Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-x5gtn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-30T12:55:52.567Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Great Britain: The Illusion of Governmental Authority

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 June 2011

Norman H. Keehn
Affiliation:
academic institution
Get access

Abstract

The capacity of the British Government to pursue and achieve economic purposes under liberal managed capitalism without the consent, cooperation, or passive acquiescence of organized producer groups is inherently limited. The ineluctable fact is that the British Government is dependent on the holders of economic power for achieving economic purposes. For this reason, national policy makers enter into partnership arrangements and contractual relationships with vital corporatist forces. Deliberate, premeditated, collaborative action is needed to ensure correlation between the government's intentions and achievements. Concertation, which represents a partnership between the public and private sectors as well as cooperative give-and-take in reaching agreements on economic objectives, enables the government to govern.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Trustees of Princeton University 1978

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Brittan, Samuel, “The Economic Contradictions of Democracy,” British Journal of Political Science, v (April 1975), 129–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Coates, David, “Politicians and the Sorcerer: The Problems of Governing with Capitalism in Crisis,” in King, Anthony, ed., Why is Britain Becoming Harder to Govern? (London: BBC Publications 1976), 3355Google Scholar; Douglas, James, “Review Article: The Overloaded Crown,” British Journal of Political Science, VI (October 1976), 483505CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

2 King, Anthony, “Overload Problems of Governing in the 1970s,” Political Studies, XXIII, Nos. 2–3 (1975), 284–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar; John P. Mackintosh, “The Declining Respect for the Law,” in King (fn. 1), 74–94.

3 Mackintosh, Ibid.

4 Gilmour, Ian, “A Chance to Do Something About the Sad State of Britain,” The Times, October 6, 1975, p. 12Google Scholar.

5 Butler, David and Stokes, Donald E., Political Change in Britain (London: Macmillan 1974), chap. 18CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Nordhaus, William D., “The Political Business Cycle,” Review of Economic Studies, XLII (April 1975), 169–89CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Douglas (fn. 1), 486–87.

6 Harold Macmillan explained the by-election setback suffered by the incumbent Conservative Party in 1962 by writing that the voters’ revolt “springs most from the Government's inability to keep the economy on an even course of continuous progress. It deplores ‘Stop-and-Go’ or ‘Acceleration and Brake.’” Macmillan, Harold, At the End of the-Day, 1961–1963 (London: Macmillan 1973), 58Google Scholar.

7 Brittan (fn. 1), 137–44; Beer, Samuel H., British Politics in the Collectivist Age (New York: Vintage Books 1969), 341–49Google Scholar.

8 See Douglas (fn. 1), 483–505; King (fn. 2), 284–95.

9 LaPorte, Todd R., ed., Organized Social Complexity: Challenge of Politics and Policy (Princeton: Princeton University Press 1975), chap. 1.Google Scholar

10 See Harris, Nigel, Competition and the Corporate Society (London: Methuen & Co. 1972), 203Google Scholar; Beer, Samuel H., “The British Legislature and the Problem of Mobilizing Consent,” in Frank, Elke, ed., Lawmakers in a Changing World (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall 1966), 3048Google Scholar; Dow, J.C.R., The Management of the British Economy (London: Cambridge University Press 1964), 3435Google Scholar; Punnett, R. M., British Government and Politics (London: Heinemann 1968), 420–22Google Scholar.

11 Cairncross, , “Incomes Policy: Retrospective and Prospect,” The Three Banks Review (London: National and Commercial Banking Group Ltd., December 1973), 21Google Scholar.

12 Jacoby, Neil, Corporate Power and Social Responsibility (New York: Macmillan 1973), 11Google Scholar.

13 For a discussion, see Barry, Brian M., “The Economic Approach to the Analysis of Power and Conflict,” Government and Opposition, IX (Spring 1974), 189223CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Ilchman, Warren F. and Uphoff, Norman Thomas, The Political Economy of Change (Berkeley: University of California Press 1971), chap. 3Google Scholar.

14 Jennifer Nias, “The Sorcerer's Apprentice: A Case-Study of Complexity in Educational Institutions,” in LaPorte (fn. 9), 217.

15 Laski, Harold J., Authority in the Modern State (London: Archon Books 1968), 35, 54–47, 66–67Google Scholar; Dejouvenel, Bertrand, Sovereignty (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1957), 29, 31, 79Google Scholar.

16 Gilmour, , “Reforming the State by Making It Work for the People,” The Times, October 6, 1975, p. 12Google Scholar.

17 See, for example, Beer (fn. 7), 71–78, 320–31; Gilmour (fn. 16); Douglas (fn. 1), 500–501; Mackintosh (fn. 2), 81–88; Eckstein, Harry, Pressure Group Politics: The Case of the British Medical Association (Stanford: Stanford University Press 1960), 19, 22–24Google Scholar; Clegg, Hugh A., The System of Industrial Relations in Great Britain (Oxford: Basil Blackwell 1976), 399Google Scholar.

18 Ionescu, Ghita, Centripetal Politics (London: Hart-Davis, MacGibbon 1975), 12Google Scholar; Smith, Bruce L. R., ed., The New Political Economy: The Public Use of the Private Sector (London: Macmillan 1975)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

19 For further elaboration, see Coombes, David, “‘Concertation’ in the Nation-State and in the European Community,” in Ionescu, Ghita, ed., Between Sovereignty and Integration (London: Croom Helm 1974), 8694Google Scholar; Ionescu (fn. 18), 1–9.

20 For further details, see Harris (fn. 10), chap. 2; Beer (fn. 7), chap. 7.

21 Winch, Donald, Economics and Policy (London: Collins-Fontana 1969), 286Google Scholar; Harris (fn. 10), chap. 11.

22 See, for example, Beer (fn. 7), 200–204; Flanders, Allan, Trade Unions (London: Hutchinson's University Library 1967), 76, 107Google Scholar; Hawkins, Kevin, British Industrial Relations (London: Barrie & Jenkins 1976), 2025, 175Google Scholar; Shonfield, Andrew, Modern Capitalism (London: Oxford University Press 1967), 112–19, 160Google Scholar.

23 For further elaboration, see Leruez, Jacques, Economic Planning and Politics in Britain (New York: Harper & Row 1976), chap. 4Google Scholar; Shonfield (fn. 22), chap. 8.

24 In the words of Kevin Hawkins, “the TUC wanted full participation in the making of government policy affecting the economy as a whole and nothing less. Without such participation an incomes policy could not succeed” (fn. 22), 45.

25 Brittan, Samuel, Steering the Economy (London: Harmondsworth 1971), 164Google Scholar; Leruez (fn. 23), 114.

26 Ibid., 115; Shonfield (fn. 22), 217–19.

27 Leruez (fn. 23), 118, 201. See also Jones, Aubrey, The New Inflation: The Politics of Prices and Incomes (London: Andre Deutsch 1973), 120–24, 185–86Google Scholar. The major set-back suffered by the Conservative Party in the 1962 by-election was attributed to the pay pause. See Macmillan (fn. 6), 58–63.

28 Mills, Daniel Quinn, Government, Labor, and Inflation: Wage Stabilization in the United States (Chicago: University of Chicago Press 1975), 264Google Scholar. See also Hawkins (fn. 24), 153.

29 Panitch, Leo, Social Democracy and Industrial Militancy: The Labour Party, the Trade Unions and Incomes Policy, 1945–1974 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 1976), 6768CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

30 See Corina, John, “Planning and the British Labour Market: Incomes and Manpower Policy, 1965–70,” in Hayward, Jack and Watson, Michael, eds., Planning, Politics and Public Policy (London: Cambridge University Press 1975), 180, 185Google Scholar; Jones (fn. 27), 135, 162–72; Fels, Allan, The British Prices and Incomes Board (London: Cambridge University Press 1972), chap. 4Google Scholar.

31 Hawkins (fn. 24), 32; see also Clegg (fn. 17), 403–6.

32 See Hawkins (fn. 24), 40–49, 63–64, 83–86; Cairncross (fn. 11), 17, 21; Flanders (fn. 22), 53–54; Clegg (fn. 17), 292–96, 491–92.

33 Robinson, Derek, “Implementing an Incomes Policy,” Industrial Relations, VIII (October 1968), 85Google Scholar.

34 For details, see Wilson, Harold, The Labour Government, 1964–1970 (London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson 1971), esp. chaps. 21 and 23Google Scholar. See also Grossman, Richard, The Diaries of a Cabinet Minister, II (London: Hamish Hamilton and Jonathan Cape 1976), 576–80Google Scholar.

35 Colin Crouch argues that the unions’ increasing militancy was a “defensive response” to the state's intrusion into free collective bargaining. See “The Drive for Equality: Experiences of Incomes Policy in Britain,” in Lindberg, Leon and others, Stress and Contradiction in Modern Capitalism (Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books 1975), 227Google Scholar. Conversely, Leo Panitch maintains that the government's failure to control prices was a precipitating factor in wage militancy (fn. 29), 214.

36 The Labour Government adopted a “tough incomes policy” because it was dependent on the financial support of international bankers. In exchange for their financial support, the bankers insisted on a strong prices and incomes policy. See Crossman (fn. 34), 720, 746.

37 De Jouvenel (fn. 15), 237.

38 The details of the Act and its consequences are provided by Engleman, S. R. and Thomson, A.W.J., “Experience Under the British Industrial Relations Act,” Industrial Relations, XIII (May 1974), 130–55Google Scholar; Hawkins (fn. 24), chap. 3; Gould, William B., “Taft-Hartley Comes to Great Britain: Observations on the Industrial Relations Act of 1971,” Yale Law Journal, Vol. 81 (July 1972), 1421–86CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Weekes, Brian and others, Industrial Relations and the Limits of the Law (Oxford: Basil Blackwell 1975)Google Scholar.

39 Panitch, Leo, “The Development of Corporatism in Liberal Democracies,” Comparative Political Studies, X (April 1977), 86Google Scholar.

40 The details are provided by Wootton, Barbara, Incomes Policy: An Inquest and a Proposal (London: Davis-Poynter 1974), chap. 3Google Scholar; Leruez (fn. 23), chap. 17; Hawkins (fn. 24), 146–54.

41 This theme is pursued with eloquence and cogency by Hirsch, Fred, Social Limits to Growth (Cambridge: Harvard University Press 1976)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

42 Olson, Mancur Jr., The Logic of Collective Action (Cambridge: Harvard University Press 1965), 21Google Scholar.

43 See Wallich, Henry C. and Weintraub, Sidney, “A Tax-Based Incomes Policy,” Journal of Economic Issues, V (June 1971), 119CrossRefGoogle Scholar. The authors propose a surcharge levy on corporate profits taxes if corporations grant wage increases in excess of the “guiding light” wage norm. Their aim is to stiffen the resolve of employers to resist excessive wage demands. The resultant lower wage increases would contribute to a reduced rate of inflation.

44 See Blackaby, Frank, “Incomes Policies and Inflation,” National Institute Economic Review, V (November 1971), 49Google Scholar.

45 Mandeville, , The Fable of the Bees: or Private Vices, Publick Benefits (New York: Capricorn Books 1962), 263CrossRefGoogle Scholar.