve the enrolment targets. Furthermore, about 36 per cent distributors did not find banks to be cooperative in handling and solving the customer complaints. At the national level, the Department of Financial Services (under the Ministry of Finance) was in alignment with the MoPNG to make the DBTL scheme a success and issued two sets of guidelines for banks to prepare themselves for DBTL scheme enrolment. However, it was found that banks were not entirely prepared for effective implementation of the scheme.

Due to delays or non-receipt of the subsidy in bank accounts, distributors had to tackle customers’ subsidy-related queries without sufficient information or capacity. Subsidy-related queries were specifically cited as a major challenge by 22 per cent of the surveyed distributors (see Figure 12.1). This shows the importance of an active communication system not only between implementing agencies but also with the customers to establish trust and empower the implementers.

While distributors reported various difficulties, the majority (87 per cent) acknowledged that the OMCs provided adequate support during the entire process. Based on our interviews with LPG leads, we found that OMCs supported the distributors in terms of both capacity building and financially (for the enrolment process). Field officers played a critical role in training and supervising the distributors.

12.4.2.3 Banking Personnel

Our interviews with LDMs revealed that banks were not well prepared for the scheme’s implementation, even though the Ministry of Finance’s Department of Financial Services issued notifications to the banks to facilitate adequate support. There was a lack of dedicated staffing in the banks for the DBTL scheme, with the responsibility bouncing from one employee to another; this often led to a waste of resources on repetitive capacity building. While the distributors received financial assistance from the OMCs on a per-enrolment basis, banks did not. Furthermore, banks lacked coordination between their headquarters and local branches. For instance, local bank personnel were not informed about the status of Aadhaar seeding when it was delayed at the central level, even though they were responsible for addressing customer enquiries.

The LDMs encountered several problems due to a lack of standardisation of the processes and protocols followed by different banks. For instance, banks were following different protocols to determine whether a joint account could be used for seeding with the LPG account (with or without Aadhaar). Such issues often created hassles for customers, distributors and LDMs.

LDMs also faced difficulties due to lapses in support from the distributors and gaps in information flows to the customers. On multiple occasions, LPG distributors shared LDMs’ contact details with the consumers for any subsidy-related queries. Consequently, LDMs were burdened by such queries, for which they were not responsible; they also did not have the capacity or information to deal with them. Interviews with senior officials at the OMCs and the MoPNG highlighted that the Ministry of Finance worked in close coordination with MoPNG and that towards the later stages, the coordination between banks, field officers and distributors improved significantly.

Overall, the DBTL scheme was well publicised and had fairly wide coverage, with efforts to increase enrolment rates by leveraging other ongoing schemes. While consumers found the scheme’s implementation largely smooth and transparent, distributors and bank personnel encountered several difficulties, particularly due to the short timeframe of implementation. However, its smooth rollout in the short four-month timeframe was facilitated by strong leadership by the OMCs and MoPNG, coordination between different stakeholders and constant improvements in the scheme during implementation.

12.5 Success of the Scheme in Achieving Its Stated Objectives
12.5.1 Effectiveness of Subsidy Disbursal to Consumers

Direct subsidy disbursal into the bank accounts of the beneficiaries was largely successful. Based on the consumer survey, 75 per cent of the households who purchased LPG cylinders after enrolling in the DBTL scheme reported receipt of subsidies in their bank accounts. The share was marginally lower in rural areas (73 per cent).

Notably, a significant proportion (16.6 per cent) of households was unaware of the status of their subsidy receipt, and a substantial share (8.6 per cent) reported non-receipt of subsidies for any cylinder purchased. We found that the issue was the lack of proactive information flows to consumers about their subsidy transfers, which was also confirmed by the findings from the distributor survey. Upon being asked about the main improvement area for the DBTL scheme, a quarter of the surveyed distributors highlighted the need to improve timely delivery of the subsidy as well as the information to consumers. Instances of non-receipt of subsidy were repeatedly cited as an issue by distributors, field officers and LDMs. However, all stakeholders mentioned that the rate of complaints significantly decreased over time.

12.5.2 Impact on Diversion of Cylinders

A majority (85 per cent) of the distributors reported that the scheme had a significant impact on reducing the diversion of cylinders. Our analysis of publicly available sales dataFootnote 8 of non-domestic LPG and auto-LPGFootnote 9 confirmed these findings.

The growth in the sales of non-household-packed LPG has been declining since 2009–10, with a negative growth rate in fiscal year (FY) 2013–14 and FY 2014–15. That began to turn around after November 2014, when the modified DBTL scheme was introduced. Since December 2014, the non-household-packed LPG sales have shown a significant positive growth rate, continuing for FY 2015–16, with an annual growth of 39.3 per cent (Figure 12.2). Such a marked increase in the growth of non-household-packed LPG can be attributed to the DBTL scheme’s impact in constraining the diversion of subsidised LPG from the distributors’ end; lower oil prices also had a partial impact by boosting demand.

Figure 12.2 DBTL scheme’s impact on growth of sales for non-domestic and auto-LPG in India.

(Source: Authors’ analysis based on Petroleum Planning and Analysis Cell data.)

Similarly, the LPG sales for transportation (auto-LPG), which have witnessed a declining growth rate since 2010–11, revived in January 2015 (concurrent to the nationwide launch of the modified DBTL scheme). For FY 2015–16, the overall growth in auto-LPG sales has been 4.3 per cent compared to a negative growth rate of 24.4 per cent in FY 2014–15 (Figure 12.2).

Even though the DBTL scheme has tried to facilitate a uniform market price of household LPG cylinders, there still is a difference between the market price for household and non-household LPG. The difference is due to the different tax structures applicable to household and non-household LPG and could still remain as an incentive to divert household LPG for non-domestic purposes. A reform in LPG taxation would be necessary to ensure entirely uniform pricing and further reduce the diversion of household LPG for unintended uses.

12.5.3 Impact on Eliminating Multiple and Fake Connections

LPG is a regulated commodity in India, and each household is allowed to have only one LPG connection. Duplicate connections, siphoning off subsidised commodities, have been a major challenge in LPG distribution. During the distributors’ survey, 84 per cent of the distributors reported that the scheme had a significant impact on controlling duplicate or multiple connections.

The government of India claims that the DBTL scheme has been able to eliminate close to 33 million ‘ghost’ (fake or duplicate) connections (MoPNG 2015f). All these ghost connections are basically inactive LPG connections (no refills done in the past six months). However, to estimate the extent of the scheme’s impact on controlling multiple connections, it is important to consider the number of inactive connections before the relaunch of the DBTL scheme (i.e. before November 2014).

An inactive connection also might not necessarily mean a ghost or duplicate/multiple connection. An unintentional impact of the DBTL scheme could be the conversion of some genuine LPG consumers into inactive connections, especially those from poorer economic backgrounds who have insufficient cash flows to buy LPG cylinders at the market price.

Under the scheme, the initial subsidy amount is transferred to the household’s bank account in advance to ensure that there is no additional outlay by the consumer while refilling a cylinder at the market price. However, in many rural areas, withdrawing money from the bank could mean losing out on half a day’s salary (as bank branches are far away). Consequently, some poorer LPG consumers might reduce LPG consumption, although our study did not test this hypothesis.

Thus, of the 33 million inactive connections, a significant proportion could be fake or duplicate. However, a more careful assessment is required to estimate the impact of the DBTL scheme in eliminating such connections while acknowledging the possible withdrawal of genuine households away from LPG due to reasons discussed earlier.

12.5.4 Impact on Availability and Delivery of LPG Cylinders

One of the four key objectives of the DBTL scheme was to improve the availability/delivery of LPG cylinders for genuine users. To assess this, we asked consumers about the change in delivery time of the cylinders in the previous two months. More than half the households reported that the timely delivery of cylinders had improved. Another 39 per cent of households reported no change in delivery time, whereas close to 9 per cent felt that the service had deteriorated. Interviews with senior officials at the OMCs suggest that the consumer perception of improved regularity in cylinder delivery could be attributed to the avoidance of collusions at the dealers’ and/or deliverymen’s end as a result of the DBTL scheme.

Overall, we found that the DBTL scheme was fairly successful in achieving its objective of direct transfer of subsidies to consumers, although some gaps remain. The scheme also succeeded in limiting the diversion of subsidised products and eliminating duplicate connections, although the extent of this needs to be carefully evaluated. Finally, the consumer perception of improved timely delivery of LPG cylinders following the scheme’s implementation could also be attributed to the DBTL scheme.

12.6 What Worked for the DBTL Scheme: Lessons Learned

This section discusses and highlights the key factors that led to the successful implementation of the DBTL scheme. It also elaborates on the lessons learned from the scheme’s implementation, which could be useful for designing fossil fuel subsidy reforms in other contexts and countries.

12.6.1 Political Leadership and Framing of the Narrative

We find that strong leadership from the national government was a prime factor behind the successful and smooth implementation of the world’s largest cash-transfer scheme, as it infused a momentum throughout the entire range of actors along the LPG supply chain involved in the implementation process. For instance, the scheme’s implementation was regularly reviewed by the Prime Minister (Prime Minister’s Office 2015) and monitored directly by the Minister of Petroleum and Natural Gas (MoPNG 2015d).

Unlike earlier initiatives for subsidy reforms, the DBTL scheme was implemented without any political backlash due to several factors. The dramatic fall in oil prices played a significant role in allaying public fears of any potential fallouts of the scheme. The government used this opportunity and framed the narrative on subsidy reforms as a measure to plug wasteful leakages and improve service delivery. Customer perception on this front was confirmed in our survey. The narrative was well timed, given popular sentiments against corruption (Sukhtankar and Vaishnav Reference Sukhtankar and Vaishnav2015).

For consumers, the scheme only changed the mode of subsidy disbursal and did not amount to subsidy withdrawal or reduction, which implied that only those accessing subsidies illegally were affected. These include local but unorganised commercial entities, which could not mobilise any opposition. While the LPG consumers who lacked access to banking services, mainly rural poor, might have been adversely affected, these cases were relatively few and diffused, given the low penetration of LPG in rural areas.

Thus, timely recognition of the opportunity for reform, smart framing of the narrative and direct monitoring by the political leadership at the national level were critical to the timely and successful implementation of the DBTL scheme.

12.6.2 Institutional Coordination

The scheme’s implementation involved multiple stakeholders, including several government ministries, the entire LPG retail supply chain, the banking sector and the district-level administration. Effective coordination across different institutions, with often different mandates, was essential for the scheme’s success.

For instance, regular meetings between the MoPNG and the Department of Financial Services were critical in ensuring overall alignment of banks in the scheme. The OMCs played a leading role in identifying and resolving bottlenecks by coordinating with all the relevant stakeholders throughout the scheme’s implementation. As one of the field officers interviewed suggested: ‘The entire implementation was under mission mode. From top to bottom, the momentum was buil[t] and leveraged, as everyone was pushing the roll-out collectively.’ An elaborate multi-tiered structure of project management teams was put in place to facilitate coordination and enable troubleshooting during implementation.

12.6.3 Exploiting Motivations at the Individual Level and Supporting Capacity Building

One of the interesting lessons from the DBTL scheme is that giving individual ownership and responsibility to stakeholders could be instrumental in the implementation of such large-scale public programmes. For instance, the senior and middle managers of the OMCs, along with the officials and Minister at the MoPNG, were the guardian officers for one district each (MoPNG 2015c). This created a sense of individual responsibility for effective implementation of the scheme in their respective districts. Further, the annual performance appraisal of the field officers of the OMCs was linked to the enrolment rate under the DBTL scheme.

Close to 16,000 LPG distributors across the country were mobilised, given individual targets and monitored on a daily basis for the scheme’s implementation. They also received periodic training and supervision from the field officers of the OMCs, along with adequate financial compensation to cover the costs incurred. Similarly, the bank personnel were trained by the LDMs, in coordination with the field officers. While an absence of dedicated bank personnel for the DBTL scheme led to delays and difficulties in the enrolment process, this was eventually overcome through continued efforts by MoPNG, Department of Financial Services, banks and LDMs.

The experience with the DBTL scheme provides an important lesson about effectively using different individual motivational drivers to facilitate effective and timely implementation of a government scheme.

12.6.4 Learning from Past Experience

As discussed in Section 12.2, the modified DBTL scheme incorporated insights from a review of the scheme’s first round of implementation. For instance, it included an alternative enrolment procedure, which addressed the politically sensitive issue of exclusion of LPG consumers lacking an Aadhaar number. Further, the review identified the difficulties faced by different stakeholders. This helped the OMCs to devise robust systems (such as improved information technology systems and software), along with teams of experts, to quickly respond to real-time on-the-ground enrolment issues. A comprehensive grievance-redressal system was also established in line with the recommendations of the committee to help resolve customer issues.

This shows the importance of reviewing reform programmes and incorporating the feedback of key stakeholders, particularly end consumers, to improve the scheme design and implementation processes.

12.6.5 Leveraging Existing Systems and Schemes

The DBTL scheme rested on the effective use of several other government schemes and efforts. Any digital cash-transfer scheme requires a branchless banking network and a robust authentication system (Banerjee Reference Banerjee2015). In the case of the DBTL scheme, the Core Banking SolutionFootnote 10 enabled electronic transfer of money to beneficiaries’ bank account, while the efforts towards the financial inclusion of the households ensured that most LPG consumers had or could open a new bank account to enrol in the DBTL scheme. In fact, about 14 per cent of enrolled households did not possess an existing account and had opened a new bank account to take advantage of the subsidy. About half of these accounts were opened under another national scheme for financial inclusion, Pradhan Mantri Jan Dhan Yojana. This highlights the benefits of convergence and the need for greater coordination between different government schemes. Furthermore, the OMCs conducted a ‘know your customer’ drive before the DBTL scheme’s launch that created a digital database of beneficiaries (LPG consumers) and enabled the enrolment of customers under the DBTL scheme. The Aadhaar numbers, meanwhile, facilitated the online authentication of beneficiaries by linking their bank accounts to the core banking server (Banerjee Reference Banerjee2015).

While there was a clear convergence of past and ongoing schemes, sustained efforts must continue to improve the banking infrastructure and services for all households, particularly as rural and/or economically poor households will make up the majority of future LPG adopters in India.

12.6.6 Strong Emphasis on Awareness Generation

The DBTL scheme was well publicised through an intensive information education campaign. This comprised advertising through different media and direct outreach to consumers through the use of text messages, calls and public announcements (MoPNG 2014, 2015d). An information education campaign was devised and implemented for each district. The effectiveness of the awareness campaign was reflected in the consumer survey, in which all surveyed households knew about the DBTL scheme. However, there were gaps in awareness about the enrolment process and the status of subsidy transfer, which could be overcome through proactive information flows. The messaging in the awareness campaigns, which focused on ensuring households that they would retain their deserving subsidy benefit, also improved compliance with the scheme.

12.7 Conclusion

With increasing coverage and use of LPG as a domestic fuel in India, the need for reforming the LPG subsidy programme is growing. Apart from capping the consumption of a subsidised product, the Indian government implemented the DBTL scheme to improve the efficiency of subsidy disbursal and to reduce diversion of subsidised LPG to unintended users and uses.

This chapter assessed the performance of the DBTL scheme in terms of its implementation and the achievement of its objectives based on the experiences of key stakeholders. Using a mixed-methods approach, we found that the DBTL scheme fared well in both implementation and achievement of objectives. However, challenges remained pertaining to delays in the subsidy transfer, information gaps and a lack of financial inclusion. In summary, the DBTL scheme was successfully implemented due to strong political leadership at the national level combined with effective institutional coordination, strategies to motivate individuals, convergence of various government efforts, learning from past experiences and a focus on awareness generation.

By guaranteeing transfers directly to the beneficiary, the DBTL scheme made the reform of LPG subsidies and the liberalisation of LPG prices possible. It has paved the way for further reforms to improve the equity of the LPG subsidy programme by targeting the beneficiaries. The Indian government has already started excluding wealthy households on the basis of income information. Potential reforms, such as differential subsidies to different types of households – classified on the basis of income, socio-economic conditions, family size or urban-rural domicile – are now possible to further improve the targeting.

The largely positive experience of the DBTL scheme has inspired the government to use direct benefit transfer for other social benefits to improve the targeting and efficacy of government subsidy expenditures. However, the government should continue its efforts to ensure that no deserving consumer is deprived of the subsidy benefit due to a lack of information, difficulty during enrolment or poor access to banking services. Sustained efforts to bring such consumers within the scheme’s fold will be required, particularly as the penetration of LPG increases in rural areas, where access to banking services is a challenge.

The DBTL scheme is one of the few shining examples of fossil fuel subsidy reform achieving successful implementation on a massive scale without any significant public opposition. Strong political will and leadership, along with effective communication and messaging, coupled with a robust implementation plan and good management, led to the success of the DBTL scheme. Insights from this scheme could inform effective design and implementation of cash-transfer programmes in particular and fossil fuel subsidy reforms in general.

13 Sustaining Carbon Lock-In Fossil Fuel Subsidies in South Africa

Jesse Burton , Tawney Lott and Britta Rennkamp
13.1 Introduction

South Africa is a highly carbon-intensive country. Its government has committed to domestic climate change mitigation policy and international treaties to reduce emissions. At the same time, the government also continues to support the production and use of fossil fuels directly (through supporting coal-fired electricity and the conversion of coal into liquid fuels) and indirectly (through the provision of supporting infrastructure). While the dominance of fossil fuels has been explained through the historical co-evolution of state, business and mining interests (Fine and Rustomjee Reference Fine and Rustomjee1996; Marquard Reference Marquard2006; Baker Reference Baker2012), little is known about the extent of current government support for fossil fuel industries and why such support persists. This chapter quantifies fossil fuel production subsidies in South Africa over the period 2007–15 and offers an analysis of the politics underpinning such subsidies.

Any study of the politics and reform of fossil fuel subsidies in South Africa requires an investigation into the existence of subsidies and their scale, who benefits from them, the actors providing them and their justifications for doing so. To date, only one analysis has attempted to describe and quantify fossil fuel production subsidies in South Africa, for 2013 and 2014 (Garg and Kitson Reference Garg and Kitson2015). This chapter extends their analysis, first, by highlighting how historical state support has created a system of ‘cheap’ fossil fuels through long-running formal and informal institutions and, second, by quantifying subsidies over a longer time period (2007–15). Remarkably, given that there are indeed extensive subsidies in South Africa to fossil fuel production, the South African government has indicated to the Group of 20 (G20) that it has no ‘inefficient’ subsidies.

In quantifying the scale of fossil fuel subsidies, we outline the rationales underpinning the varying mechanisms of support the state provides. We show that subsidies are used to support government objectives related to energy security and economic development. We argue that key drivers of subsidies include apartheid-era industrial and energy policies that have become locked in over time. Despite major political change at the end of apartheid in 1994, many sustaining subsidies have persisted, while whereas new subsidies have emerged with justifications that echo the apartheid state. The South African state does not frame such support as fossil fuel production subsidies – which could spark a national debate around their role in economic development (contrasted against mitigation policies such as carbon taxes) – but instead frames subsidies as supporting ‘vital’ or ‘strategic’ investments (e.g. Transnet 2007; National Treasury 2010; DoE, 2016). Such policies often have a distinctly distributive aim (Whitley Reference Whitley2013). Echoes of the distributive policies of the apartheid state remain in the political allocation of coal contracts and in the lack of reform of liquid fuels pricing. Subsidies that have persisted or emerged since the end of apartheid ostensibly support new beneficiaries, but the analysis shows how the structure of these benefits continues to advantage the existing beneficiaries of production subsidies.

While there has been limited public debate on fossil fuel subsidies, there is debate on South Africa’s future development pathways and the role of fossil fuel extraction and use within that (Winkler and Marquard Reference Winkler and Marquard2009; Altieri et al. Reference Altieri, Trollip and Caetano2015; Baker et al. Reference Baker, Burton, Godinho and Trollip2015). Subsidies have not been a crucial part of the debate either within or outside of government. We suggest that this may be because the scale of subsidies is not well known, and much of the detail is obscured or hidden.

The support of fossil fuel production needs to be seen against the backdrop of the broader political economy of energy in South Africa, which has historically been characterised as the ‘minerals-energy complex’. This denotes a particular set of interlinked sectors and relationships between industry, state-owned enterprises (SOEs) and the state (Fine and Rustomjee Reference Fine and Rustomjee1996). Support for these sectors persists because they are viewed as key to economic development; the state’s industrial policies are often based on the assumption that growth is encouraged through large infrastructure investments, which frequently support minerals extraction and heavy industry (NPC 2011).

Methodologically, this chapter draws on the analysis of national and departmental budgets, estimates of national expenditure, annual reports of SOEs and personal communications with civil society and government representatives. The chapter begins by outlining the current structure and historical development of the coal, electricity and liquid fuels sectors in South Africa to highlight the extent of historical support that has locked in the structure of the energy sector. This is followed by a quantification of recent fossil fuel subsidies and a description of their rationales. The chapter then analyses the politics of reform.

13.2 Historical Development of South Africa’s Fossil Fuel Subsidies

The South African fossil fuel subsidy regime mainly sustains the production of coal for export and for conversion into electricity and liquid fuels. The energy sector heavily relies on coal and was shaped by the unique politics of energy security and the country’s international isolation during apartheid. The minerals sectors shaped energy-intensive industrial development along with SOEs, such as the vertically integrated monopoly utility Eskom and (formerly state-owned) liquid fuels producer Sasol (Fine and Rustomjee Reference Fine and Rustomjee1996; Marquard Reference Marquard2006; Baker Reference Baker2012). From the 1970s onwards, the apartheid state intervened via regulation and continuously stimulated demand for coal through the state-owned electricity, coal-to-liquids, railway and steel industries. This demand built up significant reliance on fossil fuels.

Coal accounts for 65 per cent of primary energy consumed in South Africa (DoE 2010). Eskom generates 95 per cent of South Africa’s electricity, of which 90 per cent is coal fired (Eskom 2014). Sasol’s energy- and emissions-intensive coal-to-liquids process accounts for 25 per cent of liquid fuels consumption. Eskom and Sasol account for roughly 90 per cent of domestic coal consumption and about 55 per cent of South Africa’s emissions (Eberhard Reference Eberhard2011; DEA 2014).

Support for fossil fuel production is concentrated on relatively few large actors that are primarily state owned. Eskom has received government support and has passed this on in the form of ‘underpriced’ electricity (Steyn Reference Steyn2001; NPC 2011). Benefits have accrued to producers and to very large, mostly corporate consumers of electricity, which account for roughly 44 per cent of Eskom’s electricity sales (EIUG 2015). Sasol has received state subsidies since its inception, and the liquid fuels pricing regime continues to ensure large profits in the coal-to-liquids business. Transfers have primarily been from the state and consumers to private firms and Sasol (Rustomjee et al. Reference Rustomjee, Crompton, Maule, Mehlomakulu and Steyn2007). This is unlike other fossil fuel–producing countries, where consumers are often beneficiaries and subsidies play an important role in maintaining political stability (Victor Reference Victor2009). Coal mining benefits from infrastructure provision and from the subsidy-enhanced demand from Eskom and Sasol, although direct subsidisation of coal mining is limited.

13.3 Quantifying Fossil Fuel Subsidies in South Africa

‘Fossil fuel production’ refers to production in the coal, oil and gas sectors, including access, exploration and appraisal; development, extraction, preparation and transport of fossil fuel resources; plant construction and operation; distribution and decommissioning; and fossil fuel electricity generation (Bast et al. Reference Bast, Doukas, Pickard, van der Burg and Whitley2015: 9). We use the definition proposed by the Global Subsidies Initiative, which reflects the full range of benefits provided to the fossil fuel industry. This definition includes the mechanisms of subsidisation specified in the World Trade Organization’s Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures (see Chapter 7), as well as additional support mechanisms (GSI 2010: 4–5). Earlier work found that the value of national production subsidies was an average of 213 million South African rands per year (or USD 20 million) in 2013–14 (Garg and Kitson Reference Garg and Kitson2015).Footnote 1

There are several mechanisms through which fossil fuel production is subsidised. The most ‘visible’ form of subsidisation, and most easily measured, is direct transfers or budgetary outlays (Koplow Reference Koplow2015: 4; OECD 2015: 27). Under the World Trade Organization definition of a subsidy, a loan qualifies as a ‘potential’ direct transfer from the government. Fossil fuel producers can also be subsidised through tax expenditures (see Chapter 2). Similar to direct transfers, these measures effectively reduce the cost of producing fossil fuels below the costs that would prevail under a standard tax treatment. Finally, fossil fuel production is subsidised through market price transfers, which result from policy interventions and produce transfers between consumers and producers (OECD 2010: 19). In this case, liquid fuels producers receive guaranteed returns, with large transfers from consumers to producers via the regulated fuel price.

Table 13.1 shows the subsidies to fossil fuel production via direct transfers, government revenue foregone and Sasol market price support in the period 2007–15. We exclude public finance for production but note that this is an important and growing mechanism of support. Public finance for 2013–14 is included in Garg and Kitson (Reference Garg and Kitson2015) and Bast et al. (Reference Bast, Doukas, Pickard, van der Burg and Whitley2015). For example, public finance for fossil fuel electricity production within South Africa was USD 198 million in 2013 and USD 45 million in 2014 (Lott et al. Reference Lott, Burton and Rennkamp2016), and support for coal mining was USD 35.6 million in 2014–15 (IDC 2015).

Table 13.1 Annual subsidy estimates by category for South Africa

Subsidy category200720082009201020112012201320142015
Direct transfers8308301,00116913412.817.01,707
Government revenue foregone24.318.8126397506512566578267
Sasol market price supportaaaaa127aaa

Note: All amounts in 2016 USD million.

a No transfers for that subsidy in a given year or lack of data.

Source: Authors’ calculations; Lott Reference Lott2016; see Lott et al. Reference Lott, Burton and Rennkamp2016 for assumptions.

The subsidies shown in Table 13.1 are part of substantial and long-running support to fossil fuel production in South Africa. The following sections describe this history – showing how subsidies have become locked in because they support state objectives of energy security and economic growth – and explain how the substantial subsidisation shown in Table 13.1 is an extension of the minerals-energy complex in South Africa.

13.3.1 Historical Subsidies to the Coal Sector and Eskom

Coal mining benefited historically from various apartheid laws that lowered the cost of doing business, including exemptions from the usual environmental protections and the ability to pay very low wages to mine workers and provide them with little or no labour, health or safety protections. State take via royalties did not exist until 2010.Footnote 2 This created a system of cheap fossil fuels, with benefits accruing to either coal suppliers or electricity users, who were frequently the same firms and who enjoyed unparalleled access to the state, including Anglo American and Gencor (later BHP Billiton) (Fine and Rustomjee Reference Fine and Rustomjee1996; Burton Reference Burton2011).

Eskom’s coal costs were furthermore kept low via two contracting models. In the first model, Eskom provided capital to ‘cost-plus mines’, supporting coal producers by financing production and guaranteeing off-take. Eskom remains responsible for capital investment in these mines, as well as for liabilities such as mine rehabilitation. The second model involved fixed-price contracts with mines, where coal sold to Eskom was subsidised from exports, with low coal costs passed through Eskom to benefit electricity users (Eberhard Reference Eberhard2011; Matthews Reference Matthews2015).

The allocation of coal contracts was politicised. Contracts were shared out among companies and were used to develop local mining capacity and companies with political/ethnic ties to the state, creating new (white) ‘Afrikaner’ capital as distinct from (white) English or ‘imperial’ interests (Fine and Rustomjee Reference Fine and Rustomjee1996). The coal sector has evolved since 1994, but it remains reliant on Eskom as the largest user of coal, and there are crucial similarities that persist. There are links between coal mining interests and the ruling African National Congress (ANC) Party. Eskom also uses its market power to promote Black Economic Empowerment in coal. Black Economic Empowerment describes economic policies that are intended to redress the racial inequities of apartheid through privileging black or historically disadvantaged individuals. Eskom’s procurement policy is explicitly distributive and favours new black-owned mining firms that may or may not have competitively priced coal; Eskom’s support for new producers is thus based on racial economic development objectives (Burton and Winkler Reference Burton and Winkler2014).

Eskom’s provision of support for mining is seldom analysed in terms of the distributive consequences for the broader economy. This is similar to liquid fuels pricing, discussed later, where a regulated price is maintained due to concerns about downstream employment and new black ownership in the retail sector.

Recent examples of direct transfers to Eskom are shown in Table 13.2. Government support of Eskom is not new; when the utility was undertaking a large expansion programme in the 1970s and 1980s, it received subsidies through government guarantees for foreign loans and through state-supplied forward cover on currency risk (Steyn Reference Steyn2001).Footnote 3 As we explain, current support includes transfers to ensure the financial stability of Eskom and promote supply security in the electricity sector, which have been necessary given the utility’s financial and supply problems.

Table 13.2 Subsidies to coal and electricity production in South Africa

SubsidyType of subsidy200720082009201020112012201320142015
Eskom loanGovernment fundinga830830830aaaaa
Loan interestRevenue foregoneaa123390491449409407a
Eskom transferGovernment fundingaaaaaaaa1,691
Water infrastructureGovernment fundingaaa15.326.6aaa0.26
Government fundingaaaaaaaa5.23
Government fundingaaaaaa0.020.09a
Eskom loan guaranteePotential direct transferaaaaaaaaa
Eskom diesel rebateGovernment revenue foregone24.318.82.877.3315.463.3157171267
Total24.38499561,2425335125665781,964

Note: All amounts in 2016 USD million.

a No transfers for that subsidy in a given year.

In response to rolling power cuts in 2008, the national government issued a loan of USD 5.45 billion to Eskom (RSA 2008: 2) to recommission three mothballed coal plants and finance two new coal power stations. In 2014, the state converted a portion of the loan to equity (USD 2.52 billion) (Nene Reference Nene2015), resulting in direct transfers of USD 840 million between 2008 and 2011. We estimate that interest foregone on the loan between 2009 and 2014 totals USD 2.29 billion (Lott et al. Reference Lott, Burton and Rennkamp2016).

Eskom received a further direct transfer in 2015 when Parliament enacted the Eskom Special Appropriation Act to assist Eskom in expanding electricity generation capacity (RSA 2015: 2). The value of this bailout was USD 1.63 billion.

Potential direct transfers can also be identified in the provision of government loan guarantees. These loan guarantees link Eskom’s debt to the sovereign’s investment rating, lowering Eskom’s cost of borrowing by lowering the risk associated with Eskom debt. The government assumes a financial liability in the case of default. Eskom has borrowed a total of USD 12.8 billion against the total loan guarantee of USD 23.8 billion (National Treasury 2016b).

Direct transfers of USD 47.5 million from the National Treasury and Department of Water Affairs were made for water infrastructure in the Waterberg mining basin. The water infrastructure is explicitly for supplying water to Eskom’s Matimba and Medupi coal power plants and for de-bottlenecking coal supplier Exxaro’s existing pipeline. Phase two of the project is ‘a prerequisite to enable the further development of the Waterberg coalfields’ (TCTA 2014: 47; see also National Treasury 2014b, 2015: 40, 2016a: 953).

The National Treasury considers such transfers a ‘funding mechanism’ for ‘strategic projects’ that contribute to water and energy security (National Treasury 2016c). User charges go to pipelines and transfer schemes, and the government supplies guarantees to enable strategic projects. To what extent user charges cover the full costs is not known; in rail, Transnet has indicated that contracts do not fully cover the costs of new rail expansions on the coal line (Creamer Reference Creamer2015). Since these developments are run through SOEs, there is very little information publicly available on long-term financing.

Support for fossil fuels in the electricity sector has seldom been understood as a ‘fossil fuel subsidy’. Rather, subsidies have been used for energy security and industrial development in sectors that are considered by the state to be important drivers of development. Quantifying and reframing this support as a subsidy to fossil fuels are thus key in promoting discussion and debate in South Africa about the role of this support.

13.3.2 Historical Subsidies to the Liquid Fuels Sector and Sasol

The liquid fuels industry has received considerable historical support from the South African government in terms of direct and indirect subsidies. A favourable regulatory regime guaranteed ‘the profitability and the financing of every segment of the fuel value chain’ (Roberts and Rustomjee Reference Roberts and Rustomjee2010: 63).

The liquid fuels subsidy regime that developed between 1950 and early 2000 privileged synthetic fuelFootnote 4 producers Sasol and Mossgas/PetroSA. In addition, so-called other oil companies (OOCs) operate in South Africa, including Shell, BP, Total, Chevron and Engen. These actors also historically benefited from favourable policies and regulations, though to a lesser extent. The regulated price of petroleum was introduced to encourage industrialisation and import substitution by providing favourable pricing to OOCs. Profits for OOCs had to be maintained through the regulatory regime to ensure that domestic refining capacity would remain in apartheid South Africa. As such, fuel pricing in South Africa has historically been based on an import parity priceFootnote 5 that guarantees returns for domestic refiners. However, the synthetic fuel producers emerged as the primary beneficiaries of direct and indirect subsidies due to the state’s interest in reducing the country’s dependence on imported fuel. The emphasis on energy security grew in the 1970s in response to the oil crises and apartheid oil embargoes.

Support for Sasol took several forms. The first was the provision of an import parity price to Sasol when it was established in 1947. Sasol also enjoyed tariff protection when the price of oil fell below a defined threshold, which was first introduced when the coal-to-liquid plant Sasol 1 was commissioned. The South African government further stipulated that the OOCs uplift (purchase and sell) 100 per cent of production from Sasol.Footnote 6 Importantly, each of these provisions was extended when Sasol expanded in the 1980s. The upliftment agreements, designed to give preference to Sasol’s synthetic fuels in the inland market,Footnote 7 were ‘effectively a government-brokered and sanctioned form of private regulation’ (Competition Tribunal 2006: 19). To accommodate Sasol’s production, the OOCs mothballed 30 per cent of their refining capacity, receiving state compensation in the form of levies and guaranteed returns on investment paid to the refiners (Competition Tribunal 2006: 22).

In 1992, the government commissioned state-owned Mossgas. Similarly to Sasol, Mossgas received tariff protection and upliftment agreements with the OOCs, as well as transfers through levies on the fuel price (Rustomjee et al. Reference Rustomjee, Crompton, Maule, Mehlomakulu and Steyn2007: 61). In 1999, PetroSA was formed as a merger between Mossgas and the state-owned oil and gas exploration company Soekor. PetroSA continues to receive state support.

The apartheid state’s emphasis on the development of local refineries and petrochemicals capacity established the synthetic fuel producers as entities through which the government could pursue these objectives. Post-apartheid energy policy reform has not been accompanied by any fundamental pricing reform, highlighting the persistence of regulatory support for the sector.

Indeed, although South Africa altered its fuel pricing regime in 2003 to be a more accurate reflection of an import parity price, it is well documented that this price remains above a competitive price and confers a benefit to liquid fuel producers through market price transfers (Competition Tribunal 2006: 51). The Department of Energy set a 2010 deadline for the deregulation of pricing (Competition Tribunal 2006: 31), but this goal has not been met in part because the department claims deregulation will affect the sector’s new Black Economic Empowerment entrants by removing protection for retailers (where small black-owned firms are active). Sasol is therefore protected by its own important supply position in the inland market (where refinery and pipeline capacity limits conventional supply) and by the other distributive policies of the state regarding Black Economic Empowerment, even though Sasol benefits only indirectly from these latter objectives. The company’s own lobbying efforts are also important; the Competition Commission, for example, has noted Sasol’s opposition to pricing reform.

Sasol is presently the primary beneficiary of fuel pricing regulation due to its low production costs, which has resulted in the company receiving economic rents through the import parity price (on top of the direct subsidies it received). Sasol’s excessive profits as a result of the pricing rules have been a bone of contention (Competition Tribunal 2006). We estimate the value of the market price transfers to Sasol for 2012 (the only year for which data were available) at USD 127.44 million (in 2016 USD) (Lott Reference Lott2016: 78).

Support to the liquid fuels sector has also taken the form of direct transfers to finance infrastructure in support of energy security. The Department of Energy, for example, transferred USD 411.46 million to Transnet – the operator of state-owned ports, railways and pipelines – between fiscal year 2011 and fiscal year 2013 to support the commissioning of a large new pipeline.

Finally, SOEs also received direct transfers for personnel training, the promotion of oil and gas exploration and production and research and development on hydraulic fracturing and carbon capture and storage (PetroSA 2010, 2012, 2013; Maqubela Reference Maqubela2014: 18; National Treasury 2014a, 2015, 2016a). These subsidies are shown in Table 13.3.

Table 13.3 Subsidies to the liquid fuels industry in South Africa

SubsidyType of subsidy200720082009201020112012201320142015
SasolMPSaaaaa127aaa
Transnet pipelineGovernment fundingbbb148137127bbb
PetroSA (personnel training)Government fundingbb0.370.320.290.260.38bb
Central Energy Fund (oil and gas)Government fundingbbb8.325.516.416.708.629.94
SANEDIGovernment fundingbbbbbb5.698.28b

Note: All amounts in 2016 USD million.

a No transfers for that subsidy in a given year or lack of data.

b Lack of data.

13.4 The Politics of Fossil Fuel Subsidies and Their Reform in South Africa

Legitimate reasons for subsidies – such as energy security – blend with the long-term lock-in of entrenched institutions and the interest groups that have formed around them in the mix of different subsidies and their rationales (Victor Reference Victor2009). There is no public debate on fossil fuel incentives in South Africa, as the scale of support for fossil fuel production remains largely unknown. These subsidies form the core of long-running economic-development interventions by the state and its support for particular sectors. Finally, subsidies are inextricably linked to the distributive politics and racial economic transformation goals of the post-apartheid state.

Questions of subsidy definition and policy problem definition in South Africa have effectively kept the issue off the institutional or decision agenda (cf. Kingdon Reference Kingdon2014). There is no agreement on what constitutes a subsidy or the scale of subsidisation, particularly for production subsidies. Many national civil society organisations define non-priced externalities as subsidies, with their work focused on community impacts. For example, we found only one non-governmental organisation active in the energy sector that has carried out considerable research on public support to large industries (Centre for Environmental Rights et al. 2016).

The Treasury has a narrower focus on the consumption subsidies and taxes over which it has institutional influence, with little focus on production subsidies, which cross institutional boundaries (Machingambi Reference Machingambi2014). The Treasury does engage with international groups (e.g. G20) around subsidies, and the international level provides some impetus to reform subsidies and to adopt broader low-carbon policies (National Treasury 2016b).

The above-mentioned rationales for the subsidies are often linked to broader economic development plans and thus reflect ideas within the state and the ruling ANC Party about the nature and form of economic development and the state’s role in that context. Many policy documents outline the ANC’s goal for the ‘developmental state’ to take an active part in shaping the country’s economic trajectory; such documents also emphasise the importance of resource utilisation (the use of coal and other minerals) as a basis for industrialisation (Mohamed Reference Mohamed and Edighji2007). Providing infrastructure is an important component of this developmental approach. The National Development Plan, New Growth Path, and internal ANC policy documents all emphasise this role and the role of SOEs such as Eskom in supporting growth (ANC 2007, 2010; NPC 2011). For example, ‘investment in energy, rail, roads, ports and other infrastructure remains a cornerstone of [the] government’s economic strategy’ (National Treasury 2010: 96).

Eskom in particular has received large state bailouts – which essentially support coal-fired power and mining – because unbundling the ailing monopoly has not been politically feasible. Attempts to liberalise the electricity sector in the late 1990s as part of the new post-apartheid energy policy process met with resistance from unions and parts of the ANC, who perceived liberalisation as the first step to privatisation of a sector that is intended to provide a public good and is a core component of the developmental state. Eskom also opposed being broken up or sidelined (Eberhard Reference Eberhard, Victor and Heller2007; Baker and Burton Reference Baker, Burton, Goldthau, Keating and Kuzemko2018).

The contradictions between climate change mitigation and the use and support of fossil fuels for development are widespread. Such contradictions reflect long-running internal contestations in the government and within the ANC about industrial policy, even as research has shown that shifting away from resource-based industrialisation would have better economic outcomes (Altieri et al. Reference Altieri, Trollip and Caetano2015). Diversification away from minerals has been a prominent goal of industrial policy, but the blunt-force ‘heavy industry’ approach of state provision of railways, pipelines and other infrastructure has continued to receive substantial support. Such support has been concentrated in sectors that are core to the minerals-energy complex.

This may be because this type of ‘heavy industrialisation’ – which is closely aligned with types of industry that are based on, support or use fossil fuels – is easier for states to implement when they have limited capabilities. Forward-looking strategies in the National Development Plan focus extensively on the development of state capability as part of an economic diversification strategy. However, the tension between diversification and minerals/heavy industry has not been resolved in policy (neither in the National Development Plan nor in industrial policies), with persistent subsidisation for sectors deemed important for the economy.

Climate policy has emerged alongside older policies and is based in parts of the government not necessarily responsible for the original subsidy. For example, climate policy is based in the Department of Environmental Affairs, and the carbon tax is based in the Tax Directorate in National Treasury. Yet liquid fuels pricing, which perversely guarantees profits for the carbon-intensive coal-to-liquids sector, is the ambit of the Department of Energy and is not a Treasury mandate (National Treasury 2016c). Indeed, the state has continued to subsidise production while attempting to introduce a carbon tax on emissions as a reform measure to promote economic efficiency. While this is inefficient in terms of transaction costs, it may reflect diverging objectives in government (since many departments make direct on-budget transfers for infrastructure development), as well as the relative power of different state departments, their own interests and their relationships to and shared ideas with interest groups. While Treasury manages state finances, departments are responsible for overseeing their policy spaces and managing their budgets. SOEs report to the Department of Public Enterprises or to ministries in that sector.

Finally, these notions of development further link to the distributive elements of fossil fuel subsidies. Eskom has for many years been central to the system of accumulation of the minerals-energy complex. The coal sector indirectly benefits from the support given to state-owned companies such as Eskom (and previously Sasol). The rationale for the creation and maintenance of subsidies historically and currently is often implicitly related to industrial policy and is explicitly distributive – to create new capitalists in the coal sector, for example, or to ensure ‘radical economic transformation’ in the liquid fuels sector (Fine and Rustomjee Reference Fine and Rustomjee1996; Marquard Reference Marquard2006; Whitley Reference Whitley2013; DoE 2014). In the case of Sasol, the benefits that accrue to the company are not seen as a transfer from consumers to a producer, and a new pricing system for liquid fuels is not a priority on the policy agenda. This is partly because of the persisting narrative that Sasol is key to energy security, as well as the company’s perceived strategic importance to the economy in terms of security of supply, investment, tax, job creation and value added, i.e. beneficiation of coal into higher value products domestically (RSA 2007: Rustomjee et al. Reference Rustomjee, Crompton, Maule, Mehlomakulu and Steyn2007). Reform also would threaten new Black Economic Empowerment entrants in the retail sector.

Benefits continue to accrue to fossil fuel producers and reflect the lock-in of the transfers to corporations set up by the authoritarian apartheid state. These subsidies are not socially, environmentally or economically efficient, but they remain unchanged because of concerns about potential risks to security of supply and the state’s limited capability to regulate different market structures. Many of the large transfers are embedded in the specificities of the South African energy sectors and have rationales beyond merely reproducing a fossil fuel system. These include the lack of other options and ideas regarding industrialisation and development, which may account for much of the ongoing support.

Quantifying the scale and extent of support is an important first step towards reform of production subsidies (Rentschler and Bazilian Reference Rentschler and Bazilian2017). Reform will require the emergence of as-yet-unseen conditions, including coalitions between non-state actors and the state. As in other areas of policy, the government faces opposition from those who benefit (e.g. in the case of Sasol). In many cases the benefits of reform may be clearly more equitable or efficient, but the potential for organised opposition and reform of subsidies is limited without knowledge on who benefits, how and why.

13.5 Conclusion

Our analysis has shown that fossil fuel production has been and continues to be supported in various ways in South Africa. Since 2008, direct transfers have ranged between USD 454 million and USD 2.09 billion per year, whereas quantified revenues foregone have been between USD 2.45 million and USD 336 million. This increases considerably when we include the price support received by Sasol via the regulated fuel price. Beyond this, substantial unquantifiable subsidies exist but require further research to quantify.

Quantifying these subsidies contributes to the debate on fossil fuel subsidies in South Africa, which until now has been largely hindered by a lack of information and secrecy around subsidisation. We have distilled key elements of state support for fossil fuels and extended prior analyses. Quantifying subsidies to fossil fuels will enable the necessary research to understand the economic and distributional impacts of reform. However, further research is required to understand the options for reform in different sectors and departments, as well as within the ANC. While we have outlined some substantial subsidies to fossil fuels, these also require further research to analyse the political dynamics of the ministries responsible.

Given the importance of state intervention in fossil fuel production in South Africa, our findings raise important questions about the role of the state in economic development, the costs of intervention, and policymaking processes in South Africa more broadly. Mitigation is viewed as ‘too costly’ (Baker et al. Reference Baker, Burton, Godinho and Trollip2015), yet the state continues to support fossil fuels. Liquid fuels pricing reform remains off the policy agenda despite the large rents accruing to Sasol through the pricing system. This is partly explained by the borders of different policy spaces, where new policies have emerged alongside (rather than in place of) existing support in different parts of the state. Understanding the internal dynamics of different ministries and their perception of their role in subsidising fossil fuel sectors is an important avenue for future research.

Support for fossil fuel production cannot be divorced from more general analyses of the political economy of particular states and sectors, nor from broader questions regarding politics and economic strategies. The distributive implications of reform must be better understood, especially since Black Economic Empowerment objectives are supported by policies that promote subsidies for fossil fuels.

Reform will require determined action from civil society and other groups opposed to subsidies. South Africa needs debate, discussion and consultation about reforms, as well as further economic analyses of the outcomes of individual subsidy reform. Quantification is a necessary first step in understanding the scale of fossil fuel subsidies in South Africa. Ultimately, long-term economic development planning may need reinvigoration and new ideas to infuse into the state and the ANC. Without revising the current industrial development plans and pathways, state support for fossil fuels will remain locked in and continue to support a high-carbon development pathway. Fossil fuel subsidy reform may offer a narrow mechanism where disparate groups can agree on reform, especially in South Africa, where production obviously benefits so few, usually large, corporate actors.

14 The Politics of Subsidies to Coal Extraction in Colombia

Claudia Strambo , Ana Carolina González Espinosa , Angélica Puertas Velasco and Aaron Atteridge
14.1 Introduction

Following the 2016 peace agreement with the Revolutionary Armed Forces of Colombia (FARC), the Colombian government focused on the crucial issue of how to finance the peace process, especially as oil revenues declined following rapid price decreases the same year. A structural fiscal reform was promulgated at the end of 2016 with the aim of rebalancing public accounts and addressing critical revenue challenges. Reform proposals focused on issues such as value-added tax (VAT) and tax evasion, yet long-running fiscal support to sectors such as mining received a free pass, even though the restructuring or elimination of subsidies might have unlocked an additional source of government revenue.

Colombia is one of the top five exporters of thermal coal globally, and the coal mining sector became a core pillar of the government’s economic-development policy during the 2000s. However, debate about the governance of the extractives sector (i.e. production of minerals, coal, oil and gas) has increased, notably around the real costs and benefits of mining, including large-scale coal mining. This debate has focused on the lack of transparency in the governance of mining and on the use of income generated by mining activities, as well as its environmental and social impacts. As a result, the mining sector, including coal extraction, suffers today from a growing legitimacy deficit in the eyes of the general public and, increasingly, local governments, who argue that they do not reap enough of the economic benefits (Long Reference Long2017).

This situation has contributed to a redesign of the mining policy (MME 2016) and has encouraged the government to become a member of the Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative (EITI) in an attempt to improve governance of the sector. Despite these changes, subsidies to the mining sector, including to coal mining, are increasingly a controversial subject in Colombia. There is, however, little explicit ‘subsidies’ language in policy debates or the academic literature, and the first two EITI reports submitted by the Colombian government (MME 2017; 2015a) make no mention of any subsidies to extractive industries.

To understand the resilience of fiscal support to coal mining in Colombia, this chapter explores the political dynamics behind the introduction and maintenance of various kinds of subsidies that support extraction. It focuses particularly on the subsidies regime associated with large-scale coal production. After a brief overview of the sector and its socio-economic importance, we introduce some of the key subsidies to large-scale coal extraction and then explore why and how these subsidies have been maintained. We discuss two key examples of subsidies – the Plan Vallejo and a royalty rebate – in more detail before drawing conclusions.

14.2 The Economic, Social and Political Roles of Coal Extraction in Colombia

Colombia produced roughly 85 million tonnes of coal in 2015, corresponding to 1.5 per cent of global production (BP 2017). More than 90 per cent of this is high-quality thermal coal from large-scale open-pit mines (SIMCO 2016). Compared to many other major coal producers, Colombia consumes little coal domestically: only 6.5 per cent, mainly for power generation and industrial use (IEA 2016). In 2015, virtually all the large-scale coal production in the La Guajira and César departments was exported (SIMCO 2016). Most of the coal consumed internally is produced by small- and medium-scale mines. Therefore, coal production serves other, more significant societal functions than ensuring power generation and energy security. This is reflected in the fact that the legal and institutional framework governing coal extraction is for minerals, whereas other fossil fuel extraction activities such as oil and gas fall under the country’s energy policy. Since 2000, coal extraction has been dominated by private companies, with three of them – Cerrejón, Drummond Ltd. and Prodeco – producing more than 76 per cent of all Colombian coal (MME 2015a).

In 2015, coal mining represented little more than 1.3 per cent of the country’s gross domestic product (GDP) and 12 per cent of exports (MME 2016: 43). Yet the economic weight of coal extraction is particularly significant in the two main producing departments: in 2013, the industry contributed to 38 and 47 per cent of the regional GDP in the César and La Guajira departments, respectively (DANE–Banco de la República 2015a, 2015b).Footnote 1

The extractives industry in general has been a substantial contributor to the country’s public finances, accounting for about one-third of revenues in 2013 (Nieves Zárate and Hernández Vidal Reference Nieves Zárate and Hernández Vidal2016). Most of that comes out of the hydrocarbons sector; in 2015, the sector was responsible for three-quarters of the extractives industry’s contributions to the country’s public revenues via taxes, royalties and other types of financial compensation (MME 2017). For royalties alone, 82 per cent in 2014 came from oil and gas extraction, compared to 15 per cent from coal extraction and 3 per cent from other minerals (MME 2015b).

However, the wider economic benefits of large-scale mining have been the subject of growing criticism. Some highlight a lack of overall socio-economic development despite the extraordinary rents the commodity boom brought to the country (Rudas Lleras and Espitia Zamora Reference Rudas Lleras, Espitia Zamora and Salamanca2013; Torres et al. Reference Torres, Rocha, Melo and Peña2015); others worry about the potential negative macroeconomic effects of resource extraction (Torres González Reference Torres González2014). In a 2015 study commissioned by the Colombian Mining Association, 59 per cent of the interviewed inhabitants of mining municipalities said their well-being would improve if no further mining activities were developed (Arteaga Reference Arteaga2016).

Serious concerns over the environmental and human security impacts of large-scale coal mining have also been raised, focusing on community (voluntary or forced) relocation, indigenous and Afro-Caribbean communities’ rights (Múnera Monte et al. Reference Múnera Monte, Granados Castellanos, Teherán Sánchez and Naranjo Vasco2014) and air, water and soil pollution (Cabrera Leal and Fierro Morales Reference Cabrera Leal, Fierro Morales and Salamanca2013; Cardoso Reference Cardoso2015). Between 2000 and 2016, at least 179 social conflicts linked to the extractives sector (especially coal, gold and oil) have been documented (Valencia and Riaño Reference Valencia and Riaño2017). However, although 86 per cent of Colombians in 2016 thought that mining is destroying the environment, 78 per cent considered it essential for development (Rojas and Hopke Reference Rojas, Hopke, Henao and Espinosa2016).

Coal production also plays an important part in the country’s politics. Since the 1990s, the national government has based its economic policy on internationalisation and has embraced the extraction of natural resources as a main driver for development, thus facilitating the entry and operation of foreign financial and technological capital into the large-scale extractives sector (Vélez-Torres Reference Vélez-Torres2014). During this period, key mining actors reinforced their links with the national political elite (Sankey Reference Sankey2013), enabling the creation of a strong alliance between the national government, local elites and the mining sector under the administrations of Álvaro Uribe (2002–10) and Juan Manuel Santos (2010–18).

14.3 Subsidies to Coal Extraction in Colombia

As mentioned in Chapter 1, defining subsidies is a political exercise (see also Chapter 2). We draw on the definition from the Global Subsidies Initiative (GSI 2010a, 2010b), which builds on and expands the definition from the World Trade Organization’s Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures. The GSI thus defines subsidies as preferential treatment in all forms (financial and otherwise) provided to selected companies, to one sector or product when compared to other sectors or to sectors or products in one country when compared to other countries. It distinguishes the following categories of subsidies to fossil fuel producers: direct and indirect transfer of funds and liabilities, government revenue foregone, government-provided or government-purchased goods or services and income or price support.

Although incentives to coal extraction are rarely referred to as ‘subsidies’ in Colombia, the work by Rudas Lleras and Espitia Zamora (Reference Rudas Lleras, Espitia Zamora and Salamanca2013), Pardo Becerra (Reference Pardo Becerra2014; Reference Pardo Becerra2016) and Chen and Perry (Reference Chen and Perry2015) shows that there are a broad range of incentives to large-scale coal extraction, some of which can be considered subsidies. Many of these are tax incentives, a form of indirect support. The Directorate of National Taxes and Customs reported 179 tax discounts for the mining sector in 2014 (Parra et al. Reference Parra, Parra Garzón and Sierra Reyes2014: 31).

Here we provide a non-exhaustive account of subsidies from which the large-scale coal sector benefits (or has benefited from) to illustrate the diversity of mechanisms used to support the sector. While in many cases coal companies are conferred benefits because they belong to the wider mining or extractives sector, in some cases subsidies are specific to the coal sector. The following examples also show that while some of the subsidies are conferred through legal or administrative measures that target the (coal) mining or extractives sector explicitly (de jure), other conferred benefits are more general economic incentives that have ended up serving the interests of the mining or coal industry disproportionally (de facto). Table 14.1 summarises the subsidies according to the Global Subsidies Initiative classification.

Table 14.1 Examples of subsidies to coal Extraction in Colombia by subsidy category

Subsidy categorySubsidy typeColombian caseConferred benefit as
Government revenue foregoneTax expenditureExemption from departmental and municipal taxes (e.g. tax on industry and commerce)Mining industry (de jure)
Special deduction in income tax for newly acquired real productive assetsMining industry (de facto)
Deduction for anticipated investment amortisationMining industry (de jure)
Exemption from special tax on combustiblesCoal industry (de facto)
Various exemptions and deductions through Plan VallejoCoal industry (de facto)
Certificate for tax rebateExtractives sector (de jure)
Reduced royalties paymentRoyalties tax rebateMining industry (de jure)
Private Property Recognition schemeSpecific case (de jure)
Government-provided or government-purchased goods or servicesUnder-pricing of government-provided goods and servicesSecurity and protection servicesSpecific case (de jure)
Relief from normal costs and proceduresExemption from government procedures normally followed by enterprisesFaster/easier licensing and title-securing process through the Project of National and Strategic Interest classificationSpecific case (de jure)
Sources: GSI 2010a, 2010b.

In terms of revenue foregone, the coal sector (and the rest of the mining industry) benefits from an exemption on departmental and municipal taxes. This implies that departmental and municipal governments are prevented from generating additional tax income from coal exploitation and exploration (Pardo Becerra Reference Pardo Becerra2014). The mining industry, including coal, also benefits from a deduction for anticipated investment amortisation: mining exploration and development expenditures are written off within at least five years, and expensing of failed explorations is allowed.

Between 2004 and 2011, the sector disproportionally benefited from a special deduction in their income tax of 30 per cent from the investment value of newly acquired real productive fixed assets (Rudas and Espitia Reference Rudas Lleras, Espitia Zamora and Salamanca2013). When introducing this measure in 2003, President Uribe – recognising it could incur significant fiscal costs – framed it as a way to stimulate foreign direct investment and employment in a national context marked by insecurity and infrastructure deficits (Presidencia de la República Reference Pizarro Leongómez and Gutiérrez2003). However, because it proved both costly and ineffective (Galindo and Meléndez Reference Galindo and Meléndez2010), this measure was abandoned when President Santos came to power as part of an effort to improve tax collection efficiency.

Further, a 1959 measure to stimulate exports, known as the Vallejo Plan, allows Colombian companies to claim total or partial exemption from customs duties (such as tariffs and VAT) when they import raw materials, intermediate inputs, capital goods and spare parts that are destined for the manufacture of export goods. The Vallejo Plan was intended to incentivise the manufacturing industry and promote non-traditional exports. However, it ended up disproportionally favouring the coal sector (see Section 14.5). In addition, the 2016 fiscal reform reintroduced for the extractives sector the Certificate for Tax Rebate, a credit that can be applied to taxes on income, custom duties and other taxes.

Besides the tax expenditures just described, large-scale coal mining has also benefited from an exemption from special taxes because of its geographical proximity to Venezuela. In 2001, a tax relief measure was introduced to support the economy of border areas, exempting liquid combustibles distributed by the national oil company Ecopetrol from VAT, import duty and the ‘global’ tax on gasoline and diesel. This measure was initially supposed to be temporary but was extended and modified on several occasions. In 2007, the exemption was restricted to big consumers, or those consuming on average more than 20,000 gallons a month. As a result, there were fewer beneficiaries from the measure; however, one of these was the large-scale coal industry. The subsidy was eliminated in 2010 as part of tax reform in the Santos administration.

The coal sector, like the rest of the mining industry, is also eligible to deduct royalties from its income tax (see Section 14.5). This measure cost the Colombian state more than COP 13 trillion (approximately USD 6.2 billion) between 2006 and 2012 (Congreso de la República 2014).

Some coal companies benefit from special conditions under the Private Property Recognition scheme, a legal provision establishing the royalty rate at 0.4 per cent or more of the production value. This compares with the general minimum rate of 5 per cent of the mining pit revenue for companies extracting up to 3 million tonnes annually; the rate is 10 per cent for companies extracting more than 3 million tonnes annually. This special regime applies to certain mining titles issued by the state to private individuals during the nineteenth century (intended to boost mining). It did not include environmental, technical or economic obligations until 2011, when the 0.4 per cent minimum royalty rate was introduced through a ruling by the Constitutional Court. Three of the 55 existing Private Property Recognitions are for coal (Pardo Becerra Reference Pardo Becerra2012), including one for a title owned by Cerrejón (Cerrejón 2010).

Regarding benefits from the provision of goods and services below market value, the mining sector receives special security and protection services by the Colombian government (CODHES 2011; Vélez-Torres Reference Vélez-Torres2014). This can take the form of providing information, escort and backing, as well as designing security protocols and managing dynamite stocks on site. Companies appear to be contributing to part of these costs but not all of them (Glencore 2015). This type of relationship between companies and the state is established formally in agreements between the Ministry of Defence and the companies themselves (Sarmiento Reference Sarmiento2008). However, these contracts are mostly kept secret under the argument of preserving national security (Tierra Digna 2015). In 2011, about 12,000 army and navy personnel were reported to be protecting extractive operations (Mining Colombia 2011).

In the category of relief from normal costs and procedures, an example of a subsidy is the use of the Project of National and Strategic Interest classification. Private projects that are deemed strategic for the social and economic development of the country are eligible for special procedures relating to environmental licensing and land ownership applications (González Espinosa Reference González Espinosa and Isaza2015). The Colombian Ministry of Mines and Energy lists four coal Projects of National and Strategic Interest, including mines operated by Cerrejón, Prodeco and Drummond Ltd. (MME 2018).

These are only some key examples that illustrate the diversity of subsidies to the (coal) mining industry and the mechanisms used to confer them. However, it is possible that coal mining companies benefit from additional subsidies through special conditions negotiated directly in the contracts they signed with the state (Tierra Digna 2015).

14.4 The Power Dynamics Behind Coal Subsidies in Colombia

Understanding why subsidies were originally introduced is essential for identifying the opportunities and challenges for their reform. Here we turn attention to the political strategies used by a particular coalition of actors in Colombia – comprising the national government, coal extraction companies and other mining companies – to introduce and maintain subsidies that benefit coal extraction. As Victor (Reference Victor2009) highlights, the politics of subsidies include both their demand from typically well-organised groups of private actors and their supply by government in the pursuit of specific policy goals (e.g. attracting foreign investment or fostering industrial development). The introduction of the special income tax deduction for investment in real productive fixed assets by President Uribe in 2003 (see Section 14.3) is an example of the latter.

Various authors have conceptualised the relations between policymakers, public officials and incumbent companies as an alliance interested in maintaining the status quo and resisting fundamental change (Geels Reference Geels2014; see Chapter 4). One example is the ‘minerals-energy complex’ in South Africa, which describes capital accumulation of fossil fuels companies backed by policymakers (Fine and Rustomjee Reference Fine and Rustomjee1996; see Chapter 13).

Building on Geels (Reference Geels2014) and Kern (Reference Kern2011), the approach we take is to explore the political strategies and factors behind coal subsidies by analysing different forms of power: discursive, instrumental and institutional. ‘Discursive’ forms of power refer to processes of elaborating and making public discourses, which shape not only what is being discussed (thus setting agendas) but also how issues are discussed (see the discussion of ideational factors in Chapter 1). A better understanding of how ideational factors influence the introduction, maintenance and removal of subsidies can be gleaned by examining how those advocating for or offering subsidies frame coal extraction and the benefits or ‘necessity’ of government support. ‘Instrumental’ forms of power refer to cases where actors use resources (e.g. positions of authority, money, access to media, personnel and networks) to achieve their goals and interests (see also Chapter 1). ‘Institutional’ forms of power refer to how elements embedded in political cultures and governance structures (or socio-political factors) are mobilised or contribute to shape the subsidies regime (see also Chapters 1 and 4).

14.4.1 Discursive Forms of Power

Exploiting natural resources has been a key pillar of modernisation efforts in Latin America since the 1950s and remains an essential component of economic development models across the region, notably with the global boom in commodity prices of the 2000s (Veltmeyer and Petras Reference Veltmeyer and Petras2014). The relationship between extraction and economic development has been a key narrative used by the region’s governments to legitimise the existence of incentives to the extractives sector.

In Colombia, the development model shifted noticeably towards the extractives sector during the Uribe administration (2002–10). A special role in fuelling economic development was given to both hydrocarbons and minerals extraction. The development of the energy and mining sectors, together with the democratic security policy,Footnote 2 was seen as the path for Colombia to become one of the leading economies in Latin America by 2019 (Insuasty Rodriguez et al. Reference Insuasty Rodriguez, Grisales and Gutierrez León2013). The government’s discourse on the special role of the mining sector in Colombia’s economic development was accompanied by statements on the need for foreign investment to fully develop Colombia’s mining potential – and therefore on the need to increase the country’s competitiveness by providing incentives to foreign investment.

During the first administration of Juan Manuel Santos (2010–14), resource extraction maintained its central role and was framed as one of the ‘locomotives of development’ in the National Development Plan (NDP 2010). In this period, the government also increasingly used the concept of ‘responsible mining’ (Presidencia de la República 2013; Santos Calderón Reference Santos Calderón2014). Since 2015, however, this metaphor was abandoned in response to the economic and legitimacy issues of the mining sector. A new ‘peace’ frame was introduced: the national government now justifies the importance and incentives given to the extractives sector based on its expected contribution to funding the peace process and its associated social programmes (González Espinosa Reference González Espinosa and Isaza2015).

This new frame not only ensures that the extractives sector is perceived as a key partner, or even an enabler, of the country’s new development era after the peace deal with FARC, but it also leads to distorted public perceptions about the actual importance of coal in Colombia’s economy and its actual contribution to the state’s income, as well as to the diffusion or suppression of some of the concerns raised about the sector’s socio-economic impacts. As the leading mining industry, coal has benefited from being included in a broader mining and energy package that levels out the particularities and differences between minerals and hydrocarbons. For instance, the differences in terms of revenues generated and scope of payments between the hydrocarbons and the mining sector are considerable. The extractive sector paid COP 35 trillion (USD 18.5 billion) to the Colombian state in 2013, but only COP 2.3 trillion (USD 1.2 billion) was from the mining sector. Of that, 85 per cent was paid by the three main coal companies, Cerrejón, Drummond and Prodeco (MME 2015a).

14.4.2 Instrumental Forms of Power

A key political factor behind the maintenance of subsidies to the coal sector in Colombia is the strengthening of a broad constellation of actors that include mining business associations and others that benefit from the subsidies regime. Traditionally, lobbying through business associations has been an effective way for mining companies to secure significant subsidies for the sector, as described in Section 14.5. Until 2014, there were three main business associations defending mining interests: the Colombian Chamber of Mining, the Association of Large-Scale Mining Sector and the Miners’ Association (Asomineros). However, they combined to create the Colombian Mining Association in order to improve bargaining positions and communication to the general public. This fusion implies that the Colombian Mining Association is now representing a very large portion of the mining industry, articulating and representing interests from operators, producers and goods and services providers to the sector.

As was the case with framing strategies, coal producers have partnered with the rest of the mining industry to benefit from a more powerful position when negotiating with the government. However, this partnering strategy also creates additional challenges for the large-scale coal sector. While facing its own reputational challenges, it now also indirectly faces criticism that was traditionally linked to other mining subsectors, such as the disastrous environmental impacts of mercury use in gold extraction. While the coal sector’s strategy had been to keep a low profile to reduce financial and operational risks deriving from social acceptance issues (González Espinosa Reference González Espinosa2013), large companies are now increasingly engaging in communication activities, using the media to respond to accusations and improve their image.

The large-scale coal sector has also been involved in important partnership initiatives with public institutions aimed either at improving the performance of the sector (e.g. the EITI) or at engaging in social programmes (e.g. Alianza Social, a programme through which mining companies made voluntary commitments with the National Agency for Overcoming Extreme Poverty). These initiatives have been useful platforms for the sector to interact with key policymakers at the national level. At the local level, coal companies and political leaders have historically been closely linked, including through the revolving-door channel (when policymakers join industries they used to regulate and vice versa) or through political campaign financing (Transparencia por Colombia 2014). For example, several former governors and other local political leaders have had a long-standing relationship with Cerrejón, from when the state still had a stake in the company (González Espinosa Reference González Espinosa2013).

14.4.3 Institutional Forms of Power

One key element in understanding government support to coal mining, including subsidies, is the historical legacy of internal conflict and the Colombian state’s weakness and lack of legitimacy among large sections of the population. In 1991, the country underwent a constitutional reform that sought to increase the presence of the state by devolving fiscal and political power to lower levels of government and expanding basic social services (Torres del Río Reference Torres del Río2015). These measures, together with defence efforts to deal with drug trafficking, paramilitary activities and guerrilla warfare, required considerable resources. The state thus needed revenues urgently and introduced successive fiscal reforms that would prioritise rapid revenue production (or limit specific expenditures such as regional transfers) instead of tax efficiency, a situation that has prevailed since the 1990s despite several attempts at structural reform (Olivera et al. Reference Olivera, Pachón and Perry2010). Indeed, royalties became one of the most important public revenues in resource-rich regions. In La Guajira, royalties reached an annual average of USD 23.6 million between 1985 and 2004; this amount increased along with production between 2005 and 2007 to an annual average of USD 105 million (FCFI 2009: 10).

At the same time, conditions established in loan agreements with the International Monetary Fund in 1998 and 2003 led to a series of privatisations and restructuring of the state. Compared to other Latin American countries, where structural adjustment and pro-market economic policies aimed to reduce the role of the state, Colombia intended to use these measures to strengthen the state’s administrative functions (Flórez Enciso Reference Flórez Enciso2001). This pursuit of short-term revenues partly explains why the economic policy of the 2000s prioritised the extractives sector and introduced incentives for mining. The thinking was that development of this sector would deliver a steady flow of rents for the state, as long as conditions were made attractive enough to foreign investors (Caballero Argáez and Bitar Reference Caballero Argáez and Bitar2015).

Another key dimension here is the fragmentation of political parties and lack of programmatic discipline, a result of modifications to the Constitution of 1991 concerning political parties’ representation in the Congress and also of powerful lobbying by interest groups (Pizarro Leongómez Reference Pizarro Leongómez and Gutiérrez2002). These political dynamics have favoured the expansion of nominal tax rates while simultaneously expanding tax exemptions (Salazar Reference Salazar2013).

14.5 Political Factors in the Introduction, Maintenance and Removal of Subsidies

This section describes how the political dynamics introduced earlier have shaped the establishment, maintenance and/or removal of two subsidies that have highly benefited the Colombian coal industry.

14.5.1 Plan Vallejo

Plan Vallejo was introduced under the Alberto Lleras administration at the end of the 1950s in response to a deep economic crisis characterised by a drop in the price of coffee, a crisis in foreign trade, structural unemployment and a decades-long agrarian conflict. The Plan, combined with tighter currency controls and import restrictions, aimed to boost the transformation of imported raw materials and subsequent export, as well as to expand Colombia’s export capacity (Garay Salamanca Reference Garay Salamanca1998). This effectively represented a shift from the import-substitution industrialisation model to a new model based on the promotion of non-traditional exports. As a result, non-coffee exports started to increase exponentially after the 1967 modifications to the currency exchange policy (Amézquita Zárate Reference Amézquita Zárate2009). This framing remains today: the Minister for Trade announced an expansion of the Plan at the end of 2016 with the aim of increasing exports from sectors other than mining and energy (Lacouture Reference Lacouture2016).

The 1960s economic policy change was also the result of a significant shift in the country’s politics. At that time, a political agreement known as the National Front (1958–74) had emerged after years of bipartisan violence and military dictatorship, where the two main political parties (the Liberal and Conservative Parties) alternated power during four presidential terms. Under these special political circumstances, clientelism deepened (Leal Buitrago and Dávila Ladrón de Guevara Reference Leal Buitrago and Dávila Ladrón de Guevara2010), bringing economic elites together and safeguarding the interests of the emerging bourgeoisie and old landowners around the patrimonial order and the generous profits from coffee exports and industrial production (Leal Buitrago Reference Leal Buitrago and González1996).

Although the Plan has gone through a series of modifications since its introduction, especially regarding its administration, its main terms are still being applied five decades later. However, the definition of ‘non-traditional exports’ has not been adjusted over time, even as the actual export mix has changed, and as a result – against the spirit of the initiative – the industry benefiting most from the policy has been coal mining. Along with the internationalisation of Colombia’s economy, the share of coal exports under Plan Vallejo increased from 3.2 per cent in 1985 to 27.2 per cent in 1990 (Garay Salamanca Reference Garay Salamanca1998). In 2015, over one-third of the exports made under the Plan consisted of coal (Granada López et al. Reference Granada López, Zárate Farias and Sierra Reyes2016).

The maintenance of Plan Vallejo was called into question by the World Trade Organization, whose Trade Policy Review Body identified the Plan as an export subsidy in 1996 and reported it to the Committee on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures (see also Chapter 7). Colombia was given until 2003 to phase out Plan Vallejo and other export-related incentives. Thanks to ‘heavy diplomatic artillery’, the country was granted a three-year extension (El Tiempo 2002). After further negotiations, Colombia managed to keep the Plan for raw materials and services, although it had to limit the scope with regard to capital goods and spare parts. Subsequently, during negotiations about a free trade agreement, the United States initially requested elimination of the Plan for raw materials. Once again, however, Colombia managed to keep it rolling; after negotiations, the trade agreement allowed Plan Vallejo to remain in place (El Tiempo 2005).

Pressure on the Plan not only came from outside but also from inside the country. In 2004, at a Presidential Summit of the Andean Community, President Uribe suggested dismantling Plan Vallejo if other Andean countries would do the same with similar instruments. This generated strong opposition not only from the coal sector but also from other export-oriented sectors that rely heavily on the Plan’s incentives to maintain their competiveness (Correa Reference Correa2004). This suggests that an important factor for the maintenance of the Plan is support and lobbying from other industries, such as flowers and textiles production, through broader business associations such as the National Association of Exporters (Analdex).

In summary, framing and instrumental strategies have been essential in ensuring that the industry keeps the conferred benefits despite both internal and external pressures. The strength of the discourse around the contribution of Plan Vallejo for Colombia’s industrial development, along with effective lobbying from a coalition of exporting industries, has enabled the Plan to remain legitimate in a different economic model than the one in which it originated. This example also illustrates how a policy that was not designed as a subsidy to the coal sector when it was introduced became one as a result of changes in the domestic and global economic context.

14.5.2 Royalties Rebate

In 2005, a decision by the National Tax and Customs Directorate allowed mining companies to deduct the royalties they pay from their income taxes. This measure was introduced in response to a formal request by Carlos Alberto Uribe, who was then the president of Asomineros (and is not a close relative of the ex-president). The business association argued that royalties are a cost for companies – although the Colombian Constitution establishes that royalties constitute a mandatory compensation to the state generated by the exploitation of non-renewable natural resources.

The decision marked a significant change in the institution’s interpretation of Colombia’s tax law, since it had itself responded negatively to the same request on two earlier occasions, in 1998 and 2004 (Proyecto de Ley 071 2014). In 2005, however, the National Tax and Customs Directorate argued that mining companies should be given the same treatment as the national oil company Ecopetrol and be allowed to discount royalties from their income taxes.

There have already been at least four attempts to remove the subsidy since its introduction: in November 2011, when the Senate discussed the government take from mining activities; in 2012, when the Liberal Party led a proposal to reform the royalties system; in 2013, when a group of congressmen and academics submitted a simple invalidity action to the State Council, and again in 2014 through a legislative proposal from Senator Julio Guerra Soto. The lawsuit filed in 2013 was ultimately successful. In October 2017, the State Council canceled the measure (Morales Manchego 2017).

This last example not only illustrates how powerful and well-organised private interests contributed to the introduction of a key subsidy to coal production in Colombia through instrumental strategies, but it also shows how the mining sector, dominated by coal companies, has made use of institutional means to get new subsidies in place. It also raises questions about accountability and democracy in relation to the subsidy’s introduction; despite the subsidy’s significant impact on the state’s spending capacity, and resulting indirect impacts on the Colombian population’s well-being, its adoption was made by a non-representative authority.

14.6 Conclusion

The Colombian case illustrates the diversity of subsidies that are provided to fossil fuel production. It provides insights into the varied and innovative framing strategies used by producers and the governments to justify the existence of fiscal incentives. It also suggests that a powerful actor coalition exists in Colombia beyond the coal sector itself, including not only other minerals producers but also the national government and, in some cases, other export sectors. While relying mainly on traditional instrumental strategies, the coal industry has also made efforts to develop innovative framing strategies while relying on institutional support from the national government to maintain existing or obtain new subsidies.

In Colombia, a complex set of objectives is being pursued by the government, not all of which relate to the energy or natural resources sectors. The Colombian example highlights issues of democratic legitimacy and accountability in the establishment of subsidies, as evidenced by the example of the royalty rebate. When the Colombian Congress discussed the 2016 fiscal reform, there was significant debate about a VAT increase – a measure known for placing a high burden on the poorer segments of the population – but little was said about sectoral subsidies, such as those described here benefiting coal mining. The Congress did not discuss the actual socio-economic benefits of such subsidies or the opportunity cost of maintaining them. This is nevertheless a crucial matter within the context of the peace agreement’s implementation. The process needs significant public resources, and peace is contingent on the well-being of and economic opportunities for Colombians in rural areas, which depend on how public resources are used.

The Colombian case offers insights into how historically inherited political and social factors have influenced the governance of the sector, including the provision and maintenance of subsidies. Many of these influential socio-political factors are shared with the rest of Latin America, as a result of the continent’s historical processes of integration in the global economy. A historical comparative assessment of the Colombian case with other Latin American fossil fuel and minerals producers – such as Brazil, Chile, Peru and Venezuela – would provide interesting perspectives on how domestic and global political and economic factors have interacted to shape the current subsidies regime for fossil fuel extraction in these countries. Understanding these interactions will be essential to effectively combine domestic and global strategies for reforming fossil fuel subsidies.

15 Reforming Egypt’s Fossil Fuel Subsidies in the Context of a Changing Social Contract

Tom S. H. Moerenhout
15.1 Introduction

In July 2014, as a very first measure under newly elected President Abdel Fattah el-Sisi, the Egyptian government drastically reformed domestic energy prices. It increased the prices of most petroleum products and electricity for a wide range of consumers including industry, commercial businesses and households. At the time these reforms were implemented, Egypt faced a disconcerting record-high fiscal deficit, public debt surpassing 100 per cent of the country’s gross domestic product (GDP) and the highest unemployment rate in decades, particularly among the country’s youth (World Bank 2017).

While this dire situation had been long in the making due to Egypt’s inequitable and excessive subsidisation system, the Arab Spring aggravated the country’s predicament. In the wake of unprecedented political instability – and a political revolution that led to the ousting of Hosni Mubarak in 2011 – both the Morsi and El-Sisi governments had expanded certain patronage packages, while growth rates dropped about 4 percentage points to below 2 per cent. To top things off, the net-hydrocarbon-importing country had faced international oil prices of around USD 100 per barrel in the preceding years. As a consequence, fossil fuel subsidies had become the largest government expenditure item, comprising 20 per cent of expenditures in 2013–14 (Moerenhout Reference Moerenhout2017).

In short, it was a situation of superlatives: fossil fuel subsidy reforms were exceptionally urgent, while the political climate appeared utterly hostile. At first sight, Egyptian politics appeared in disarray. Among other demands, a quest for more socio-economic justice and dignity was at the heart of the Arab Spring (Beissinger et al. Reference Beissinger, Jamal and Mazur2015). When Mohamed Morsi failed to deliver, mass protests supported by the military led to his arrest. By the time General El-Sisi (who had led the revolt against Morsi) became President El-Sisi, it was considered a substantial political risk to reform what was the country’s foremost method of distributing welfare.

It was to the surprise of many that the sizeable reforms were implemented with relatively little public, political and private opposition – notwithstanding the fact that they fundamentally contradicted the implicit social contract that had existed for decades. This chapter explains why political economy conditions in 2014 were actually exceptionally beneficial to the implementation of subsidy reforms. It does so with reference to ‘behavioural realist traditions’, i.e. theories on how heterogeneous stakeholders act and why. I first shortly summarise political developments since the Arab Spring in Egypt. Next, I explain behavioural realism and how to understand key stakeholder dynamics in Egypt. I then discuss each of these stakeholder dynamics in detail for the July 2014 reforms (with reference to the historical context). Finally, I discuss how these dynamics have changed since 2014, effectively constraining the government’s legitimacy.

15.2 Crisis and Political Turmoil in Post–Arab Spring Egypt

In February 2011, President Mubarak was ousted as a result of large street protests and a decision by the military to stay neutral. The key slogans of the revolution were a demand for dignity and socio-economic justice and opportunity. In late 2011, the Muslim Brotherhood won the parliamentary elections and its leader, Morsi, won the presidential election in June 2012. The Brotherhood was the most organised opposition group and had wide support among the many groups to which it offered social services. In the end, Morsi won with a narrow margin in the second round against Mubarak’s former prime minister, Amhed Shafik.

The subsequent efforts of President Morsi and the Brotherhood to consolidate political power came at the expense of countering the economic crisis. As Morsi’s popularity decreased and he repeatedly antagonised the military establishment, the military strongly supported street protests, which quickly grew to more than a million people across Egypt. In early July 2013, the military intervened, officially ‘on behalf of the people’; by many, it was heralded as a de facto coup. The army removed Morsi and the Brotherhood from power and installed an interim government until new presidential elections were held. The leader of the armed forces, General El-Sisi, gained a huge amount of popularity during this time. The Muslim Brotherhood was removed (by force) from Egyptian politics.

In the July 2014 election, Sisi was elected in the first round by more than 90 per cent of the vote. The election was recognised internationally and by all opposition parties. His first measure in office was to reform the country’s fossil fuel subsidies. From 2014 to 2016, Sisi’s popularity decreased as the impact of reforms was painful and accusations of governmental corruption were rampant. In 2015, Sisi had to replace his entire government because of corruption allegations. Furthermore, he used repressive tactics to reduce potential domestic opposition.

While there were positive results from the necessary but drastic domestic reforms, the resulting fiscal breathing space was used to pursue further reforms in August 2016. This second round of large, structural reforms was required to unlock an urgent International Monetary Fund (IMF) loan. Reforms included energy pricing increases, the introduction of a value-added tax and the free floating of the Egyptian pound. These measures led to a spike in inflation, which further increased Sisi’s unpopularity. At the time of writing, it is best to understand Egypt’s reform process as a country walking on a balancing cord in a socio-political hurricane (Moerenhout Reference Moerenhout2017).

15.3 Behavioural Realism and the Implementation of Fossil Fuel Subsidy Reform
15.3.1 The Nature and Pace of Reforms: Stakeholders Matter Most

The failure to reform fossil fuel subsidies is primarily due to the political economy aspects of reform (Victor Reference Victor2009). Many analysts (from the IMF, the World Bank and the Global Subsidies Initiative) point to a maze of conditions that explain why reforms are successful or not, including timing, political regime, internal coordination, interest-group behaviour and technical characteristics of reform (Beaton et al. Reference Beaton, Gerasimchuk and Laan2013; IMF 2013a, 2013b; Kojima Reference Kojima2016). While it is clear that different conditions affect each other and that a successful reform outcome is causally complex, it is possible to understand (and, to a certain extent, predict) the political arena by understanding the dynamics among stakeholders. A behavioural realist stakeholder assessment has the advantage of recognising that stakeholders reach decisions in heterogeneous ways.

What does this mean? In general, it means that a political economy analysis of subsidy reform starts with how stakeholders actually behave rather than with how they should rationally behave to achieve the economically best possible subsidy reform process. It is logical that organisations concerned with macroeconomic stability (such as the IMF and World Bank) prescribe gradual reform as a key to successful long-term subsidy reform. This would be the wisest path from an economically rational standpoint. A behavioural realist school of thought argues that this does not coincide with the political reality under which many subsidy reforms take place.

Behavioural realism argues that different stakeholders make choices in different ways. Some stakeholders act rationally and will decide on exercising pressure based on the distributive impact of reforms, their interest and their potential influence (Baron Reference Baron2013). As described later, in the Egyptian context, the military and political opposition parties behaved in a more rational way. Other stakeholders, however, do not necessarily act as economically rational individuals. This is where behavioural realism innovates: by looking at the psychological drivers of citizens. It is without a doubt that citizens can be a powerful opposition group to subsidy reforms. This was particularly the case in Egypt, where they had demonstrated their power twice in three years’ time.

Therefore, behavioural realism argues that analysing stakeholders’ interests from a mere conventional rational choice point of view is insufficient to predict political outcomes (Kahneman Reference Kahneman2013). To assess the behaviour of citizens, behavioural realism relies on ‘system justification theory’ and ‘loss aversion’. The latter is the notion in behavioural economics that explains people’s preference for avoiding losses instead of acquiring equal gains. The former explains how individuals tend to behave when various belief systems conflict with one another. For example, while reform might be economically disadvantageous, citizens may have different dominant belief systems at the time of reform (such as fear of physical security or patriotism). System justification theory finds that people are often willing to accept rationally negative consequences to remain consistent with such dominant belief systems at the time of reform (Blasi and Jost Reference Blasi and Jost2006).

System justification theory and framing are closely related. A key insight of the framing literature is that individuals do not just make decisions based on individual preferences but in evaluation of a social context (Madrian Reference Madrian2014). System justification theory would assess what types of conflicting and dominant belief systems are shared among citizens so that frames can be developed to maximise reform acceptance. In this way, the behavioural realist framework employed here focuses on the role of actors opposed and in favour of reform and how framing may influence such actors within the window of opportunity to change socio-political structures – the social contract – in Egypt (see Chapter 1).

15.3.2 A Behavioural Realist Framework for Studying Fossil Fuel Subsidy Reform in Egypt

Researching Egypt’s 2014 subsidy reforms benefits from a behavioural realist approach. As Table 15.1 shows, the Egyptian reforms were of a ‘big bang’ nature. Egypt’s 2014 reforms are a good example of opportunistic reform. Many subsidy reforms in countries with traditionally low prices happen in shocks and during windows of opportunity, most often at the time of an observable fiscal crisis or after an election. Public choice scholars often speak of the ‘crisis hypothesis’ and the ‘honeymoon hypothesis’ to explain why structural reforms tend to be implemented in such an opportunistic fashion (Williamson Reference Williamson1994).

Table 15.1 Egypt’s 2014 and 2016 subsidy reforms

Key July 2014 price increasesKey August 2016 price increases
Gasoline78% (gasoline-80), 41% (gasoline-92), 7% (gasoline-95)47% (gasoline-80), 35% (gasoline-92), price allowed to float (gasoline-95)
Diesel64%
Kerosene64%31%
Natural gas33–204% (energy-intensive industries), >200% (low users), 500% (medium users), 700% (high users)±50% (low to medium users), 33% (heavy users)
Heavy fuel oil50% (cement), 30% (bricks, other users), 40% (bakeries and food)7% (most users)
Electricity<50% (low users), ±17% (commercial and other residential users)Up to 40% residential, up to 20% commercial (mainly medium and heavy users)
Liquefied petroleum gasExcluded from reforms87%
Source: Collected by author.

As the government is primarily responsible for the planning and implementation of reforms, the possibility of reform ultimately depends on its assessment of the need for reform, as well as whether key stakeholder groups are ready to accept such reforms without threatening the government’s legitimacy. In Egypt, I argue that legitimacy depends on three key stakeholder dynamics: (1) the social contract that guides the relationship between the state and its people, with the state composed of the government and the military, but with government primarily responsible towards its citizens, (2) the relationship between the military and the government and (3) the presence or absence of political alternatives to the government (Figure 15.1).

Figure 15.1 Stakeholder dynamics in Egypt.

First, the historical contract between the state and the people of Egypt has closely resembled that of other countries in the region. The key characteristic of that social contract is the exchange of people’s loyalty to the country’s authoritarian regime for a government-driven distribution of welfare. In practice, this means that the state was given a monopoly on Egypt’s economy, including the exploitation of hydrocarbons and other resources. In practice, the ruling government exploited the economy for its own benefit and without profound public oversight. In exchange, the government was expected to provide public employment and subsidised food, energy, housing, social security and so on (Fattouh et al. Reference Fattouh, Moerenhout and Sen2016). Taking away fossil fuel subsidies not only hurts people’s welfare, but it can also be a symbolic measure indicative of a changing social contract. Much of what Sisi has done so far is change the social contract unidirectionally: less distribution of welfare but a maintaining of authoritarian power.

Second, the relationship between the Egyptian military and government is one of checks and balances. The government needs the military to protect the country and, importantly, to support it in the domestic application of its policies. In simple terms, the government uses the security sector to be the ‘stick’ to ensure civil acquiescence to its regime. When people revolt against the state because of breach of the social contract, they often do this in the first place against the government and only secondarily against the military. This is because the military is believed to provide checks and balances to the government. In Egypt during the Arab Spring, for example, the army acted against Mubarak and Morsi. In reality, the military is a huge institutional apparatus that protects the political and economic power it shares with government. In practice, such interests are often linked to the energy sector, to large infrastructure projects and so forth. This makes the military a key stakeholder in large reforms.

Third, the government acts to silence political opposition. Political opposition attempts to manifest as a realistic alternative to rule the country. It seeks to influence the perception of stakeholder groups that it can cover their interests better than the current government.

15.4 Military Support and the Absence of Political Alternatives During the July 2014 Reforms

When Sisi implemented subsidy reforms in July 2014, two out of three constraining factors were mitigated, which made the implementation of fossil fuel subsidy reforms far easier. He had the support of the military, and there was no effective political alternative with the repression of the Muslim Brotherhood.

15.4.1 Why the Military Mattered to the Implementation of the July 2014 Reforms

Support of the military for fossil fuel subsidy reforms was necessary for two reasons. First, the military had strong interests in fossil fuel subsidies and could therefore be an opposing actor. Second, the military was needed to showcase strength and prevent unrest following reforms. The fact that President Sisi spent his life as an officer in the Egyptian army improved relationships. The military had been historically involved in non-military manufacturing, including energy-intensive industries (CMI 2013: 2), and in fuel black markets. Under Mubarak, however, many business deals went to private capitalists or internal security forces (Makara Reference Makara2013: 345–46). This was one of the reasons why the military ultimately did not suppress the Arab Spring protests (Barany Reference Barany2011; Akkas and Ozekin Reference Akkas and Ozekin2014: 83).

After Mubarak’s ousting, the military government re-established its economic and political position. In his one-year rule, President Morsi tried to reverse some of these steps and centralise power at the expense of the military’s political power (Brown Reference Brown2013: 45–50). He also pushed an Islamist agenda in which he counted on military support in safeguarding security. This challenge on two fronts made the military increasingly wary of its relationship with Morsi (CMI 2013: 4). At the same time, Morsi sought more oversight over the Suez Canal expansion project at the expense of the military (Marshall Reference Marshall2015: 11–12). Eventually, the military opposed Morsi and the Muslim Brotherhood and started actively supporting massive demonstrations with the assistance of Saudi Arabia and the United Arab Emirates (Marshall Reference Marshall2015: 18).

After his election as president, Sisi immediately extended the military’s influence on major manufacturing, transportation and infrastructure projects. Their leading role in the Suez Canal expansion project was also reaffirmed. He also involved the military in other projects, such as national bank loans to a subsidiary of Tharwa Petroleum, the only state-owned national oil company involved in upstream activities (Marshall Reference Marshall2015: 14–18). As such, fossil fuel subsidy reform could be advantageous for the military because it would strengthen the capacity of Egypt’s oil sector to pay off its debts to foreign operators. Via Tharwa Petroleum, the military would then benefit from foreign investors re-entering the Egyptian market (McMurray and Ufheil-Somers Reference McMurray and Ufheil-Somers2013). At the same time, following frequent negotiations with the military, Sisi decided to drop liquefied petroleum gas (LPG) from the 2014 subsidy reforms. It is believed that this is because the military was a key stakeholder benefiting from black markets for LPG cylinders (James Reference James2014). In exchange for these benefits, not only did the military support fossil fuel subsidy reform, but it also supported Sisi’s reign, which resembles that of a return to a repressive and authoritarian state (Khalaf Reference Khalaf2016).

15.4.2 The Absence of Political Alternatives and Prior Subsidy Reform Under Morsi

Because of its strong organisation, the Muslim Brotherhood was able to boost the numbers of protesters when it united with nationalistic civil society movements to oust Mubarak. It is also a key reason why it won the subsequent elections. However, the goal of replacing the Mubarak regime with an Islamic regime appeared far less important for most demonstrators than the primary economic reasons and the secondary demands for civil and political freedom (Beissinger et al. 2014: 4). The Muslim Brotherhood, however, spent most of its one-year reign on consolidating power. When the military intervened and removed Morsi from power, they also subsequently crushed the Muslim Brotherhood. Thereby, they effectively nullified the most organised opposition party.

In retrospect, the short time period that the Islamist government under President Morsi was able to govern mostly served as a catalyst for the subsequent El-Sisi presidency to actually implement substantial reforms. It confirmed the nationalistic sentiment that had been prevalent in the wake of the Arab Spring (Akkas and Ozekin Reference Akkas and Ozekin2014: 80) and the need for economic reforms. This is the platform on which Sisi would announce fossil fuel subsidy reforms. At the same time, the Brotherhood had become the scapegoat for the enduring financial crisis, with most political parties supporting its removal from power (Butter Reference Butter2013: 13). It also increased the popularity of the army, which gave Sisi a huge amount of political capital at the start of his presidency to actually implement reforms.

That said, Sisi benefited from some key fossil fuel subsidy reforms Morsi had initiated. In the 2012–13 period, prices for gasoline more than doubled for high-end vehicles, fuel oil prices increased by one-third for non-energy-intensive industries and by half for energy-intensive industries, while they rose by one-third for electricity generation. Electricity prices for households also increased on average by 16 per cent (Sdrazlevich et al. Reference Sdrazlevich, Randa, Younes and Albertin2014: 45). Natural gas prices also increased for residential, commercial and industrial consumers. However, the real prices for all refined products actually decreased due to inflation (Clarke Reference Clarke2014). In addition to actual price increases, some institutional innovations were prepared. One success was the development of an electronic tracking system to monitor fuel movements between suppliers and filling stations aimed at cutting fuel smuggling to Turkey and Gaza (James Reference James2014). The result was the uncovering of hundreds of fuel stations that only existed on paper (Butter Reference Butter2013: 14–15).

15.5 Energy Subsidy Reform and a Unidirectionally Changing Social Contract

Inevitably, the rationalisation of energy prices was going to impact a large part of his constituency, particularly lower- and middle-income households that had lambasted the Mubarak regime for not taking care of its people. To achieve acceptability for the reforms, Sisi attempted to mitigate distributional losses and change the perception of reform. He did this by playing into the belief systems of Egyptians via a wide variety of measures (described later). In this way, he tried to achieve buy-in for a structural reformation of the social contract. While in 2014 such a change may have appeared successful, his subsequent governing style resembles a return to the security state. This section shows that this attempt for a unidirectional change of the social contract has the potential to backfire on the regime.

15.5.1 A Crisis of Unprecedented Proportions and the July 2014 Reforms

By the time Morsi was ousted, Egypt’s debt surpassed 100 per cent of its GDP, the Egyptian government risked defaulting on its debts, GDP growth had dropped from 5 per cent pre-revolution to around 2 per cent in 2012–14 and unemployment had risen, particularly among the country’s youth (about 40 per cent of those aged between 20 and 24). At the same time, there was widespread inflation (rates were around 10 per cent after the Arab Spring) and a record-level budgetary deficit (nearly 14 per cent of GDP in 2012–13). Rural-urban income disparities also were on the rise, and there were considerable disruptions in fuel and electricity supply (Butter Reference Butter2013: 4; Paciello Reference Paciello2013: 2; ERPIC 2014; James Reference James2014; Muthuthi Reference Muthuthi2014). The only economic indicator that looked somewhat acceptable was the balance of payments, and that was only due to a generous financial support package from Gulf countries.

Energy subsidies were one of the main causes of this bleak picture. Expenditure on fuel subsidies had grown with a compound annual growth rate of 26 per cent between 2002 and 2013 (Clarke Reference Clarke2014), amounting to about USD 21 billion, which represented 8.5 per cent of GDP (Griffin et al. Reference Griffin, Laursen and Robertson2016: 2) and 20 per cent of public expenditure (El-Katiri and Fattouh Reference El-Katiri and Fattouh2015). The July 2014 reforms were steep price increases affecting various consumer groups and nearly all fuels and energy products, with LPG being the one notable exception. Among the main transport fuel price increases were a 64 per cent hike in diesel prices, a 78 per cent hike in gasoline-80 and a 40 per cent hike in gasoline-92. Kerosene prices also rose for all users by 64 per cent. Fuel oil prices did not increase for the electricity sector but did for the cement sector, food industry and other users. Natural gas prices increased substantially for all energy-intensive industries and for electricity generation. Residential natural gas prices were staggered by consumption levels, with larger consumers paying more; still, small-scale consumers saw their price double. Finally, electricity prices increased for all consumer groups but were also blocked to eventually allow for cross-subsidisation (Clarke Reference Clarke2014: 4–5).

15.5.2 Modest Mitigation Measures to Cover Distributional Losses

Besides using communication campaigns to affect belief systems (see below), the government also introduced several compensation measures to ease stakeholder reluctance about reform. As Egypt’s non-subsidy social safety net was poorly developed, a few short-term measures that strongly resembled conventional social contract politics were used to send out a message that Egypt’s government wanted to cushion the effects of the reform. With the crucial help of a USD 12 billion package from Gulf countries, Egypt implemented two stimulus packages in August 2013 and January 2014. Minimum wages in the public sector were raised, even though it increased the budget deficit (Muthuthi Reference Muthuthi2014: 4). This financial assistance from the Gulf also included USD 3 billion in fuel supplies to reduce the fuel shortages that had been so prominent during Morsi’s reign (Butter Reference Butter2013: 13–14).

Right before the fossil fuel subsidy reform, the government also extended the food subsidy system to include 20 new products (Clarke Reference Clarke2014). This was intended to reduce concerns about food price increases as a consequence of fossil fuel subsidy reforms. At the same time, the fact that it was implemented before and explicitly linked to the fossil fuel subsidy reform reduced the risk of protest due to loss aversion among the people. When a compensation measure is implemented before subsidy reforms and explicitly linked to such reforms, people are more likely to become attached to this compensation measure and, consequently, feel relatively less averse towards the associated subsidy reforms. Finally, there was a promise to keep LPG – a fuel widely used by poorer households – subsidised (El-Katiri and Fattouh Reference El-Katiri and Fattouh2015). As far as transport goes, there were several concerns (see below). In response, the government offered some free transport in army buses (James Reference James2014).

15.5.3 Psychological Drivers of Citizens at the Time of Reform

Relative to the size of the fossil fuel subsidy reforms, the aforementioned compensation measures were largely insufficient to ease the welfare losses of a large part of Egyptian households. The reason why the Egyptian population was willing to accept such reforms goes beyond mitigation measures. It is difficult to know whether Egyptians were simply tired of conflict or they were genuinely open to redrawing the blueprints of how Egypt was managed. However, it does seem likely that the government’s use of the carrot and stick – as well as the characteristics of reform – certainly played into the belief systems of Egyptians and, as such, increased the acceptability and support for reform. It did so in primarily four interdependent ways.

First, the timing of reform meant that Sisi could take full advantage of the so-called honeymoon period. In the wake of Morsi’s ousting, General El-Sisi and the military had gained popularity. Unlike Morsi, El-Sisi was also elected in one round and with about 90 per cent of the vote, giving him extensive political capital (James Reference James2014). El-Sisi used a large part of this political capital immediately by addressing fossil fuel subsidies, which had been left untouched by the transitional government (Paciello Reference Paciello2013: 3). System justification theory supports the notion that to be consistent with their electoral choice, people more easily trust the newly elected leader, even if his choices contradict their material interests (Blasi and Jost Reference Blasi and Jost2006).

Second, the immediate announcement of fossil fuel subsidy reform and the communication around subsidy reform left no space for people to doubt that reform was actually happening. By pressing the inevitability of reform, Sisi reduced a status quo bias as change was imminent, not just a potential plan. Behavioural psychology has shown that when change is certain, people adjust more easily to the idea of it (Blasi and Jost Reference Blasi and Jost2006). Egyptians were also aware that there were no real political alternatives. After three years of political turmoil, Sisi had a firm grip on power. In a ruthless display of power, he had cracked down violently on the apparatus of the Muslim Brotherhood. At the same time, public protests had been banned in 2014. This discouraged demonstrations (fear as a dominant belief system), particularly with the awareness that the leading general had just been elected president.

Third, the framing of reform and complementary measures linked back to the key demands protesters called for during the Arab Spring. Communication campaigns addressed the inequitable nature of fossil fuel subsidies by explaining how they disproportionally reached the rich. This argument fell in line with the protesters’ argument for more socio-economic justice. It also stressed the urgency of the measure to revive the Egyptian economy, which also played into the major concern that had caused the country’s two popular uprisings. Right after his election, Sisi also increased taxes on the wealthy and imposed a new capital gains tax on business. These moves got him praise, as they showed a contrast with the Mubarak regime (Marshall Reference Marshall2015: 19) and increased the belief that the government was serious about its intention to revive the Egyptian economy.

Fourth, a key element of Sisi’s strategy was to target the nationalistic sentiment that had been so dominant in the uprisings (patriotism constituting a dominant belief system). Sisi stressed the responsibility and need for ‘shared sacrifice’ (a key slogan in the fossil fuel subsidy reform communication campaign) to repair Egypt’s economy, while admitting that the price increases themselves were unpopular. He mixed the promise of renewed economic opportunity with a Nasseresque national pride to gain the most effective support for reform possible. One notable example outside of fossil fuel subsidy reform is the Suez Canal expansion project, which increased national sentiment by limiting sales of investment certificates to Egyptian nationals.

15.5.4 Intra-Governmental Coordination and External Support for Subsidy Reform

It is a consensus among international experts (such as the IMF, World Bank and the Global Subsidies Initiative) that subsidy reform requires a large level of international coordination and a supportive coalition. Stakeholder interests and influence gave the government a nearly blank cheque for economic reforms in July 2014. On the side of the government, Sisi had a predominantly technocratic cabinet that also favoured reform. This in itself already reduced internal competition within the high ranks of government. Sisi also took on leadership over reform and profiled himself as such externally. That said, even before Sisi’s election, Egypt’s government was working with internal and external experts (such as the Global Subsidies Initiative and the World Bank’s Energy Sector Management Assistance Programme) to prepare an extensive public relations campaign. This effort was essential given the severe lack of awareness about the costs and inequity of fossil fuel subsidies. Apart from some initial inconsistencies, there generally was consistency in messaging, from everyday governmental communication in the media to Sisi’s widely broadcasted televised speech (Clarke Reference Clarke2014).

Sisi could also count on the supporting stance of several other stakeholders. Already for years an informal coalition of businesses, industry, commentators and academics had argued in favour of meaningful subsidy reform (Clarke Reference Clarke2014). The media were also generally supportive of Sisi’s proposed reforms (Marshall Reference Marshall2015: 19) and mainly focused on the impact on households and on what the government could do to protect the poor. Both the general media and social media appeared to react in a balanced manner towards the reforms (Clarke Reference Clarke2014). Because of this wide coalition and consensus, other political stakeholders generally did not strongly oppose reform. Most political parties saw their role marginalised following Sisi’s landslide election. Some leftist political parties did oppose reform, but mainly on the grounds that they wanted more preparation, particularly with regard to the impact on households (Clarke Reference Clarke2014). Similarly, the wealthy elite did not oppose reforms, even though there was a clear direction from the government to target subsidies better. As in many parts of the middle class, a fatigue and desire for order and stability made the wealthy favour Sisi’s proposed reforms (The Economist 2015).

The most vocal actor opposing subsidy reform was the transportation sector. Transport operators believed that they were providing a public service and that this ought to remain supported. President Sisi and the prime minister negotiated with transport operators to make sure that they would not resort to increasing prices in the face of uncertainty. However, transport operators did increase their prices when subsidy reform was announced and even resorted to strikes and demonstrations in Cairo, Sinai and Alexandria (Clarke Reference Clarke2014). Many drivers, however, are not linked to particular political parties or associations, and the drivers’ union was fairly weak. This explained how their opposition was relatively well contained during the implementation process.

15.5.5 How People’s Belief Systems Changed, but Only Temporarily

Even though many people remained sceptical about the ability of the government to redistribute and invest savings from the subsidy reforms (El-Katiri and Fattouh Reference El-Katiri and Fattouh2015), system justification theory (Blasi and Jost Reference Blasi and Jost2006) suggests that people can easily extend the acceptability of a government within one issue (overthrowing Morsi, favouring economic recovery, measures targeting the rich, etc.) to another (actually being able to achieve tangible economic progress via subsidy reforms). The characteristics of reforms and actions by Sisi, as mentioned earlier, fundamentally altered the framing of subsidy reform from a measure that affirmed corruption during Mubarak to a necessity for economic revival under Sisi.

As in other countries in the Middle East and North Africa, the gradual acceptance that subsidy reforms were necessary to counter deteriorating economies represented a significant shift in the belief systems of Egyptian people (Moerenhout et al. Reference Moerenhout, Vezanis and Westling2017). The communication campaign approach used by Sisi was also in stark contrast to Morsi’s approach and generally to how the earlier social contract had operated for decades. It showed an understanding on the part of the government that convincing the Egyptian people of a particular policy had become a necessity to progress on impactful reforms.

At this stage, the social contract began to shift tangibly. The Egyptian people accepted that the government would no longer support a subsidy-based distribution of welfare, and in exchange, the government spent more effort to communicate its policies to the people. Nonetheless, the people’s expectations were high. The government promised more economic opportunity and more targeted social safety mechanisms for those in need. In the years after the subsidy reforms, these expectations were not met. Consequently, and also as a result of Sisi’s repressive mode of governing, a large part of the Egyptian people started to notice that the social contract was changing unidirectionally.

15.6 Frustration with the Change of the Social Contract Since the 2014 Reforms

In the two years following the July 2014 reforms, Sisi’s popularity decreased, as it became increasingly obvious that the social contract was changing in just one direction. Sisi was not able to meet the people’s expectations to deliver more targeted social assistance or to spur domestic economic growth. At the same time, Sisi was increasingly using repressive tactics to silence and prevent domestic opposition. Civil society organisations played a crucial role in mobilising Arab Spring protesters. The ability to freely organise during the Mubarak years covertly shifted the power balance in the social contract. Sisi attempted to undermine such a civil society response to his authoritarian rule.

Already in 2014, the price increases were very unpopular among the poor and lower-middle-income households, subsequently reducing the popularity of Sisi with this group (Clarke Reference Clarke2014). Notwithstanding Sisi’s efforts to better target social assistance to the poorer segments of Egyptian society, the slow pace of progress in this field does not re-establish trust in Sisi. On the eve of the 2014 reform, social safety nets had low coverage and inadequate financing and often disproportionally targeted the non-poor. Given other stakeholder dynamics (see below), strengthening social safety nets is a key priority for the El-Sisi government to retain trust in the reform process. Even though the government is working together with the World Bank to strengthen two large social safety net programmes (World Bank 2015), progress has been slow, while the Egyptian people feel the negative impact of the reforms (Moerenhout et al. Reference Moerenhout, Vezanis and Westling2017).

At the same time, Egypt is still waiting for economic growth. The tourism sector has not recovered, and there are overall few new job opportunities. The drop in international oil prices has been a blessing and a curse. On the one hand, it reduces the gap between international prices and domestic prices. On the other hand, Gulf countries stalled financial aid packages because of their own internal fiscal problems (Aman Reference Aman2016). This has increased scepticism about Sisi’s competence to restore the economy. Also, wealthy Egyptians who favoured stability in 2014 are increasingly discontent as they feel the grip of Sisi’s policies that generally favour the poor (Walsh Reference Walsh2016). As far as the military is concerned, the 2014 reforms caused a shift in production and investment to the construction sector (Griffin et al. Reference Griffin, Laursen and Robertson2016). However, not all construction projects have yielded results as fast as hoped. For example, while the jury on the Suez Canal expansion is still out, many analysts believe that the government’s estimate of additional revenue was on the ambitious side (Egyptian Streets 2016).

On top of all of this, Sisi was obliged to pass a second round of large reforms to access a USD 12 billion IMF loan in August 2016. These reforms included energy price increases, the introduction of a value-added tax and a free floating of the Egyptian pound. The result was a large and unpopular inflation spike that reached almost 20 per cent in November 2016 (Moerenhout Reference Moerenhout2017).

The 2016 reforms and delay in results seem to have changed the perception of many poor and middle-income groups. One part of system justification theory is that people easily resort back to stereotyping. This played out in Egypt as the trust put in Sisi in July 2014 eroded very fast and was replaced with the traditional stereotype of a corrupt and incompetent government. While there had been allegations of corruption in the social security sector earlier on (James Reference James2014), a painful reality check occurred in the summer of 2015 when Sisi was forced to replace his entire government due to corruption scandals (Moerenhout et al. Reference Moerenhout, Vezanis and Westling2017).

15.7 Conclusion

Tough economic reforms and Sisi’s repressive mode of governing have frustrated the Egyptian people. The hope for a sustainable, new social contract seems stuck in the history books. In 2014, that hope had seemed real. The Arab Spring had demonstrated the strength of the people vis-à-vis government. The key priority was socio-economic justice and economic growth. At the same time, the government had a great window of opportunity to pass the difficult reforms needed to restart the engine of economic growth. These reforms included an alteration of the social contract: government could no longer provide across-the-board subsidies. At the same time, Sisi seemed aware of the need to communicate why these reforms were necessary and to ask for ‘shared sacrifice’. Whether or not the government intended it, the messaging and combination of measures played into the behavioural psychology of the Egyptian people, which ultimately led to a smooth implementation of energy pricing reforms.

Soon after 2014, however, the hope for a durable alteration of the social contract disappeared. It became increasingly clear that Sisi was attempting to alter the social contract unidirectionally by clinging to an authoritarian mode of power, while economic pressure on the population kept growing. His popularity decreased because of the negative impacts of subsidy reform. His Nasseresque political gamble to unite the country under a nationalistic discourse until the realisation of economic results failed. He had to replace his entire government due to corruption allegations, and the development of targeted social safety nets was much slower than anticipated. Finally, because of a drop in oil prices, financial aid from Gulf countries was cut off, leaving Sisi no choice but to implement more painful reforms to unlock IMF loans.

Egypt’s situation will be unsustainable if reforms do not quickly spur the engine for economic growth. Unless it provides tangible improvements for its citizens, an unpopular and repressive government that is reforming to comply with the conditions of international financial institutions will be at significant risk of political instability. Fossil fuel subsidy reforms that constitute unidirectional changes to the social contract are not durable in the long run.

16 Actors, Frames and Contexts in Fossil Fuel Subsidy Reform The Case of Trinidad and Tobago

Michelle Scobie
16.1 Introduction

Small island states tend to frame global climate change action in terms of climate justice and environmental stewardship. In fossil fuel–producing developing states, debates about fossil fuel subsidies also include redistributive justice frames, for instance, that the population has a normative right to cheap energy. The question is, how are these contradictory frames reflected in countries that are simultaneously small island developing states and fossil fuel producers, and do other frames also feature in their debate on fossil fuel subsidy reform?

This chapter examines how fossil fuel subsidies and their reform have been addressed in Trinidad and Tobago, a petroleum producer and small island developing state. It puts forward an analytical framework of actors, frames and contexts that have been central to the global and local subsidy reform debate. The chapter uses this framework to understand the particular context of a small island state that is heavily dependent on hydrocarbon exports for its socio-economic development and that has had entrenched producer and consumer subsidies (in the electricity and transport sectors) since the 1970s. The chapter illustrates how different actors use different frames (e.g. environmental stewardship, economic prudence, climate and energy justice) in the subsidy reform debate and how historical and economic contexts are relevant to the reform process.

16.2 The Nature of Fossil Fuel Subsidies in Trinidad and Tobago

Caribbean small island developing states share a history of colonial exploitation (Baptiste and Rhiney Reference Baptiste and Rhiney2016), with a peripheral economic development model that kept an entrenched dependence on colonial powers even after independence. Caribbean island states have many of the vulnerabilities of small island developing states that make their survival a remarkable challenge (Fry Reference Fry2005; Mertz et al. Reference Mertz, Halsnæs and Olesen2009): small size and populations, limited resources, economies that are vulnerable to external economic shocks and dependent on tourism and primary production, especially agriculture, limited resilience to climate change, high levels of migration and limited commercial prospects due to their small scale and geographical position. Having suffered marginalisation and exploitation at the hands of industrial powers during colonialism, the region now suffers the deleterious effects of industrialisation through climate change impacts (Baptiste and Rhiney Reference Baptiste and Rhiney2016; Popke et al. Reference Popke, Curtis and Gamble2016). This includes extreme climatic events, such as floods, hurricanes and drought (Palanisamy et al. Reference Palanisamy, Becker and Meyssignac2012; Trotz and Lindo, Reference Trotz and Lindo2013), that come with adaptation and mitigation burdens (Rhiney Reference Rhiney2015).

Trinidad and Tobago has since 1857 used its petroleum industry as a pathway to social and economic development. Its undiversified economy is heavily dependent on hydrocarbon exports (i.e. petroleum, petroleum products and natural gas; IMF 2016). Since 1990, the hydrocarbons sector changed from being based on oil to mainly natural gas recovery, processing, downstream industries and export; it also has one of the largest liquefied natural gas processing plants in the world (GORTT 2017b). It has a population of about 1.3 million and a human development index of 0.772, which in 2014 placed it as sixty-fourth in the world and seventh in the Americas and the Caribbean (UNDP 2016). The country ranked sixteenth in the world in natural gas exports in 2014, with approximately 17.4 billion cubic meters of gas exported (CIA 2017). It has one of the highest per capita emissions in the world largely because of the size of its hydrocarbons industry compared to its small population. Together with all small island developing states, Trinidad and Tobago contributes to less than 1 per cent of global carbon emissions. However, the country is faced with the climate justice dilemmas of all small island developing states: delivering cheap fuel to its low-income groups and globally uncompetitive small business sector while also considering the environmental responsibilities of reducing emissions. The country’s petroleum output fell progressively after 2015, and fiscal accounts have been negatively affected by falling energy prices (IMF 2016). The national debate on the need to reduce or remove the fuel subsidy began in the 1990s, driven by falling global petroleum prices; the subsequent falling revenues made it difficult for the government to finance this social transfer.

Trinidad and Tobago has producer and consumer fuel subsidies for the hydrocarbon industry. Producer subsidies include fiscal investment incentives to exploit hydrocarbons and produce petrochemical products, written into production-sharing contracts between the government and large foreign (mainly multinational) companies. Far from removing these incentives, the industry’s argument is that the government’s incentives should continue or increase because the sector is now facing diminishing returns – i.e. reserves have fallen, and exploration for unexploited wells in deeper territorial waters is costlier and riskier than the near-shore wells drilled thus far. The incentives include preferential loans, royalty exemptions, depreciation allowances, tax credits, infrastructure allowances and support, research funding and exemptions from import duties on plant and machinery (Iwaro and Mwasha Reference Iwaro and Mwasha2010). Consumer subsidies include pre-tax vehicle fuel subsidies for public, commercial and industrial transportation; prices at the pump are fixed by the state and include the refinery price, excise duty, wholesale margin, retail margin, value-added tax, road improvement tax and the subsidy. The country also provides pre-tax electricity subsidies to domestic, commercial and industrial users. Negligible electricity production comes from renewables despite the government’s policy to provide incentives for the use of wind and solar power.

Most of the national fuel subsidy reform debate centres on the removal of transport fuel subsidies, for which disaggregated data are available (Imbert Reference Imbert2016c; Imbert and Khan Reference Imbert and Khan2016; Imbert and Raffoul Reference Imbert and Raffoul2017). Table 16.1 shows the main uses for transport fuels and how the subsidy has changed between 2011 and 2015.

Table 16.1 Transport fuels subsidised in Trinidad and Tobago

Type of fuelPrivate vehicles, luxury carsPrivate vehicles, economy carsCommercial/industrial transportPublic transportation vehicles2011 Subsidy claim values (TTD ‘000)2015 Subsidy claim values (TTD ‘000)
Premium236,223.25
Super1,634,208.93662,989.81
Regular26,301.565,111.55
Diesel2,407,590.11900,651.62
Liquefied petroleum gasa71,637.1076,877.81

a High incidence of use for domestic and commercial cooking.

Source: Ministry of Energy and Energy Industries 2016.

Pre-tax fuel subsidies for 2006–15 were on average 2 per cent of gross domestic product annually (TTD 31 billion, or about USD 4.6 billion) and strongly correlated to global crude prices (IMF 2016). Lower petroleum prices reduce the subsidy, but this also means that the government has less revenue to finance the subsidy and other social transfers. The transport subsidy disproportionately benefits higher-income groups; in 2014, the average monthly subsidy for the wealthiest households was 95 per cent higher than for low-income households (IMF 2016). In 2016, the drastic fall in national income gave impetus to reform arguments and paved the way for the removal of fuels subsidies for private transport vehicles and a reduction of fuel subsidies for public transportation and cargo vehicles. The country has almost universal electricity coverage; in 2012, 99.8 per cent of the population had access to electricity (World Bank 2016). The state-owned Trinidad and Tobago Electricity Company sells 27 per cent of the electricity it produces to residential clients, 57 per cent to industrial clients and 8 per cent to commercial customers. The subsidised electricity prices are the lowest among Caribbean small island developing states and globally competitive compared to electricity rates of about USD 0.10 per kilowatt hour (kWh) for the United States and USD 0.21 per kWh for Italy (which has one of the highest electricity rates in the world; Marzolf et al. Reference Marzolf, Fernando Casado and Johanna2015). Electricity subsidies disproportionately benefit higher-income groups and local industries that consume more energy and pay lower rates. Residential users pay a maximum of USD 0.06 (TTD 0.37) per kWh, commercial users pay between USD 0.06 and 0.09 (TTD 0.41 and 0.61) per kWh based on a minimum monthly use of 5,000 kWh, and industrial users pay between USD 0.02 and 0.03 (TTD 0.1450 and 0.1990) per kWh (TTEC 2001). In 2017, the government proposed a further 25 per cent rebate on domestic users (about 120,000 households) whose bill is below USD 50 (Imbert Reference Imbert2016b).

16.3 Understanding the Dynamics of Fossil Fuel Subsidy Reform: Actors, Frames and Contexts

This section explains the framework that will be used to illustrate the dynamics behind fossil fuel subsidy reform in Trinidad and Tobago: the role of actors with different interests in shaping policy, the ways in which the debates for and against the subsidy have been framed and the prevailing contexts (macroeconomic and local) that can determine the reform trajectory (see also Chapter 1).

16.3.1 Actors

Multiple actors influence subsidy reform agendas. The group advocating for subsidy reform usually includes international development agencies (Lockwood Reference Lockwood2015), multilateral financial institutions and environmental groups. Traditionally, the group of actors that have championed its maintenance has included labour and elite interest groups and energy-intensive industries (de Moor Reference de Moor2001; van Beers and de Moor Reference de Moor2001; Lockwood Reference Lockwood2015). Politicians, especially in developing states, tend to shape policy based on which group of actors has a greater sway on public opinion (Lockwood Reference Lockwood2015), except – as we will see later – when it is financially impossible to maintain the subsidy. In developing states, especially where information on the real cost and economic inefficiency of the subsidy is not readily available, politicians are able to use subsidies to gain or keep political patronage with the poor population. In spite of the inefficiency of subsidies, powerful groups were mobilised to strike and stage social disturbances during recent attempts in Nigeria in 2012, Indonesia in 2013 (see Chapter 11) and Yemen in 2014 to reduce fuel subsidies and use the savings for improved social services (Lockwood Reference Lockwood2015).

16.3.2 Frames

Arguments for and against fuel subsidy reform have been framed in different ways, with actors employing frames related to (1) climate as well as energy redistributive justice, (2) environmental stewardship and (3) economic prudence. Subsidies may be a (contested) way to redistribute national wealth in energy-producing states (climate and energy redistributive justice) or a fillip to environmental pollution (environmental stewardship). They can also contribute to fiscal imbalances and economic inefficiency and irresponsibility in the case of consumer subsidies (economic prudence); in the case of producer subsidies for the hydrocarbons industry, subsidies may help buttress falling government revenues (economic prudence).

‘Climate justice’ refers to the burden-sharing arrangement for climate change impacts and mitigation actions among states, non-state actors and individuals within both wealthy and poor states (Okereke Reference Okereke2010; Barrett Reference Barrett2013; Baptiste and Rhiney Reference Baptiste and Rhiney2016). It draws from political philosophy on fairness (Rawls Reference Rawls2005) in the distribution of resources and responsibilities, rights and obligations for mitigation and adaptation (Caney Reference Caney2010). ‘Energy redistributive justice’ concerns energy access and affordability and applies ethical and justice arguments to the fields of energy policy (McCauley et al. Reference McCauley, Heffron, Stephan and Jenkins2013), energy use and energy production (Sovacool and Dworkin Reference Sovacool and Dworkin2015). Rising energy prices have a larger impact on the poor, who have less disposable income (Boardman Reference Boardman2010) and are less able to challenge energy policy related to mitigation measures (such as measures that make fossil fuels more expensive to reduce the demand for them). Poorer countries need low-cost energy resources for economic development. Energy justice may be qualified by climate justice duties that are everyone’s responsibility: negative duties correspond to polluters, and positive duties apply to all capable of contributing to reducing emissions (Duus-Otterström and Jagers Reference Duus-Otterström and Jagers2012). The greenhouse development rights model, for example, may be interpreted as warranting the poor to adopt a part, albeit proportionately minimal, of the burden of higher energy costs that come with the removal of fuel subsidies. In that model, in 2030, least developed countries would have a 1.2 per cent ‘responsibility capacity’ (the measure used for burden sharing) to reduce emissions compared to 25 per cent for the United States (Baer et al. Reference Baer, Athanasiou, Kartha and Kemp-Benedict2008). Thus, energy and climate justice frames can be used to argue both for and against fossil fuel subsidy reform.

Those in favour of keeping fossil fuel subsidies have also used energy redistributive justice frames. Most members of the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (Hochman and Zilberman Reference Hochman and Zilberman2015) appeal to justice. This is particularly powerful when there is little public confidence in the government’s ability to transfer savings from subsidy removal to other social programmes. Lower energy prices contribute to lower transport and food prices (Soile et al. Reference Soile, Tsaku and Yar’Adua2014). Energy subsidies, according to this frame, allow citizens to their entitlement – i.e. citizens (including the poor) own the resource (Whitley Reference Whitley2013). Fuel and electricity subsidies, according to this argument, may also help boost export competitiveness by contributing to lower production costs for small manufacturers (who are disadvantaged by a lack of economies of scale and distance from global markets). Removing subsidies is unappealing to the poor because the short- to medium-term distributional effects of the removal are harder on low-income groups, at least when remedial measures are not adopted (Mathur and Morris Reference Mathur and Morris2014; Siddig et al. Reference Siddig, Aguiar and Grethe2014; Jiang et al. Reference Jiang, Ouyang and Huang2015).

Small island developing states contribute minimally to carbon emissions (World Bank 2017), but from the perspective of climate justice, and acknowledging the principle of common but differentiated mitigation responsibilities under the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, they should also be environmental stewards and avoid fuel subsidies where possible. From the environmental stewardship perspective, fuel subsidies are environmentally harmful: they contribute to global warming, local pollution, traffic congestion and road accidents and damage (see Chapters 3 and 8).

From an economic prudence perspective, fuel subsidies are suboptimal: they reduce economic growth by artificially supporting inefficient national production and have a negative impact on national welfare and the economy (Arzaghi and Squalli Reference Arzaghi and Squalli2015). Specifically, fuel subsidies are inefficient wealth-transfer mechanisms (Saboohi Reference Saboohi2001; Dube Reference Dube2003) because the wealthy use more high-energy-consuming goods and benefit most from direct fuel subsidies (Gangopadhyaya et al. Reference Gangopadhyaya, Ramaswamia and Wadhwaa2005; Arze del Granado and Coady Reference Arze del Granado and Coady2012; Rao Reference Rao2012). Savings from removing subsidies – redirected, for example, to health and education programmes – and direct transfers to targeted groups are more efficient ways to distribute national energy wealth (Commander Reference Commander2012).

International development agencies that provide financial and technical assistance to developing states commonly exert pressure and use narratives for reform within frames of economic prudence and environmental stewardship: subsidies are inefficient social transfer mechanisms, and energy subsidies encourage overuse and increase emissions.

16.3.3 Contexts

The third part of the framework addresses contexts. For many energy-producing developing states, energy subsidies have been simple – with visible administrative mechanisms to transfer the state’s resources to the poor (Victor Reference Victor2009) – and easily justifiable to voters (Cheon et al. Reference Cheon, Lackner and Urpelainen2015). However, they tend to be non-transparent (Koplow and Dernbach Reference Koplow and Dernbach2001). Reform advocates recommend several measures, including

Successful reform, however, often depends on national contexts, including the administrative capacity to channel savings towards targeted social assistance, the availability of timely and accurate economic data on the cost of the subsidy and potential savings (IMF 2013), the power of an antireform lobby to block or hinder reform, the availability or attractiveness of substitutes for the subsidy, the level of trust and buy-in that the government has from the population to transfer savings to more efficient social programmes (Vagliasindi Reference Vagliasindi2013), the force of external macroeconomic pressures to reduce government disposable income and the health of the economy and its ability to sustain subsidies. In developing states, contexts are often less favourable, and reform may pose administrative burdens for poorer governments.

16.4 Actors, Frames and Contexts in Fuel Subsidy Reform in Trinidad and Tobago
16.4.1 Actors

Following the framework just outlined, this section identifies the main actors involved in the subsidy reform debate in Trinidad and Tobago and their positions on the issue. These actors include the International Monetary Fund (IMF) (IMF 2016), the Energy Chamber – the energy and hydrocarbon industry’s trade association, which is particularly vocal on consumer subsidies (Long Reference Long2013), the environmental lobby, including academics and economists that comment on government policy, government agencies more directly involved in climate policymaking, such as the Ministry of Planning and Development and the Ministry of the Environment and Water Resources (Solaun et al. Reference Solaun, Gómez and Larrea2015; GORTT 2017a) and companies from the other member states of the Caribbean Community Common Market (Khelawan Reference Khelawan2013; Collister Reference Collister2016).

Other actors have, at times, been opposed to the removal of the transport subsidy, including some labour unions such as the National Workers Union and the Federation of Independent Trade Unions and Non-Governmental Organisations (C News 2016; NWU 2016), minibus associations (Phillip Reference Phillip2016) and groups representing low-income communities (Sturge Reference Sturge2016; Taitt Reference Taitt2016). The manufacturing sector comprises about 400 companies and contributes to approximately 8 per cent of the country’s gross domestic product (TTMA 2017). Small retail businesses and manufacturers and sub-national chambers of commerce – which are less able to absorb higher transport costs – argue that removing the subsidy will mean higher prices for consumers and inflationary pressure on the economy (Ali Reference Ali2016). Larger manufacturers have more recently begun to argue for removal of the subsidy, citing its inefficiency, negative environmental consequences and unsustainability (referring to the drop in petroleum prices and consequent drop in government revenue from the hydrocarbons sector; Harrinanan Reference Harrinanan2015). Figure 16.1 presents the main actors in the subsidy removal debate in Trinidad and Tobago.

Figure 16.1 Actors in fuel subsidy reform in Trinidad and Tobago.

16.4.2 Frames

In Trinidad and Tobago, economic prudence and environmental stewardship frames are used to object to the transport and electricity subsidies. Actors in favour of those subsidies use climate and energy redistributive justice frames. Those in favour of the producer subsidy (the hydrocarbons sector) also use economic prudence frames. However, there is very little evidence of public debate on producer subsidies. Low-income groups focused more on the maintenance of social transfers related to health, education and employment, which are also being contested as inefficient and in need of reduction by the IMF, the larger manufacturers and the government.

The economic prudence frame dominates the fuel subsidy debate. Estimates in parliamentary debates put subsidies for fuel, unemployment relief, electricity and water at 50 per cent of national expenditure (Imbert Reference Imbert2016c). The fuel subsidy may have continued as long as the government was able to finance it, but the global financial crisis of 2007–8 gave greater prominence to economic prudence frames. In a 2016 budget debate, the Minister of Finance noted that the government is taking steps to reduce expenditure on other social programmes, including spending on tertiary education (the Government Assistance for Tuition Expenses Programme) and on job creation (the Community-Based Environmental Protection and Enhancement Programme and the Unemployment Relief Programme; Imbert, Reference Imbert2016b, 16). Past IMF Article IV consultations – in which the IMF’s staff study the country’s economic and fiscal policy and trajectory – repeatedly called for the removal of the transport subsidy to improve the fiscal climate and to increase savings to the country’s sovereign wealth fund, which was created to encourage state savings from petroleum revenues (IMF 2016). The political response has changed over the years from being wary of the IMF’s intrusion into domestic policy (Trinidad Guardian 2013) to a commitment to a phased removal of the transport subsidy. Subsidy removal will be coupled with a new pricing mechanism for transport fuels to reduce transport costs for low-income groups (Imbert Reference Imbert2016b).

National debates have very recently begun to introduce data on the subsidy’s cost that confirm its inefficient design (GORTT 2012a) and the opportunity costs to taxpayers (Scobie Reference Scobie2017). However, the lack of data on the inefficiencies gave the climate and energy redistributive justice frames greater appeal over the years. The country has a small carbon footprint and relies on its petrochemical sector; thus, some argue that fuel, electricity and transport prices should be very affordable to the poor, to local businesses and manufacturers (Trinidad Guardian 2011; Newsday 2016) and to the population in general (Thomas Reference Thomas2003; NWU 2016). Successive governments have deferred subsidy reform in part because of the prominence given to these redistributive justice frames in public opinion.

Actors who support keeping the transport subsidy have used energy redistributive justice and environmental stewardship frames. Private minibus associations – the main source of public transport – objected to early attempts to remove the fuel transport subsidy because removal would reduce their small profit margins. They argued that such a move would force them to increase fares, which would hurt the low-income groups that depend upon this public transport. In 2003, for example, in response to proposals to reduce the transport subsidy, two minibus associations covering important parts of the minibus network threatened to increase transit fares or refuse to offer their services (Thomas Reference Thomas2003). Labour unions representing low-wage earners have traditionally been hostile to the government’s reform policy, which in their view includes austerity measures that take national wealth away from the poor. The National Workers Union, for example, argued that ‘the government in an effort to keep us away from an IMF standby programme is implementing all the measures the IMF would have imposed. An IMF programme is being implemented even though no loans have been made by the IMF’ (NWU 2016). It also issued a statement in 2016 objecting to fuel subsidy reform, which it views as part of a larger move by the government to reduce pro-poor programmes, such as the ‘extending of [a value-added tax] on thousands of items, the increases in fuel prices, the job losses in the public sector, the reduction of social welfare programmes and the speeding up of divestment/privatisation of state enterprises’ (NWU 2016). Small businesses (mainly retailers) benefit from savings in transport and electricity costs.

On the other side of the debate, companies from other Caribbean states – as well as the regional airline Leeward Islands Air Transport (LIAT, which is not based in Trinidad and Tobago) – have been critical of the unfair advantage that the transport and electricity subsidies have given to companies from Trinidad and Tobago and to the Trinidad and Tobago airline (Caribbean Airways) on the regional common market (Collister Reference Collister2016). Opposition to subsidies from the regional business community has had little resonance in parliamentary debates and on reform policy (Scobie Reference Scobie2017).

The economic prudence frame that holds that the electricity subsidy creates an artificial sense of security and inefficiencies in production has traditionally had less resonance. Unlike transport fuels, electricity prices have not been adjusted since 2009, and the electricity subsidy received less attention in public debates. Environmental stewardship and economic prudence, however, are used in the literature around subsidy reform for transport fuels and electricity. The government’s carbon emissions reduction strategy proposed introducing renewables to reduce dependence on natural gas for electricity generation, but uptake has been slow because the fuel subsidy makes traditional electricity sources more economical (Humpert and Espinosa Reference Humpert and Espinosa2016: 11). Small businesses and manufacturers used climate and energy redistributive justice frames to argue that the electricity subsidy supports the local small business sector, given electricity generation’s small carbon footprint and the economic challenges and lack of economies of scale faced by small island developing state exporters. Local small businesses need government assistance to be competitive in an increasingly globalised world, to provide local jobs, to help the country’s diversification away from the dwindling hydrocarbons sector and to contribute to social and economic development.

The producer subsidy is firmly entrenched, and there is little national debate on its reform – its maintenance is part of the economic prudence frame employed by the hydrocarbon companies. This demonstrates that frames are used differently by different actors in different contexts. Economic prudence frames employed in the context of producer subsidies suggest that the country should provide incentives to industry to boost output and government revenue (IMF 2016: 7). The Energy Chamber supported the removal of the transport subsidy but was silent on production subsidy reform or removal. Generally, these transfers to the industry are not framed as subsidies but rather as incentives needed to keep the hydrocarbons sector and exports as near to current levels as possible. The hydrocarbon companies argue for a fiscal regime that would reduce exploration risk and encourage foreign direct investment; producer subsidies thus should remain, in their view, especially in the context of a hydrocarbon-dependent economy in an epoch of economic downturn. Trinidad and Tobago has over 40 active production-sharing contracts and joint-venture partnerships with several energy companies, including Petro-Canada, BHP Petroleum, BG and many others (Petrotrin 2015; Ministry of Energy and Energy Affairs 2017). Large multinational and local energy actors are now negotiating production-sharing contracts with attractive investment terms for riskier investments in new oil fields (Energy Chamber 2017). When the state-owned oil company – the Petroleum Company of Trinidad and Tobago Limited (Petrotrin) – released a call for expressions of interest in March 2017 to assist with enhanced oil and gas recovery, it received responses from 29 firms in China, Canada, the United Kingdom, the United States and Trinidad and Tobago (Energy Chamber 2017).

Voices against the petroleum subsidy have been negligible in comparison, with one Member of Parliament going on record to complain that the subsidy was unfair to the state. The energy industry, he argued, generated as much as TTD 150 billion but ‘the State was only receiving [TTD] 18 to [TTD] 19 billion in revenue, something was wrong with the system because somebody else (not the State) was getting [TTD] 132 billion’ (Small Reference Small2016: 30; Taitt Reference Taitt2016).

Climate justice and environmental stewardship frames have been used by the government and are embedded in the country’s low-carbon development policy. The environmental stewardship–related goal is to move towards a low-carbon development pathway by removing dependence on the hydrocarbons sector. Restructuring fuel subsidies (Solaun et al. Reference Solaun, Gómez and Larrea2015) is part of the government’s 2011 National Climate Change Policy, Low Carbon Development Plan and Carbon Reduction Strategy (GORTT 2012b). Resource and capacity constraints hinder the implementation of several climate policy initiatives in small island developing states (Scobie Reference Scobie2016). This is true for Trinidad and Tobago, which is struggling with the national Carbon Reduction Strategy target to reduce emissions from the power, industrial and transport sectors by 15 per cent by 2040 compared to 2000 levels – targets also included in the country’s nationally determined contribution submitted under the Paris Agreement (GORTT 2015). A recent report on renewables in Trinidad and Tobago noted that to achieve the stewardship goal, it needed to better incentivise the use of wind, solar and wave energy (Solaun et al. Reference Solaun, Gómez and Larrea2015). Table 16.2 summarises how the frames just discussed have been used by groups of actors to support positions on the reform/removal debate in Trinidad and Tobago.

Table 16.2 Actors and frames in fuel subsidy reform debates in Trinidad and Tobago

Subsidy typeFrame usedPosition on subsidyActors invoking the frameMain argument(s)
TransportEconomic prudenceRemove
  • IMF

  • Energy Chamber

  • Ministry of Planning and Development/Ministry of the Environment and Water Resources

  • Reduces social transfers

  • Subsidy economically unsustainable

  • Encourages economic inefficiency

ProducerEconomic prudenceKeep or increase
  • Hydrocarbon companies

  • Foreign direct investment needed as petroleum production is falling

TransportEnvironmental stewardshipRemove
  • IMF

  • Energy Chamber

  • Ministry of Planning and Development/Ministry of the Environment and Water Resources

  • Environmentalists

  • Subsidy leads to fossil fuel pollution

  • Subsidy contradicts environmental stewardship duties and National Clean Energy Policy

Energy redistributive justice
Climate justice
ElectricityEnvironmental stewardshipRemove
  • IMF

  • Ministry of Planning and Development/Ministry of the Environment and Water Resources

  • Subsidy runs counter to low-carbon development pathway

  • Reduces social transfers

  • Encourages economic inefficiency

Economic prudence
Transport and electricityEnergy redistributive justiceKeep
  • Labour unions

  • Minibus associations

  • Low-income groups

  • Direct way to share hydrocarbon wealth

  • Government may not redistribute savings to other pro-poor measures

  • Cheap fuel needed for national development

  • Rights of poor to energy resources

  • The country’s minimal contribution to climate change

Climate justice
  • Small businesses

16.4.3 Contexts

While some actors have become more vocal in the use of economic prudence and environmental stewardship frames to advocate for subsidy removal – and although pro-subsidy advocates who appeal to climate and energy justice frames concede that fuel subsidies are not the most efficient form of pro-poor government spending – it does not follow that reform will be the next step (Scobie Reference Scobie2017; see also Chapter 6). Several of the contextual factors identified in the literature have made reforms more challenging and have favoured subsidy lock-in, such as the unavailability of timely and accurate economic data on the cost of the producer and consumer subsidies and potential savings, the power of the antireform lobby to influence government policy, the unavailability of appropriate substitutes for the subsidy and the low level of trust and buy-in that the government has had from the population to transfer savings to more efficient social programmes (Scobie Reference Scobie2017). However, other contextual factors have favoured the removal of the transport subsidy. Notably, external macroeconomic pressures (the global financial crisis of 2007 and the subsequent fall in petroleum prices) increased pressure to reduce inefficient government spending. Moreover, the dependence on the hydrocarbon sector for national income and the resulting falling government revenue reduced the state’s ability to sustain subsidies (IMF 2016).

The information deficit on subsidy costs can be seen as another contextual factor influencing the public debate. It reduced the persuasive power of economic prudence frames to lower-income groups and made energy redistributive justice arguments more appealing. Two recent developments may pave the way for a greater understanding of the true costs of the subsidy and may improve transparency. The first is a National Tripartite Advisory Council, created in March 2016 to improve transparency and promote regular consultation between the private sector, labour groups and the government. The second is the creation of an autonomous National Statistical Institute to reduce the backlogs in the state-owned Central Statistical Office. Both bodies have not yet addressed the fuel subsidy, but they have the potential to contribute to improved data availability for policymaking.

One of the elements of subsidy reform suggested in the literature is the substitution of inefficient fuel subsidies with targeted pro-poor transfers (AlShehabi Reference AlShehabi2012). In the Trinidad and Tobago context, this raises two problems. First, there is already a generous and comprehensive set of social programmes (Imbert Reference Imbert2016b: 32); the social safety net includes conditional cash-transfer programmes, housing-assistance programmes, infrastructure projects in needy communities and a suite of social services in the areas of health, alimentation, education, employment and sanitation (Imbert Reference Imbert2016b). Second, the system of transfers has been heavily criticised for being inefficient, with the employment programmes distorting and undermining the local labour market (IMF 2016) and programmes being subject to fraud and corruption (Imbert Reference Imbert2016c: 14). While it is true that subsidy removal savings may be redirected to improve the quality and delivery of existing social relief programmes, this is more difficult to measure, justify and support given the existing inefficiencies in public administration and the lack of public trust in the way public funds are administered in social programmes.

16.5 Conclusion

Fuel subsidies have been part of the economic policy of Trinidad and Tobago for decades. The hydrocarbons sector has always benefited from investment incentives, many of which amount to producer subsidies. Since the 1970s, transport fuels have been subsidised as a way to transfer national wealth from the petroleum sector to the population, and electricity has always been generated with autochthonous natural gas priced below market prices. While producer subsidies and electricity subsidies persist, the transport subsidy was substantially reduced over the last decade. This chapter outlined a novel framework to better understand the politics of subsidy reform, focusing on actors, frames and contexts as explanatory variables. Employing this framework, the chapter sought to provide insights into the subsidy reform debates in this small island hydrocarbon-dependent state.

External actors, including companies from other Caribbean countries and the IMF (which advised the government on economic policy) – as well as internal actors such as the Energy Chamber, the government ministries charged with climate policy and environmentalists – have for different reasons opposed the subsidy. The labour unions representing low-wage earners, minibus associations that service a large part of the public transport network, small businesses and the hydrocarbons sector have been more or less vocal advocates for the maintenance of the status quo for the transport, electricity or producer subsidies.

The frames developed in this chapter helped to coalesce the perspectives or motivations of actors or groups of actors on subsidy reform, removal or maintenance. To some extent, the frames used in the Trinidad and Tobago debate mirrored the (sometimes conflicting) frames found in the fossil fuel subsidy reform literature. Subsidies run counter to good economic policy, or subsidies are needed for economic development. Subsidies allow for redistributive energy justice, or subsidies are an ineffectual tool of redistributive energy justice. Subsidies run counter to climate justice – or climate justice explains their persistence in countries with minimal emissions, and subsidies thus detract from environmental stewardship.

This chapter explained that even with the same actors and the existence of similar frames, policy changed in the last decade. The removal of transport subsides was needed because of a changed international economic context (Imbert Reference Imbert2016a) – which is in keeping with the small states literature that recognises the relevance of global trends for domestic policymaking (Keohane Reference Keohane1969; Payne Reference Payne2004). In this case, the financial crisis of 2007 was accompanied by a fall in petroleum prices and thus a fall in government revenues, which opened up space to discuss the frames that promoted subsidy reform. The government no longer had levels of income that would allow for the subsidy’s continuance. Transport subsidies were largely removed, and reform of the electricity subsidy is being discussed, but the government has kept producer subsidies to promote investments that maintain or increase hydrocarbon output. Context was also relevant for the reform trajectory in other ways. While the literature recommends substituting the fossil fuel subsidy for other forms of wealth transfer, this was inappropriate in this case for two reasons: first, there was already a comprehensive social net, and second, social transfers were already badly managed, and there was little appetite to add another mechanism. Finally, the availability of data (transparency) was another relevant contextual factor. The transport subsidy – for which most information on government expenditure was available – was gradually removed. But the producer and electricity subsidies – for which information is not easily available – have not yet been removed or reduced. The case is a sobering example of how global frames are applied at local scales and of how local contexts, economic and historical realities and actors articulate these frames to shape domestic fuel subsidy policy.

Footnotes

11 Fossil Fuel Subsidy Reform in Indonesia The Struggle for Successful Reform

1 Interviews were carried out in Jakarta, Indonesia, from July to August 2015 with a range of government officials from the Ministry of Finance and Ministry of Energy, policy analysts, international organisations and local nongovernmental organisations working on energy subsidy reform.

2 Since the expenditure on fossil fuel subsidies would have increased significantly in 2005 compared to 2004 had the reforms not been introduced. The increase in fuel prices reduced the fiscal burden of subsidies and subsequently the deficit as well.

12 Lessons from the World’s Largest Subsidy Benefit Transfer Scheme The Case of Liquefied Petroleum Gas Subsidy Reform in India

1 Or 35 cylinders weighing 5 kilograms each for households using smaller cylinders.

2 As of 12 March 2017, the scheme covers 165.9 million domestic connections (MoPNG 2017).

3 Earlier, LPG for households was available at subsidised market prices, unlike for commercial entities. This led to a direct incentive for siphoning and diversion of subsidised commodity for commercial uses, primarily by LPG distributors but also by consumers.

4 Many distributors (and consumers) had taken connections under ‘ghost’ names with illegal documents to receive the benefit of the subsidised commodity for non-domestic purposes.

5 An Aadhaar number is a 12-digit unique identification number for Indian residents that is linked to the resident’s basic demographic and biometric information stored in a centralised database.

6 In the Corruption Perception Index 2016, India is ranked low at 79 out of 176 (Transparency International 2017).

7 Based on our discussions with officials at the MoPNG.

8 Monthly sales performance review reports are published by the Petroleum Planning and Analysis Cell, a body under the MoPNG.

9 LPG used for automobiles.

10 The Core Banking Solution entails the networking of branches, enabling customers to operate their accounts and use banking services from any branch of the bank on the network regardless of where the customer maintains his or her account.

13 Sustaining Carbon Lock-In Fossil Fuel Subsidies in South Africa

1 This estimate was for quantifiable national subsidies (excluding SOE investment and public finance). We exclude SOE investment in fossil fuels but include state transfers to SOEs.

2 The state has continued to forego royalty revenues (Daniel et al. Reference Daniel, Grote, Harris and Shah2015; National Treasury 2015b).

3 Eskom was initially also capitalised by the state in 1922, benefited from tax exemption and dividend-free equity and had a ‘captive’ domestic market for its bonds due to prescribed asset rules (Steyn Reference Steyn2001).

4 Synthetic fuels (or ‘synfuels’) were developed during apartheid for energy security and other reasons. Sasol gasifies coal and converts it to liquid fuels; Mossgas converts gas to liquids.

5 The cost, insurance and freight price of fuel plus additional costs related to international transport and tariffs.

6 This agreement was terminated in 2003.

7 The inland market, or ‘Sasol supply area’, included the inland provinces of South Africa (Competition Tribunal 2006: 19).

14 The Politics of Subsidies to Coal Extraction in Colombia

1 In 2015, more than 92 per cent of coal was produced in the César and La Guajira departments (SIMCO 2016).

2 This policy aimed to re-establish internal order and to protect civilians from illegal, armed organisations, theoretically under a framework of rights and protections related to the rule of law. In practice, the policy privileged a conventional military approach (Mason Reference Mason2003).

15 Reforming Egypt’s Fossil Fuel Subsidies in the Context of a Changing Social Contract

16 Actors, Frames and Contexts in Fossil Fuel Subsidy Reform The Case of Trinidad and Tobago

References

References

ADB (Asian Development Bank) (2015). Fossil Fuel Subsidies in Indonesia: Trends, Impacts and Reforms. Manila: ADB.Google Scholar
Aldy, J. (2013). Proposal 5: eliminating fossil fuel subsidies. In 15 Ways to Rethink the Federal Budget, ed. Greenstone, M., Harris, M., Li, K., Looney, A. and Patashnik, J.. Washington, DC: Brookings Institute, pp. 3135.Google Scholar
APBN (Anggaran Pendapatan dan Belanja Negara) (2016). Book II Financial Notes Along with the State Budget 2016 (Buku II Nota Keuangan Beserta Anggaran Pendapatan dan Belanja Negara 2016). Jakarta: Republik Indonesia.Google Scholar
Aspinall, E. (2013). Popular agency and interests in Indonesia’s democratic transition and consolidation. Indonesia 96, 1132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aswicahyono, H., Bird, K. and Hill, H. (2009). Making economic policy in weak, democratic, post-crisis states: an Indonesian case study. World Development 37(2), 354–70.Google Scholar
Bacon, K. and Kojima, M. (2006). Coping with Higher Oil Prices. Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Basri, M. C. and Hill, H. (2004). Ideas, interests and oil prices: the political economy of trade reform during Soeharto’s Indonesia. The World Economy 27(5), 633–55Google Scholar
Basri, M. C. and Rahardja, S. (2011). Mild crisis, half hearted fiscal stimulus: Indonesia during the GFC. In Assessment on the Impact of Stimulus, Fiscal Transparency and Fiscal Risk, ed. Ito, T. and Parulian, F.. Jakarta: Economic Research Institute for ASEAN and East Asia, pp. 169211.Google Scholar
Beaton, C., Gerasimchuk, I., Laan, T. et al. (2013). A Guidebook to Fossil-Fuel Subsidy Reform: For Policy-Makers in Southeast Asia. Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
Beaton, C. and Lontoh, L. (2010). Lessons Learned from Indonesia’s Attempts to Reform Fossil-Fuel Subsidies. Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
Benes, K., Cheon, A., Urpelainen, J. and Yang, J. (2015). Low Oil Prices: An Opportunity for Fuel Subsidy Reform. New York, NY: Columbia University School of International and Public Affairs.Google Scholar
Bridle, R. and Kitson, L. (2014). The Impact of Fossil-Fuel Subsidies on Renewable Electricity Generation. Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
Budya, H. and Arofat, M.Y. (2011). Providing cleaner energy access in Indonesia through the megaproject of kerosene conversion to LPG. Energy Policy 39(12), 7575–86.Google Scholar
Cahyfitri, R. (2015). Transparency remains a key issue. Jakarta Post, 27 April 2011.Google Scholar
Casier, L. and Beaton, C. (2015). Fossil-Fuel Subsidy Reform and Higher Fuel Prices in Indonesia: Impacts and Expectations. Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
Cassin, R. L. (2014). Indonesia anti-graft agency to take on ‘oil and gas mafia’. The FCPA Blog, 2 December 2014.Google Scholar
Checkel, J. A. (2006). Tracing causal mechanisms. International Studies Review 8(2), 362–70.Google Scholar
Collier, D. (2011). Understanding process tracing. Political Science and Politics 44(4), 823–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diop, N. (2014). Why Is Reducing Energy Subsidies a Prudent, Fair, and Transformative Policy for Indonesia? Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Drazen, A. and Grilli, V. (1993). The benefit of crises for economic reforms. American Economic Review 83(3), 598607.Google Scholar
EIA (Energy Information Administration) (2017). Spot prices. Available at www.eia.gov/dnav/pet/pet_pri_spt_s1_d.htm (accessed 18 September 2017).Google Scholar
García Villarreal, J. P. (2010). Successful Practices and Policies to Promote Regulatory Reform and Entrepreneurship at the Sub-national Level. Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.Google Scholar
GOI (Government of Indonesia) (1945). The 1945 Constitution of the Republic of Indonesia. Jakarta: GOI.Google Scholar
GSI (Global Subsidies Initiative) (2014). The Impact of Fossil Fuel Subsidies on Renewable Electricity Generation. Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
Guillaume, D., Zytek, R. and Farzin, M. R. (2011). Iran: The Chronicles of the Subsidy Reform. Washington, DC: IMF.Google Scholar
Hill, H. (2013). The political economy of policy reform: insights from Southeast Asia. Asian Development Review 30(1), 108–30.Google Scholar
HKSIP (Harvard Kennedy School Indonesia Program) (2013). The Sum Is Greater than the Parts: Doubling Shared Prosperity in Indonesia through Local and Global Integration. Jakarta: Gramedia Pustaka Utama.Google Scholar
Hook, W. and Replogle, M. (1996). Motorization and non-motorized transport in Asia. Land Use Policy 13(1), 6984.Google Scholar
IEA (International Energy Agency) (2016). Fossil Fuel Subsidy Reform in Mexico and Indonesia. Paris: IEA.Google Scholar
IEA (International Energy Agency), Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, and World Bank (2009). The Scope of Fossil-Fuel Subsidies in 2009 and a Roadmap for Phasing Out Fossil-Fuel Subsidies (joint report prepared for the G20 Summit). Paris: IEA.Google Scholar
IMF (International Monetary Fund) (2013). Case Studies on Energy Subsidy Reform: Lessons and Implications. Washington, DC: IMF.Google Scholar
Indriyanto, A., Lontah, L., Pusakantara, A., Siahaan, N. and Vis-Dunbar, D. (2013). Fossil-Fuel Subsidy Reform in Indonesia: A Review of Government Communications in 2012. Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
Kapoor, K. (2014). Indonesia inaugurates parliament likely to curb Widodo’s reforms. Reuters, 1 October 2014.Google Scholar
Khan, M. H. (2000). Rent-seeking as process. In Rent, Rent-Seeking and Economic Development: Theory and Evidence in Asia, ed. Khan, M. and Jomo, K. S.. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 70144.Google Scholar
Kojima, M. (2016). Fossil Fuel Subsidy and Pricing Policies: Recent Developing Country Experience. Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Lockwood, M. (2015). Fossil fuel subsidy reform, rent management, and political fragmentation in development countries. New Political Economy 20(4), 475–94.Google Scholar
Lontoh, L. and Toft, L. (2016). Indonesia Approves Revised 2016 Budget: Subsidy Update. Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development. Available at www.iisd.org/gsi/news/indonesia-approves-revised-2016-budget-subsidy-update (accessed 16 August 2017).Google Scholar
Mietzner, M. (2009). Indonesia’s 2009 Election: Populism, Dynasties and the Consolidation of the Party System. Sydney: Lowy Institute for International Policy.Google Scholar
Mydans, S. (1998). Suharto, besieged, steps down after 32-year rule in Indonesia. New York Times, 21 May 1998.Google Scholar
Nangoy, F. and Suroyo, G. (2015). Update 2: Indonesia’s rupiah hits 17-yr low, c.bank to intervene if needed. Reuters, 3 June 2015.Google Scholar
Otto, B. (2015). Indonesia’s Pertamina fuel-sale losses hit $1 billion. Wall Street Journal, 25 September 2015.Google Scholar
Perdana, A. A. (2014). The Future of Social Welfare Programs in Indonesia: From Fossil-Fuel Subsidies to Better Social Protection. Jakarta: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
Pisani, E. (2014). Indonesia, Etc: Exploring the Improbable Nation. New York, NY: W.W. Norton.Google Scholar
Pradiptyo, R. Wirotomo, A., Adisasmita, A. and Permana, Y. H. (2015). The Role of Information Perception of Fossil Fuel Subsidy Reform: Evidence from Indonesia. Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
Prawiraatmadja, W. (2015). Reform of fuel subsidies by the government of Indonesia and the medium-term plan: international experience with fuel subsidy pricing policy. MEMR Presentation, 23 April 2015, KESDM/MEMR, Jakarta.Google Scholar
Samboh, E. and Cahyafitri, R. (2015). Govt shifts burden to Pertamina. Jakarta Post, 25 May 2015.Google Scholar
Schlogl, L. and Sumner, A. (2014). How middle class are the ‘emerging middle’ or ‘scooter class’ in Indonesia? A household asset approach to social stratification. Working Paper No. 201407, Padjadjaran University, Bandung.Google Scholar
Sdralevich, C., Sab, R., Zouhar, Y and Albertin, G. (2014). Subsidy Reform in the Middle East and North Africa: Recent Progress and Challenges Ahead. Washington, DC: IMF.Google Scholar
Sipahutar, T. (2014). Oil, gas governance in spotlight. Jakarta Post, 17 November 2014.Google Scholar
Sukoyo, Y. (2014). For Jokowi, oil mafia is a slick target to catch. Jakarta Globe, 23 September 2014.Google Scholar
The Economist (2014). The empire strikes back. The Economist, 4 October 2014.Google Scholar
Wenzelburger, G. and Horisch, F. (2016). Unpopular social policy reform and strategic communication: an introduction. Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis 18(2), 113–21.Google Scholar
Wikipdr (2014). ‘Red-White’ blast reallocation fuel subsidy, prepare ‘Hak Angket’. Available at http://wikidpr.org/news/red-white-blast-reallocation-fuel-subsidy-prepare-hak-angket (accessed 16 August 2017).Google Scholar
Witular, R. (2015). No reform in fuel subsidies, Jokowi just forces others to pay the tab. Jakarta Post, 31 July 2015.Google Scholar
World Bank (2009). Imagine a New Indonesia: Spending to Improve Development. Washington, DC: World Bank. Available at http://blogs.worldbank.org/eastasiapacific/imagine-a-new-indonesia-spending-to-improve-development (accessed 16 August 2017).Google Scholar
World Bank (2013). Indonesia Economic Quarterly. Jakarta: World Bank.Google Scholar
World Bank (2017a). General Government Final Consumption Expenditure (Current US$). Washington, DC: World Bank. Available at http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NE.CON.GOVT.CD (accessed 16 August 2017).Google Scholar
World Bank (2017b). Pump Price for Diesel Fuel (US$ per Liter). Washington, DC: World Bank. Available at http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/EP.PMP.DESL.CD (accessed 16 August 2017).Google Scholar

Interviews

Interview 1 Muhamad Chatib Basri, economist and former Minister of Finance of Indonesia (23 September 2015)

Interview 2 Triharyo Soesilo, Project Director for Energy Sector, Ministry of Energy and Mineral Resources of the Republic of Indonesia (29 July 2015)

Interview 3 Fabby Tumiwa, Executive Director, Institute for Essential Services Reform (10 August 2015)

Interview 4 Agung Wicaksono, Director, President’s Delivery Unit for Development Monitoring and Oversight, Republic of Indonesia (6 August 2015)

Interview 5 Sunandar, S.Kom,M.Si, Oil and Gas Sub-Directorate, Directorate of Energy, Mineral and Mining Resources, Indonesian Ministry of National Development Planning (BAPPENAS) (11 August 2015)

Interview 6 Lucky Lontoh, Consultant, International Institute for Sustainable Development (15 December 2016)

References

Bamberger, M. (2013). The Mixed Methods Approach to Evaluation (Social Impact Concept Note Series). London: Overseas Development Institute.Google Scholar
Banerjee, S. S. (2015). From Cash to Digital Transfers in India: The Story So Far. Washington, DC: Consultive Group to Assist the Poor.Google Scholar
Clarke, K. and Sharma, S. (2014). India Energy Subsidy Review: A Biannual Survey of Energy Subsidy Policies. Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
Docherty, J. (2014). Subsidies to Liquefied Petroleum Gas in India : An Overview of Recent Reforms. Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
Ganguly, A. and Das, K. (2016). Effect of reduction of fuel subsidies on poverty and inequality in developing countries – the case of India. SAMVAD International Journal of Management 11, 3241.Google Scholar
Grubb, M., Hourcade, J. C. and Neuhoff, K. (2014). Planetary Economics: Energy, Climate Change and the Three Domains of Sustainable Development. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Jain, A., Agrawal, S. and Ganesan, K. (2014). Rationalising Subsidies, Reaching the Underserved: Improving Effectiveness of Domestic LPG Subsidy and Distribution in India. New Delhi: Council on Energy, Environment and Water.Google Scholar
Jain, A., Agrawal, S. and Ganesan, K. (2016). DBTL Performance Evaluation: Insights from the World’s Largest Subsidy Benefit Transfer Scheme. Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
Lang, K. and Wooders, P. (2012). India’s Fuel Subsidies: Policy Recommendations for Reform. Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
MoPNG (Ministry of Petroleum and Natural Gas) (2013). Report of the Expert Group to Advise on Pricing Methodology of Diesel, Domestic LPG and PDS Kerosene. New Delhi: Government of India.Google Scholar
MoPNG (Ministry of Petroleum and Natural Gas) (2014). Review of the Direct Benefit Transfer for LPG Scheme: Committee Report. New Delhi: Government of India.Google Scholar
MoPNG (Ministry of Petroleum and Natural Gas) (2015a). About the scheme. Available at http://petroleum.nic.in/dbt/whatisdbtl.html (accessed 17 August 2017).Google Scholar
MoPNG (Ministry of Petroleum and Natural Gas) (2015b). Handbook on ‘PAHAL’ (DBTL) Scheme: Ministry of Petroleum and Natural Gas, Government of India. New Delhi: Government of India.Google Scholar
MoPNG (Ministry of Petroleum and Natural Gas) (2015c). Inauguration of mission office for PAHAL at World Trade Centre. Available at http://pib.nic.in/newsite/mbErel.aspx?relid=114107 (accessed 17 August 2017).Google Scholar
MoPNG (Ministry of Petroleum and Natural Gas) (2015d). Over 80 per cent LPG consumers have joined PAHAL. Available at http://pib.nic.in/newsite/PrintRelease.aspx?relid=116400 (accessed 17 August 2017).Google Scholar
MoPNG (Ministry of Petroleum and Natural Gas) (2017). PAHAL – direct benefits transfer for LPG (DBTL) consumers scheme. Available at http://petroleum.nic.in/dbt/index.php (accessed 17 August 2017).Google Scholar
MoPNG (Ministry of Petroleum and Natural Gas) (2015e). ‘PaHaL’ acknowledged by the Guinness Book of World Records as the largest cash transfer program. Available at http://pib.nic.in/newsite/PrintRelease.aspx?relid=125024 (accessed 17 August 2017).Google Scholar
MoPNG (Ministry of Petroleum and Natural Gas) (2015f). Subsidies on LPG cylinders. Available at http://pib.nic.in/newsite/PrintRelease.aspx?relid=128653 (accessed 17 August 2017).Google Scholar
Morris, S. and Pandey, A. (2006). Efficient subsidization of LPG: a study of possible options in India today. Working Paper No. 2006-04-07, Indian Institute of Management Ahemdabad, Vastrapur.Google Scholar
Nag, S. (2014). Fiscal effects and reforms: petro-fuel subsidy in India. International Journal of Humanities and Social Science Studies 1(2), 4649.Google Scholar
Prime Minister’s Office (2015). PM reviews PaHaL scheme for direct benefit transfer for LPG subsidy. Available at pib.nic.in/newsite/PrintRelease.aspx?relid=115109 (accessed 17 August 2017).Google Scholar
Salehi-Isfahani, D., Stucki, B. W. and Deutschmann, J. (2015). The reform of energy subsidies in Iran: the role of cash transfers. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 51(6), 1144–62.Google Scholar
Savatic, F. (2016). Fuel Subsidy Reform: Lessons from the Indonesian Case. Paris: Institute for Sustainable Development and International Relations.Google Scholar
Soni, A., Chaterjee, A. and Bandhopadhyay, K. R. (2012). Fossil-Fuel Subsidy Reform in India: Cash Transfers for PDS Kerosene and Domestic LPG. Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
Sukhtankar, S. and Vaishnav, M. (2015). Corruption in India: Bridging Research Evidence and Policy Options. India Policy Forum. Washington, DC: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace.Google Scholar
Transparency International (2017). Corruption Perception Index 2016. Available at www.transparency.org/news/feature/corruption_perceptions_index_2016 (accessed 17 August 2017).Google Scholar

References

Altieri, K., Trollip, H., Caetano, T. et al. (2015). Achieving development and mitigation objectives through a decarbonization development pathway in South Africa. Climate Policy 16 (S1), S7891.Google Scholar
ANC (African National Congress) (2007). 52nd National Conference: Adopted Strategy and Tactics of the ANC. Available at www.anc.org.za/content/52nd-national-conference-adopted-strategy-and-tactics-anc (accessed April 2017).Google Scholar
ANC (African National Congress) (2010). Transformation of State and Governance: National General Council Discussion Document. African National Congress. Available at www.anc.org.za/docs/discus/2010/legislaturez.pdf (accessed 17 August 2017).Google Scholar
Baker, L. (2012). Power shifts: the political economy of socio-technical transitions in South Africa’s electricity sector. PhD thesis, University of Sussex, Brighton.Google Scholar
Baker, L. and Burton, J. (2018). The politics of procurement and the low carbon transition in South Africa. In Handbook of the International Political Economy of Energy and Natural Resources, ed. Goldthau, A., Keating, M. and Kuzemko, C.. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 91–106.Google Scholar
Baker, L., Burton, J., Godinho, C. and Trollip, H. (2015). The Political Economy of Decarbonisation: Exploring the Dynamics of South Africa’s Electricity Sector. Cape Town: Energy Research Centre, University of Cape Town.Google Scholar
Bast, E., Doukas, A., Pickard, S., van der Burg, L. and Whitley, S. (2015). Empty Promises: G20 Subsidies to Oil, Gas and Coal Production. London: Overseas Development Institute.Google Scholar
Burton, J. (2011). The role of industrial policy in meeting climate change mitigation objectives in South Africa. MSc thesis, University of Cape Town.Google Scholar
Burton, J. and Winkler, H. (2014). South Africa’s Planned Coal Infrastructure Expansion: Drivers, Dynamics and Impacts on Greenhouse Gas Emissions. Cape Town: Energy Research Centre, University of Cape Town.Google Scholar
Centre for Environmental Rights, groundWork, Greenpeace and 350.org (2016). Personal communication, 6 December 2016.Google Scholar
Competition Tribunal (2006). Merger between: Sasol Limited, Engen Limited, Petronas International Corporation Limited (Primary Acquiring Firms) and Sasol Oil (Pry) Ltd, and Engen Ltd (Primary Target Firms). Available at www.saflii.org/za/cases/ZACT/2006/15.pdf (accessed 17 August 2017).Google Scholar
Creamer, T. (2015). TFR confident of settling take-or-pay deals with 36 coal exporters. Engineering News, 4 March 2015.Google Scholar
Daniel, P, Grote, M, Harris, P and Shah, A. (2015). Fiscal Regimes for Mining and Petroleum: Opportunities and Challenges (Country Report No. 15/244). Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
DEA (Department of Environmental Affairs) (2014). Greenhouse Gas Inventory for South Africa 2000–2010. Pretoria: DEA.Google Scholar
DoE (Department of Energy) (2010). South African Energy Synopsis. Available at www.energy.gov.za/files/media/explained/2010/South_African_Energy_Synopsis_2010.pdf (accessed 17 August 2017).Google Scholar
DoE (Department of Energy) (2014). Strategic Plan 2015–2020. Pretoria: DoE.Google Scholar
DoE (Department of Energy) (2016). Annual Report 2015–16. Pretoria: DoE.Google Scholar
Eberhard, A. (2007). The political economy of power sector reform in South Africa. In The Political Economy of Power Sector Reform, ed. Victor, D. and Heller, T. C.. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 215–53.Google Scholar
Eberhard, A. (2011). The future of South African coal: market, investment, and policy challenges. Working Paper 100, Stanford University Program on Energy and Sustainable Development, Stanford.Google Scholar
EIUG (Energy Intensive Users Group) (2015). About EIUG. Available at www.eiug.org.za/about/ (accessed 17 August 2017).Google Scholar
Eskom (2014). Integrated Report 2014. Johannesburg: Eskom.Google Scholar
Fine, B. and Rustomjee, Z. (1996). The Political Economy of South Africa: From Minerals-Energy Complex to Industrialization. London: C. Hurst & Co.Google Scholar
Garg, V. and Kitson, L. (2015). G20 Subsidies to Oil, Gas and Coal Production: South Africa. London: Overseas Development Institute.Google Scholar
GSI (Global Subsidies Initiative) (2010). Defining Fossil Fuels Subsidies for the G20: Which Approach Is Best? Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
IDC (Industrial Development Corporation of South Africa Ltd) (2015). IDC Integrated Report 2015. Johannesburg: IDC.Google Scholar
Kingdon, J. (2014). Agendas, Alternatives, and Public Policies. Harlow: Pearson.Google Scholar
Koplow, D. (2015). Subsidies to energy industries. Encyclopedia of Energy 5, 749–64.Google Scholar
Lott, T. (2016). A political economy analysis of liquid fuel production incentives in South Africa. MPhil Dissertation, University of Cape Town.Google Scholar
Lott, T., Burton, J. and Rennkamp, B. (2016). The Political Economy of Fossil Fuel Subsidies in South Africa. Cape Town: Energy Research Centre, University of Cape Town.Google Scholar
Machingambi, M. (2014). Overcoming Obstacles to Policy Reform: The Case of South Africa. Nairobi: National Treasury. Available at http://web.unep.org/greeneconomy/sites/unep.org.greeneconomy/files/session_2_memory_machingambi_south_africa.pdf (accessed 17 August 2017).Google Scholar
Maqubela, T. (2014). Department’s strategic and annual performance plans: budget vote 29 2014/2015 Financial Year. PowerPoint presentation to the Select Committee on Economic Business Development, Department of Energy, Pretoria.Google Scholar
Marquard, A. (2006). The origins and development of South African Energy Policy. PhD thesis, University of Cape Town.Google Scholar
Matthews, C. (2015). Eskom: big clean up costs. Financial Mail, 27 August 2015.Google Scholar
Mohamed, S. (2007) Industrial policy for economic development proposals. In Rethinking South Africa’s Development Path: Reflections on the ANC’s Policy Conference Discussion Documents, ed. Edighji, O.. Johannesburg: Centre for Policy Studies, pp. 8185.Google Scholar
National Treasury (2010). Budget Review 2010. Pretoria: National Treasury.Google Scholar
National Treasury (2013). Estimates of National Expenditure. Pretoria: National Treasury.Google Scholar
National Treasury (2014a). Estimates of National Expenditure. Pretoria: National Treasury.Google Scholar
National Treasury (2014b). Estimates of National Expenditure. Pretoria: National Treasury. Available at www.treasury.gov.za/documents/national%2520budget/2014/ene/FullENE.pdf (accessed 17 August 2017).Google Scholar
National Treasury (2015). Estimates of National Expenditure. Pretoria: National Treasury.Google Scholar
National Treasury (2016a). Estimates of National Expenditure. Pretoria: National Treasury.Google Scholar
National Treasury (2016b). Budget Review 2016. Pretoria: National Treasury.Google Scholar
National Treasury (2016c). Personal communication with National Treasury official, 21 December 2016.Google Scholar
Nene, N. (2015). Remarks by Minister of Finance Mr Nhlanhla Nene. Available at www.treasury.gov.za/comm_media/speeches/2015/2015060301%2520-%2520Eskom%2520Speech.pdf (accessed 17 August 2017).Google Scholar
NPC (National Planning Commission) (2011). National Development Plan: Vision 2030. Pretoria: NPC.Google Scholar
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development) (2010). Measuring Support to Energy, version 1.0. Background Paper, OECD, Paris.Google Scholar
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development) (2015). OECD Companion to the Inventory of Support Measures for Fossil Fuels 2015. Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
PetroSA (2010). Annual Report 2010: Green with Energy. Cape Town: PetroSA.Google Scholar
PetroSA (2012). Annual Report 2012. Cape Town: PetroSA.Google Scholar
PetroSA (2013). Integrated Annual Report 2013. Cape Town: PetroSA.Google Scholar
Rentschler, J. and Bazilian, M. (2017). Reforming fossil fuel subsidies: drivers, barriers and the state of progress. Climate Policy 17(7), 891914Google Scholar
Roberts, S. and Rustomjee, Z. (2010). Industrial policy under democracy: apartheid’s grown-up infant industries? Iscor and Sasol. Transformation: Critical Perspectives on Southern Africa 71, 5075.Google Scholar
RSA (Republic of South Africa) (2007). Energy Security Master Plan: Liquid Fuels, Pretoria: Department of Minerals and Energy.Google Scholar
RSA (Republic of South Africa) (2008). Eskom Subordinated Loan Special Appropriation Act: Act No. 41 of 2008. Government Gazette 521(38973).Google Scholar
RSA (Republic of South Africa) (2015). Eskom Special Appropriation Act: Act No. 7 of 2015. Government Gazette 601(38974).Google Scholar
Rustomjee, Z., Crompton, R., Maule, A., Mehlomakulu, B. and Steyn, G. (2007). Possible Reforms to the Fiscal Regime Applicable to Windfall Profits in South Africa’s Liquid Fuel Energy Sector, with Particular Reference to the Synthetic Fuel Industry. Pretoria: Windfall Tax Task Team.Google Scholar
Steyn, G. (2001). Governance, finance and investment: decision making and risk in the electric power sector. PhD thesis, University of Sussex, Brighton.Google Scholar
TCTA (Trans-Caledon Tunnel Authority) (2014). Integrated Annual Report 2013–2014. Centurion: Trans-Caledon Tunnel Authority.Google Scholar
Transnet (2007). Transnet Annual Report 2006–2007. Johannesburg: TransnetGoogle Scholar
Victor, D. G. (2009). The Politics of Fossil Fuel Subsidies. Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
Whitley, S. (2013). Time to Change the Game: Fossil Fuel Subsidies and Climate. London: Overseas Development Institute.Google Scholar
Winkler, H. and Marquard, A. (2009). Changing development paths: from an energy-intensive to low carbon economy in South Africa. Climate and Development 1(1), 4765.Google Scholar

References

Amézquita Zárate, P. (2009). Aspectos económicos del gobierno de Carlos Lleras Restrepo (Colombia, 1966–1970). Revista Civilizar de Empresa Y Economía 1(1), 3653.Google Scholar
Arteaga, J. (2016). Resultados de la Brújula Minera 2016. Presentation at the Annual Congress of the Colombian Mining Association. Cartagena: Columbian Mining Association. Available at www.youtube.com/watch?v=ZYeHu8JyUzA (accessed 23 August 2017).Google Scholar
BP (British Petroleum) (2017). BP Statistical Review of World Energy. London: BP.Google Scholar
Caballero Argáez, C. and Bitar, S. (2015). The Liberal Rarity of South America: Oil and Mining Policy Reform in Colombia in the 2000s. Bogotá: Los Andes University.Google Scholar
Cabrera Leal, M. and Fierro Morales, J. (2013). Implicaciones ambientales y sociales del modelo extractivista en Colombia. In Minería En Colombia. Fundamentos Para Superar El Modelo Extractivista, ed. Salamanca, L. Garay. Bogota: Contraloría General de la República, pp. 89106.Google Scholar
Cardoso, A. (2015). Behind the life cycle of coal: socio-environmental liabilities of coal mining in Cesar, Colombia. Ecological Economics 120, 7182.Google Scholar
Cerrejón (2010). La Contribución Fiscal de Cerrejón a las Finanzas Públicas Nacionales y Territoriales 2009. Bogotá: Fundaciones Cerrejón.Google Scholar
Chen, D. and Perry, G. (2015). Mining Taxation in Colombia. Calgary: University of Calgary, School of Public Policy.Google Scholar
CODHES (Consultoría para los Derechos Humanos y el Desplazamiento) (2011). ¿Consolidación de qué? Informe sobre desplazamiento, conflicto armado y derechos humanos en Colombia 2010 (Codhes Informa No 77). Bogotá: CODHES.Google Scholar
Congreso de la República (2014). Informe de Ponencia para primer debate al Proyecto de Ley 071 de 2014, Cámara de Representantes. Bogotá: Imprenta Nacional de Colombia. Available at www.imprenta.gov.co/gacetap/gaceta.mostrar_documento?p_tipo=22&p_numero=071&p_consec=40876 (accessed 23 August 2017).Google Scholar
Correa, J. (2004). Sorpresa por desmonte del Plan Vallejo. El Tiempo, 16 July 2004.Google Scholar
DANE (Departamento Administrativo Nacional de Estadística) and Banco de la República (2015a). Informe de Coyuntura Económica Regional. Departamento del César 2014. Valledupar: DANE and Banco de la República.Google Scholar
DANE (Departamento Administrativo Nacional de Estadística) and Banco de la República (2015b). Informe de Coyuntura Económica Regional. Departamento de La Guajira 2014. Riohacha: DANE and Banco de la República.Google Scholar
El Tiempo (2002). Plan Vallejo, 4 años más. El Tiempo, 14 December 2002.Google Scholar
El Tiempo (2005). Se mantienen Plan Vallejo y zonas francas. El Tiempo, 11 February 2015.Google Scholar
FCFI (Fundación Cerrejón para el Fortalecimiento Institucional) (2009). La Contribución Fiscal de Cerrejón a las Finanzas Públicas Nacionales y Territoriales 2008. Bogotá: FCFI.Google Scholar
Fine, B. and Rustomjee, Z. (1996). The Political Economy of South Africa: From Minerals-Energy Complex to Industrialization. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Flórez Enciso, L. (2001). Colombia tras diez años de reformas políticas y económicas. Cuadernos Económicos 20(34), 3355.Google Scholar
Galindo, A. and Meléndez, M. (2010). Corporate tax stimulus and investment in Colombia. Working Paper Series No. IDB-WP-173, Inter-American Development Bank, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Garay Salamanca, L. (1998). La Promoción a las Exportaciones en Perspectiva. In Colombia: Estructura Industrial e Internacionalización 1967–1996. Bogotá: National Department of Planning.Google Scholar
Geels, F. W. (2014). Regime resistance against low-carbon transitions: introducing politics and power into the multi-level perspective. Theory, Culture and Society 31(5), 2140.Google Scholar
Glencore (2015). Executive Summary of Glencore’s Response to PAS/ASK’s Report on Glencore’s Activities at the Prodeco Group Coal Mine, Colombia. Available at www.glencore.com/assets/public-positions/doc/Glencores-response-to-PAS-ASK-report-April-2015.pdf (accessed 23 August 2017).Google Scholar
González Espinosa, A. (2013). Empresas y Promoción del Accountability Público para la Gestión Local de la Renta Extractiva. PhD Thesis, Institut d´Etudes Politiques, Paris.Google Scholar
González Espinosa, A. (2015). La paradoja del sector minero-energético en el Plan Nacional de Desarrollo 2014–2018: financiador de la paz y generador de tensiones en el territorio. In Anuario 2015. Seguimiento y Análisis de Policía Públicas en Colombia, ed. Isaza, C.. Bogotá: Universidad Externado de Colombia, pp. 105–15.Google Scholar
Granada López, A., Zárate Farias, R. and Sierra Reyes, P. (2016). Boletín de Comercio Exterior Correspondiente al Período Enero – Diciembre de 2015. Bogotá: Dirección de Impuestos y Aduanas Nacionales de Colombia.Google Scholar
GSI (Global Subsidies Initiative) (2010a). A How-to Guide: Measuring Subsidies to Fossil-Fuel Producers. Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
GSI (Global Subsidies Initiative) (2010b). Defining Fossil-Fuel Subsidies for the G-20: Which Approach Is Best? Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
IEA (International Energy Agency) (2016). Sankey diagram for Colombia, 2013. Available at www.iea.org/sankey/ (accessed 23 August 2017).Google Scholar
Insuasty Rodriguez, A., Grisales, D. and Gutierrez León, E. (2013). Conflictos asociados a la gran minería en Antioquia. Agora U.S.B. 13(2), 371–93.Google Scholar
Kern, F. (2011). Ideas, institutions and interests: explaining policy divergence in fostering ‘system innovations’ towards sustainability. Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy 29(6), 1116–34.Google Scholar
Lacouture, M. (2016): Exportar es cuestión de todos. El Tiempo, 4 December 2016.Google Scholar
Leal Buitrago, F. (1996). El estado colombiano: ¿crisis de modernización o modernización incompleta? In Colombia Hoy, ed. González, J. O. Melo. Bogota: Presidencia de la República.Google Scholar
Leal Buitrago, F. and Dávila Ladrón de Guevara, A. (2010). Clientelismo: El Sistema Político y su Expresión Regional. Bogotá: University of the Andes.Google Scholar
Long, G. (2017). Mining groups in Colombia fear popular backlash. Financial Times, 17 May 2017.Google Scholar
Mason, A. (2003). Colombia’s democratic security agenda: public order in the security tripod. Security Dialogue 34(4), 391409.Google Scholar
Mining Colombia (2011). El Gobierno se propone reestructurar las instituciones mineras y cambiar la estrategia de seguridad para el sector. Available at www.miningcolombia.com/descargas/boletines/008boletin.pdf (accessed 23 August 2017).Google Scholar
MME (Ministry of Mines and Energy) (2015a). Informe Eiti Colombia 2013. Bogotá: MME.Google Scholar
MME (Ministry of Mines and Energy) (2015b). Resolución 40659 de 2015. Bogotá: MME.Google Scholar
MME (Ministry of Mines and Energy) (2016). Política Minera de Colombia. Bases para la Minería del Futuro. Bogotá: MME.Google Scholar
MME (Ministry of Mines and Energy) (2017). Informe EITI Colombia Vigencias Fiscales 2015–2016. Bogota: MME.Google Scholar
MME (Ministry of Mines and Energy) (2018). Proyectos de Interés Nacional y Estratégico PINE. Available at www.minminas.gov.co/proyectos-de-interes-nacional-estrategico-pine (accessed 29 may 2018).Google Scholar
Morales Manchego, M. (2017). Fallo judicial tumba medida que le costó $ 13 billones a la Nación. El Tiempo, 30 October 2017.Google Scholar
Múnera Monte, L., Granados Castellanos, M., Teherán Sánchez, S. and Naranjo Vasco, J. (2014). Bárbaros hoscos: historia de resistencia y conflicto en la explotación del carbón en La Guajira, Colombia. Opera 14, 4769.Google Scholar
NDP (National Department for Planning) (2010). Plan Nacional de Desarrollo 2010–2014. Bogotá: NDP.Google Scholar
Nieves Zárate, M. and Hernández Vidal, A. (2016). Colombia Energy Investment Report. Brussels: Energy Charter Secretariat.Google Scholar
Olivera, M., Pachón, M. and Perry, G. (2010). The political economy of fiscal reform: the case of Colombia, 1986–2006. Working Paper No. 181, Inter-American Development Bank, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Pardo Becerra, L. (2012). Minería, Renta Minera y Tributación. Bogotá: Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung en Colombia.Google Scholar
Pardo Becerra, L. (2014). Análisis de los Beneficios Globales de la Industria Minera en Colombia. Improvisación, Opacidad e impactos en la economía. Bogota: Justicia Tributaria. Available at http://justiciatributaria.co/wp-content/uploads/2014/11/Beneficios-integrales-de-la-miner%25C3%25ADa_Resumen.pdf (accessed 26 September 2017).Google Scholar
Pardo Becerra, L. (2016). Radiografía de los Beneficios Onerosos en el Estatuto Tributario. Bogota: Justicia Tributaria. Available at http://justiciatributaria.co/wp-content/uploads/2016/12/Radiografia-de-los-beneficios-tributarios.pdf (accessed 23 August 2017).Google Scholar
Parra, G., Parra Garzón, D. and Sierra Reyes, P. (2014). El Gasto Tributario en Colombia. Beneficios en el Impuesto Sobre la Renta–Personas Jurídicas. Años Gravables 2012 y 2013. Bogotá: Dirección de Impuestos y Aduanas Nacionales de Colombia.Google Scholar
Pizarro Leongómez, E. (2002). La atomización partidista en Colombia: el fenómeno de las microempresas electorales. In Degradación o Cambio: Evolución del Sistema Político Colombiano, ed. Gutiérrez, F.. Bogotá: National University of Colombia, pp. 357401.Presidencia de la República (2003). Texto de la Alocución del Presidente Uribe tras las Aprobación de la Reforma Tributaria. Broadcasted Speech, 29 December 2003. Available at http://historico.presidencia.gov.co/prensa_new/discursos/reformatribu2003.htm (accessed 26 September 2017).Google Scholar
Presidencia de la República. (2013). Sí es posible la sana convivencia entre minería responsable y protección al medio ambiente: Presidente Santos. Press release on President Santos’ discourse at the National Congress on Mining and Oil. Available at http://wsp.presidencia.gov.co/Prensa/2013/Mayo/Paginas/20130515_09.aspx (accessed 26 September 2017).Google Scholar
Proyecto de Ley 071 (2014). Acción de simple nulidad contra el Concepto Tributario No. 015766 de 2005 de la DIAN. Available at www.imprenta.gov.co/gacetap/gaceta.mostrar_documento?p_tipo=05&p_numero=071&p_consec=39963 (accessed 23 August 2017).Google Scholar
Rojas, H. and Hopke, J. (2016). Opinión pública y actitudes sobre la minería en Colombia: ambivalencia y desinformación. In Minería y desarrollo. Minería y comunidades: impactos, conflictos y participación ciudadana, ed. Henao, J. and Espinosa, A. González. Bogotá: Universidad Externado de Colombia, pp. 497526.Google Scholar
Rudas Lleras, G. and Espitia Zamora, J. E. (2013). Participación del estado y la sociedad en la renta minera. In Minería En Colombia. Fundamentos Para Superar El Modelo Extractivista, ed. Salamanca, L. J. Garay. Bogotá: Contraloría General de la República, pp. 125–74.Google Scholar
Salazar, N. (2013). Political Economy of Tax Reforms: The Case of Colombia. Washington, DC: Wilson Center.Google Scholar
Sankey, K. (2013). El boom minero en Colombia: ¿locomotora del desarrollo o de la resistencia? Estudios Críticos del Desarrollo 3(4), 113–44.Google Scholar
Santos Calderón, J. (2014): Minería responsable: aliada del desarrollo de Colombia. Presented at the Inauguration of the 3rd Annual Congress of Responsible Mining, Agencia Nacional de Mineria, Cartagena.Google Scholar
Sarmiento, N. (2008). ¿Bondad o estrategia? Tejiendo responsabilidad social en el mundo del carbón. Colombia Internacional 67, 132–51.Google Scholar
SIMCO (Sistema Minero Colombiano) (2016). Estadísticas Available at www.simco.gov.co (accessed 23 August 2017).Google Scholar
Tierra Digna (2015). Seguridad y Derechos Humanos ¿para quién? Voluntariedad y Militarización, Estrategias de las Empresas Extractivas en el Control de Territorios. Bogotá: Centro de Estudios para la Justicia Social Tierra Digna.Google Scholar
Torres, A., Rocha, J., Melo, D. and Peña, R. (2015). El Carbón en Colombia ¿Quién Gana, Quién Pierde? Minería, Comercio Global y Cambio Climático. Bogotá: Centro de Estudios para la Justicia Social Tierra Digna.Google Scholar
Torres del Río, C. M. (2015). Colombia Siglo XX. Desde La Guerra de Los Mil Días Hasta La Elección de Álvaro Uribe. Bogotá: Editorial Pontifica Universidad Javierana.Google Scholar
Torres González, J. (2014). Colombia: Logros en dos décadas de modelo de desarrollo aperturista: análisis según resultados de balanza comercial. Análisis Político 27(82), 212–35.Google Scholar
Transparencia por Colombia (2014). Análisis de la Financiación de las Campañas Legislativas de Colombia en 2014. Bogotá: Transparencia por Colombia.Google Scholar
Valencia, L. and Riaño, A. (2017). La Minería en el Posconflicto. Un Asunto de Quilates. Bogotá: Ediciones B.Google Scholar
Vélez-Torres, I. (2014). Governmental extractivism in Colombia: legislation, securitization and the local settings of mining control. Political Geography 38, 68–78.Google Scholar
Veltmeyer, H. and Petras, J. (2014). The New Extractivism: A Post-Neoliberal Development Model or Imperialism of the Twenty-First Century? London: Zed Books.Google Scholar
Victor, D. G. (2009). The Politics of Fossil Fuel Subsidies. Geneva: Global Subsidies Initiative.Google Scholar

References

Akkas, H. and Ozekin, M. (2014). An empirical look to the Arab Spring: causes and consequences. Turkish Journal of International Relations 13(1–2), 7687.Google Scholar
Aman, A. (2016). Will Egyptians open their wallet to help Cairo get out of debt? Al Monitor, 14 March 2016.Google Scholar
Barany, Z. (2011). The role of the military. Journal of Democracy 22(4), 2839.Google Scholar
Baron, D (2013). Business and Its Environment, 7th edn. London: Pearson.Google Scholar
Beaton, C., Gerasimchuk, I., Laan, T. et al. (2013). A Guidebook to Fossil-Fuel Subsidy Reform. Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
Beissinger, M., Jamal, A. and Mazur, K. (2015). Explaining divergent revolutionary coalitions: regime strategies and the structuring of participation in the Tunisian and Egyptian revolutions. Comparative Politics 48(1), 124.Google Scholar
Blasi, G. and Jost, J. T. (2006). System justification theory and research: implications for law, legal advocacy, and social justice. California Law Review 94(4), 1119–68.Google Scholar
Brown, N. (2013). Tracking the ‘Arab Spring’: Egypt’s failed transition. Journal of Democracy 24(4), 4558.Google Scholar
Butter, D. (2013). Egypt in Search of Economic Direction. London: Chatham House.Google Scholar
Clarke, K. (2014). Egypt’s Recent Subsidy Reforms. Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
CMI (2013). The Egyptian Military in Politics and the Economy: Recent History and Current Transition Status. Bergen: Chr. Michelsen Institute.Google Scholar
Egyptian Streets (2016). Egypt’s Suez Canal earnings fall for third month in a row. Egyptian Streets, 23 March 2016.Google Scholar
El-Katiri, L. and Fattouh, B. (2015) A Brief Political Economy of Energy Subsidies in the Middle East and North Africa. Oxford: Oxford Institute for Energy Studies.Google Scholar
ERPIC (European Rim Policy and Investment Council) (2014). Energy Brief: Egypt’s Al-Sisi Addresses Energy Subsidy Issue. Cyprus: ERPIC.Google Scholar
Fattouh, B., Moerenhout, T. and Sen, A. (2016) Striking the Right Balance? GCC Energy Pricing Reforms in a Low Price Environment. Oxford: Oxford Institute for Energy Studies.Google Scholar
Griffin, P., Laursen, T. and Robertson, J. (2016). Egypt: guiding reform of energy subsidies long-term. Policy Research Working Paper WPS 7571, World Bank, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
IMF (International Monetary Fund) (2013a). Case Studies on Energy Subsidy Reform: Lessons and Implications. Washington, DC: IMF.Google Scholar
IMF (International Monetary Fund) (2013b). Energy Subsidy Reform: Lessons and Implications. Washington, DC: IMF.Google Scholar
James, L. M. (2014). Recent Developments in Sudan’s Fuel Subsidy Reform Process. Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D. (2013). Thinking, Fast and Slow, 1st edn. New York, NY: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.Google Scholar
Khalaf, R. (2016). Sisi’s Egypt: the march of the security state. Financial Times, 19 December 2016.Google Scholar
Kojima, M. (2016). Fossil fuel subsidy and pricing policies: recent developing country experience. Policy Research Working Paper WPS 7531, World Bank, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Madrian, B. (2014). Applying insights from behavioral economics to policy design. NBER Working Paper No. 20318, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Makara, M. (2013). Coup-proofing, military defection, and the Arab Spring. Democracy and Security 9(4), 334–59.Google Scholar
Marshall, S. (2015). The Egyptian Armed Forces and the Remaking of an Economic Empire. Beirut: Carnegie Middle East Center.Google Scholar
McMurray, D. and Ufheil-Somers, A. (2013). The Arab Revolts: Dispatches on Militant Democracy in the Middle East. Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press.Google Scholar
Moerenhout, T. (2017). Energy Pricing Reforms in Egypt. Oxford Energy Forum, 108, 3436.Google Scholar
Moerenhout, T., Vezanis, N. and Westling, C. (2017). Navigating Political Hurricanes in the MENA Region: Energy Pricing Reform in a Context of Changing Social Contracts. New York, NY: Columbia University Center on Global Energy Policy.Google Scholar
Muthuthi, C. (2014). African Economic Outlook: Egypt 2014. New York, NY: United Nations Development Programme.Google Scholar
Paciello, M. (2013). Economic and social policies in post-Mubarak Egypt. Insight Egypt 3. Available at www.iai.it/sites/default/files/inegypt_03.pdf (accessed 23 August 2017).Google Scholar
Sdrazlevich, C., Randa, S., Younes, Z., and Albertin, G. (2014). Subsidy Reform in the Middle East and North Africa. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
The Economist (2015). Worse than Mubarak. The Economist, 2 May 2015.Google Scholar
Victor, D. G. (2009). The Politics of Fossil-Fuel Subsidies. Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
Walsh, D. (2016). Where’s my Mercedes? Egypt’s financial crisis hits the rich. New York Times, 10 March 2016.Google Scholar
Williamson, J. (ed.) (1994). The Political Economy of Policy Reform. Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics.Google Scholar
World Bank (2015). US$400 million program to support 1.5 million poor Egyptian families through enhanced social safety nets. Available at www.worldbank.org/en/news/press-release/2015/04/10/us400-million-program-to-support-15-million-poor-egyptian-families-through-enhanced-social-safety-nets (accessed 23 August 2017).Google Scholar
World Bank (2017). World development indicators. Available at http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators (accessed 23 August 2017).Google Scholar

References

Ali, L. (2016). Budget 2016/2017: a closer look at the fuel subsidy. Trinidad and Tobago 103 FM. Available at http://103fm.tt/?p=11705 (accessed 24 August 2017).Google Scholar
AlShehabi, O. H. (2012). Energy and labour reform: evidence from Iran. Journal of Policy Modeling 34(3), 441–59.Google Scholar
Arzaghi, M. and Squalli, J. (2015) How price inelastic is demand for gasoline in fuel-subsidizing economies? Energy Economics 50(C), 117–24.Google Scholar
Arze del Granado, F. J. and Coady, D. (2012) The unequal benefits of fuel subsidies: a review of evidence for developing countries. World Development 40(11), 2234–48.Google Scholar
Baer, P., Athanasiou, T., Kartha, S. and Kemp-Benedict, E. (2008). The Right to Development in a Climate Constrained World: The Greenhouse Development Rights Framework. Berlin: Heinrich Böll Foundation, Christian Aid, EcoEquity and Stockholm Environment Institute.Google Scholar
Baptiste, A. K. and Rhiney, K. (2016). Climate justice and the Caribbean: an introduction. Geoforum 73, 1721.Google Scholar
Barrett, S. (2013). Local level climate justice? Adaptation finance and vulnerability reduction. Global Environmental Change 23(6), 1819–29.Google Scholar
Boardman, B. (2010), Fixing Fuel Poverty: Challenges and Solutions. London: Earthscan.Google Scholar
C News (2016). FITUN won’t support any proposal to remove fuel subsidy. Available at http://ctntworld.com/ctv/index.php/c-news/news/item/724-fitun-won-t-support-any-proposal-to-remove-fuel-subsidy (accessed 24 August 2017).Google Scholar
Caney, S. (2010). Climate change and the duties of the advantaged. Critical Review of International Social and Political Philosophy 13(1), 203–28.Google Scholar
CIA (Central Intelligence Agency) (2017) The World Factbook. Available at www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/geos/td.html (accessed 24 August 2017).Google Scholar
Cheon, A., Lackner, M. and Urpelainen, J. (2015). Instruments of political control: national oil companies, oil prices, and petroleum subsidies. Comparative Political Studies 48(3), 370402.Google Scholar
Collister, K. (2016). Jamaica beyond the IMF (Part 2): Caricom, Brexit and Jamexit. Jamaica Observer, 25 July 2016.Google Scholar
Commander, S. (2012). A guide to the political economy of reforming energy subsidies. IZA Policy Paper No. 52, Institute for the Study of Labor, Bonn.Google Scholar
de Moor, A. (2001). Towards a grand deal on subsidies and climate change. Natural Resources Forum 25, 167–76.Google Scholar
Dube, I. (2003). Impact of energy subsidies on energy consumption and supply in Zimbabwe: do the urban poor really benefit? Energy Policy 31(15), 1635–45.Google Scholar
Duus-Otterström, G. and Jagers, S. C. (2012). Identifying burdens of coping with climate change: a typology of the duties of climate justice. Global Environmental Change 22(3), 746–53.Google Scholar
Energy Chamber (2017). Enhanced oil and gas recovery in the works at Petrotrin. Trinidad and Tobago: The Energy Chamber of Trinidad and Tobago. Available at http://energynow.tt/blog/enhanced-oil-and-gas-recovery-in-the-works-at-petrotrin (accessed 24 August 2017).Google Scholar
Fry, I. (2005). Small island developing states: becalmed in a sea of soft law. Review of European Community and International Environmental Law 14(2), 8999.Google Scholar
Gangopadhyaya, S., Ramaswamia, B. and Wadhwaa, W. (2005). Reducing subsidies on household fuels in India: how will it affect the poor? Energy Policy 33(18), 2326–36.Google Scholar
GORTT (Government of the Republic of Trinidad and Tobago) (2012a). Budget Statement 2013: Stimulating Growth, Generating Prosperity. Available at www.guardian.co.tt/sites/default/files/story/Budget-Statement-2013.pdf (accessed 24 August 2017).Google Scholar
GORTT (Government of the Republic of Trinidad and Tobago) (2012b). Trinidad and Tobago National Climate Change Policy. Port of Spain: GORTT.Google Scholar
GORTT (Government of the Republic of Trinidad and Tobago) (2015). Intended Nationally Determined Contribution (INDC) under the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change. Port of Spain: GORTT.Google Scholar
GORTT (Government of the Republic of Trinidad and Tobago) (2017a). National Environmental Policy, Republic of Trinidad and Tobago. Port of Spain: Ministry of Environment and Water Resources.Google Scholar
GORTT (Government of the Republic of Trinidad and Tobago) (2017b). Oil and Gas Industry: Overview. Available at www.energy.gov.tt/our-business/oil-and-gas-industry (Accessed 24 August 2017).Google Scholar
Harrinanan, S. (2015). Balgobin: ‘just and courageous budget’. Trinidad and Tobago Newsday, 8 October 2015.Google Scholar
Hochman, G. and Zilberman, D. (2015). The political economy of OPEC. Energy Economics 48(C), 203–16.Google Scholar
Humpert, M. E. and Espinosa, R. (2016). Energy Dossier: Trinidad and Tobago. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.Google Scholar
Imbert, C. (2016a). 2016 Mid Year Budget Review. Port of Spain: GORTT.Google Scholar
Imbert, C. (2016b). Shaping a Better Future: A Blueprint for Transformation and Growth. Port of Spain: GORTT.Google Scholar
Imbert, C. (2016c). Finance (Variation of Appropriation) (Financial Year 2016) Bill, Parliament of Trinidad and Tobago, Port of Spain.Google Scholar
Imbert, C. and Khan, F. (2016). The Finance Bill 2016, Parliament of Trinidad and Tobago, Post of Spain.Google Scholar
Imbert, C. and Raffoul, J. (2017). Finance (Variation of Appropriation) (Financial Year 2017) Bill, Parliament of Trinidad and Tobago, Port of Spain.Google Scholar
IMF (International Monetary Fund) (2016). Trinidad and Tobago: Staff Report for the 2016 Article IV Consultation. Washington, DC: IMF.Google Scholar
Iwaro, J. and Mwasha, A. (2010). Towards energy sustainability in the world: the implications of energy subsidy for developing countries. International Journal of Energy and the Environment, 1(4), 705–14.Google Scholar
Jakob, M., Chen, C., Fuss, S. et al. (2015). Development incentives for fossil fuel subsidy reform. Nature Climate Change 5(8), 709–12.Google Scholar
Jiang, Z., Ouyang, X. and Huang, G. (2015). The distributional impacts of removing energy subsidies in China. China Economic Review 33(C), 111–22.Google Scholar
Keohane, R. O. (1969). Lilliputians’ dilemmas: small states in international politics. International Organization, 23(2), 291310.Google Scholar
Khelawan, V. (2013). Liat wants same fuel subsidy. Trinidad and Tobago Newsday, 23 May 2013.Google Scholar
Koplow, D. and Dernbach, J. (2001). Federal fossil fuel subsidies and greenhouse gas emissions: a case study of increasing transparency for fiscal policy. Annual Review of Energy and the Environment 26, 361–89.Google Scholar
Lockwood, M. (2015). Fossil fuel subsidy reform, rent management and political fragmentation in developing countries. New Political Economy 20(4), 475–94.Google Scholar
Long, S. (2013). A closer look at T&T’s Fuel Subsidy, Commentary. Business Guardian, 17 October 2013.Google Scholar
Marzolf, N. C., Fernando Casado, C., Johanna, K. et al. (2015). A Unique Approach for Sustainable Energy in Trinidad and Tobago. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.Google Scholar
Mathur, A. and Morris, A. C. (2014). Distributional effects of a carbon tax in broader U.S. fiscal reform. Energy Policy 66(C), 326–34.Google Scholar
McCauley, D., Heffron, R. J., Stephan, H. and Jenkins, K. (2013). Advancing energy justice: the triumvirate of tenets. International Energy Law Review 32(3), 107–10.Google Scholar
Mertz, O., Halsnæs, K., Olesen, J. E. et al. (2009) Adaptation to climate change in developing countries. Environmental Management 43(5), 743–52.Google Scholar
Ministry of Energy and Energy Affairs (2017). Petroleum Register for Petroleum Sharing Contracts. Available at www.energy.gov.tt/petroleum-register (accessed 24 August 2017).Google Scholar
Ministry of Energy and Energy Industries (2016). Personal communication with an official from the Ministry of Energy on Trinidad and Tobago subsidy claim values, 22 April 2016.Google Scholar
Newsday (2016). ECA expresses concern. Trinidad and Tobago Newsday, 7 October 2016.Google Scholar
NWU (National Workers Union) (2016). NWU: No to Wage Suppression. Available at www.workersunion.org.tt/where-we-stand/nwu-media/nwunotowagesuppression (accessed 24 August 2017).Google Scholar
Okereke, C. (2010). Climate justice and the international regime. WIREs: Climate Change 1(3), 462–74.Google Scholar
Palanisamy, H., Becker, M., Meyssignac, B. et al. (2012). Regional sea level change and variability in the Caribbean Sea since 1950. Journal of Geodetic Science 2(2), 125–33.Google Scholar
Payne, A. (2004). Small states in the global politics of development. Round Table 93, 623–35.Google Scholar
Petrotrin (2015) Joint Ventures. Available at www.petrotrin.com/~/media/Files/JV%20Listing%20-%202015%2008%2014.ashx?la=en (accessed 24 August 2017).Google Scholar
Phillip, L. (2016). Budget 2016/2017: A Closer Look at the Fuel Subsidy. Trinidad and Tobago 103 FM. Available at http://103fm.tt/?p=11705 (accessed 24 August 2017).Google Scholar
Plante, M. (2014). The long-run macroeconomic impacts of fuel subsidies. Journal of Development Economics 107(C), 129–43.Google Scholar
Popke, J., Curtis, S. and Gamble, D.W. (2016). A social justice framing of climate change discourse and policy: adaptation, resilience and vulnerability in a Jamaican agricultural landscape. Geoforum 73, 7080.Google Scholar
Rao, N. D. (2012). Kerosene subsidies in India: when energy policy fails as social policy. Energy for Sustainable Development 16, 3543.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. (2005). A Theory of Justice. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Rhiney, K. (2015). Geographies of Caribbean vulnerability in a changing climate: issues and trends. Geography Compass 9(3), 97114.Google Scholar
Saboohi, Y. (2001). An evaluation of the impact of reducing energy subsidies on living expenses of households. Energy Policy 29(3), 245–52.Google Scholar
Scobie, M. (2016). Policy coherence in climate governance in Caribbean small island developing states. Environmental Science and Policy 58, 1628.Google Scholar
Scobie, M. (2017). Fossil fuel reform in developing states: the case of Trinidad and Tobago, a petroleum producing small island developing State. Energy Policy 104, 265–73.Google Scholar
Siddig, K, Aguiar, A, Grethe, H et al. (2014). Impacts of removing fuel import subsidies in Nigeria on poverty. Energy Policy 69, 165–78.Google Scholar
Small, D. (2016). Appropriation Bill 2016, Financial Year 2017, Parliament of Trinidad and Tobago, Port of Spain.Google Scholar
Soile, I. O., Tsaku, H. and Yar’Adua, B. M. (2014). The impact of gasoline subsidy removal on the transportation sector in Nigeria. American Journal of Energy Research 2(3), 6066.Google Scholar
Solaun, K., Gómez, I., Larrea, I. et al. (2015). Strategy for Reduction of Emissions in Trinidad and Tobago, 2040. Port of Spain: Government of the Republic of Trinidad and Tobago.Google Scholar
Sovacool, B. K. and Dworkin, M. H. (2015). Energy justice: conceptual insights and practical applications. Applied Energy 142, 435–44.Google Scholar
Sturge, W. (2016). Finance Bill, 2016, Parliament of Trinidad and Tobago, Port of Spain.Google Scholar
Taitt, R. (2016). Govt urged to penalise those with high usage. Trinidad Express, 21 October 2016.Google Scholar
Thomas, C. (2003). Taxi fares increase looming. Trinidad and Tobago Newsday, 8 October 2003.Google Scholar
Trinidad Guardian. (2011) Energy Chamber: time to phase out gas subsidy. Trinidad and Tobago Guardian, 17 June 2011.Google Scholar
Trinidad Guardian (2013). T&T rebuffs IMF call to end “unsustainable” fuel subsidies. Trinidad and Tobago Guardian, 14 August 2013.Google Scholar
Trotz, U. and Lindo, S. (2013). Vulnerability and resilience building in CARICOM countries. Small Island Digest 2, 2539.Google Scholar
TTEC (Trinidad and Tobago Electricity Comission) (2001). Summary of Electricity Rates. Available at https://ttec.co.tt/default/tariffs-2 (accessed 24 August 2017).Google Scholar
TTMA (Trinidad and Tobago Manufacturers’ Association) (2017). Brief on Manufacturing – Facts about Manufacturing in Trinidad and Tobago 2015. Available at http://ttma.com/business-development/facts-about-manufacturing (accessed 24 August 2017).Google Scholar
UNDP (United Nations Development Programme) (2016). Human Development Report. New York, NY: UNDP.Google Scholar
Vagliasindi, M. (2013). Implementing Energy Subsidy Reforms: Evidence from Developing Countries. Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
van Beers, C. and de Moor, A. (2001). Public Subsidies and Policy Failures: How Subsidies Distort the Natural Environment, Equity and Trade and How to Reform Them, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Victor, D. G. (2009). The Politics of Fossil-Fuel Subsidies. Geneva: International Institute for Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
Whitley, S. (2013). Time to Change the Game: Fossil Fuel Subsidies and Climate. London: Overseas Development Institute.Google Scholar
World Bank (2016). The World Bank Data Catalogue. Washington, DC: World Bank Group.Google Scholar
World Bank (2017). CO2 Emissions (metric tons per capita). Available at http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/EN.ATM.CO2E.PC (accessed 24 August 2017).Google Scholar
Yates, R. (2014). Recycling fuel subsidies as health subsidies. Bulletin of the World Health Organization 92(8), 547–47A.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 11.1 Timeline of fossil fuel subsidy reforms in Indonesia

(Sources: Beaton and Lontoh 2010; IMF 2013; ADB 2015; IEA 2016; Kojima 2016.)
Figure 1

Figure 11.1 Indonesia fuel prices compared to international oil market prices

(Sources: EIA 2017; World Bank 2017b.)
Figure 2

Figure 11.2 Fuel subsidies in Indonesia (2006–15)

(Source: Prawiraatmadja 2015.)
Figure 3

Figure 12.1 Challenges for distributors during the DBTL scheme rollout in India.

(Source: Authors’ analysis of survey data)
Figure 4

Figure 12.2 DBTL scheme’s impact on growth of sales for non-domestic and auto-LPG in India.

(Source: Authors’ analysis based on Petroleum Planning and Analysis Cell data.)
Figure 5

Table 13.1 Annual subsidy estimates by category for South Africa

Source: Authors’ calculations; Lott 2016; see Lott et al. 2016 for assumptions.
Figure 6

Table 13.2 Subsidies to coal and electricity production in South Africa

Figure 7

Table 13.3 Subsidies to the liquid fuels industry in South Africa

Figure 8

Table 14.1 Examples of subsidies to coal Extraction in Colombia by subsidy category

Sources: GSI 2010a, 2010b.
Figure 9

Table 15.1 Egypt’s 2014 and 2016 subsidy reforms

Source: Collected by author.
Figure 10

Figure 15.1 Stakeholder dynamics in Egypt.

Figure 11

Table 16.1 Transport fuels subsidised in Trinidad and Tobago

Source: Ministry of Energy and Energy Industries 2016.
Figure 12

Figure 16.1 Actors in fuel subsidy reform in Trinidad and Tobago.

Figure 13

Table 16.2 Actors and frames in fuel subsidy reform debates in Trinidad and Tobago

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×