Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-22dnz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-26T12:49:06.457Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Monetary Policy Deliberations: Committee Size and Voting Rules*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 August 2016

Vincent Maurin
Affiliation:
European University Institute. Email: vincent.maurin@eui.eu
Jean-Pierre Vidal
Affiliation:
European Central Bank and Centre d’Economie de la Sorbonne (UMR 8174). Email: jean-pierre.vidal@ecb.europa.eu
Get access

Summary

How large should a monetary policy committee be? Which voting rule should a monetary policy committee adopt? This paper builds on Condorcet's jury theorem to analyse the relationships between committee size and voting rules in a model where policy discussions are subject to a time constraint. It suggests that in large committees majority voting is likely to enhance policy outcomes. Under unanimity (consensus) it is preferable to limit the size of the committee. Finally, supermajority voting rules are social contrivances that contribute to policy performance in a more uncertain environment, when initial policy proposals are less likely to be correct, or when payoffs are asymmetric.

Quelle est la taille optimale d'un comité de politique monétaire? Quelle est la meilleure règle de vote? Dans l'esprit du théorème de Condorcet, cet article propose un modèle de prise de décision contenant des phases de délibération pendant lesquels les membres du comité peuvent changer de position. Ce processus de délibération est conclu par une décision qui peut être prise à l'unanimité, à la majorité simple ou à la majorité qualifiée. En termes de performance, la majorité simple apparaît plus efficace pour les comités composés d'un grand nombre de membres. En revanche, décider à l'unanimité n'est profitable que dans les comités de petite taille. D'une manière générale, les règles de super-majorité sont adaptées dans un environnement incertain, lorsque les propositions initiales ont moins de chance d'être correctes, ou dans des problèmes de décision asymétrique, quand la perte liée à l'adoption d'une mauvaise proposition est plus élevée que celle du rejet d'une bonne proposition.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain, Institut de recherches économiques et sociales 2015 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

We would like to thank Alessandra Casella and Eric Leeper for stimulating discussions at an early stage of this project, Beata Bierut, Ludger Schuknecht and an anonymous referee for helpful comments. Suggestions by Philippine Cour-Thimann and Alexander Jung, as well as by participants at the 25 November 2011 meeting of the ECB Research Coordination Committee Forum on Central Bank Decision-making and Central Bank Communication and at the 15 March 2012 seminar of IRES (Louvain-la-Neuve) are gratefully acknowledged. This paper was started when Vincent Maurin was a trainee in the Monetary Policy Strategy Division. The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the ECB.

References

Apel, M., Claussen, C. A., and Lennartsdotter, P. Picking the brains of mpc members. Working Paper Series 237, Sveriges Riksbank (Central Bank of Sweden), Jan. 2010.Google Scholar
Austen-Smith, D., and Banks, J. Information aggregation, rationality and the condorcet jury theorem. American Political Science Review (1996).Google Scholar
Austen-Smith, D., and Feddersen, T. J. Deliberation, preference uncertainty and voting rules. American Political Science Review (2006).Google Scholar
Berg, S. Condorcet’s jury theorem, dependency among jurors. Social Choice and Welfare (1993).Google Scholar
Berk, J. M., and Bierut, B. K. Committee structure and its implications for monetary policy. Tech. rep., Tinbergen Institute, 2003.Google Scholar
Berk, J. M., and Bierut, B. K. Communication in a monetary policy committee. European Journal of Political Economy 27, 4 (2011), 791801.Google Scholar
Besley, T., Meads, N., and Surico, P. Insiders versus outsiders in monetary policymaking. American Economic Review 98, 2 (May 2008), 218–23.Google Scholar
Bhattacharjee, A., and Holly, S. Understanding interactions in social network and committees. Tech. rep., Faculty of Economics, University of Cambridge, 2009.Google Scholar
Blinder, A. Monetary policy committee: Why and how? European Journal of Political Economy (2007).Google Scholar
Claussen, C. A., and Roisland, O. The discursive dilemma in monetary policy. Tech. rep., Sveriges Riskbank (Central Bank of Sweden), 2010.Google Scholar
de Condorcet, M. Essai sur l’application de l’analyse à la probabilité des décisions rendues à la pluralité des voix. Imprimerie Royale, 1785.Google Scholar
de Marzo, P. M., Vayanos, D., and Zwiebel, J. Persuasion bias, social influence and unidimensionnal opinions. Quarterly Journal of Economics (2003).Google Scholar
ECB. Rotation of voting rights in the governing council of the ecb. ECB Monthly Bulletin (2009).Google Scholar
Erhart, S., and Vasquez-Paz, J.-L. Optimal monetary policy committee size: Theory and cross country evidence. Tech. rep., Magyar Nemzeti Bank (The Central Bank of Hungary), 2007.Google Scholar
Farvaque, E., Matsueda, N., and Mon, P.-G. HOW monetary policy committees impact the volatility of policy rates. Journal of Macroeconomics (2009).Google Scholar
Gerardi, D., and yariv, L. Deliberative voting. Journal of Economic Theory (2007).Google Scholar
Gerlach-Kristen, P. Too little, too late: Interest rate setting and the costs of consensus. Economic Letters (2005).Google Scholar
Gerlach-Kristen, P. Monetary policy committees and interest rate setting. European Economic Review (2006).Google Scholar
Gerlach-Kristen, P. The role of the chairman in setting monetary policy: Individualistic vs autocratically collégial mpcs. International Journal of Central Banking (2008).Google Scholar
Hansen, S., and Mcmahon, M. How experts decide: Identifying preferences versus signals from policy decisions. CEP Discussion Papers dpl063, Centre for Economic Performance, LSE, July 2011.Google Scholar
Kirman, A. Ants, rationality and recruitment. Quarterly Journal of Economics (1993).Google Scholar
Ladha, K. K. The condorcet jury theorem, free speech, and correlated votes. American Journal of Political Science (1992).Google Scholar
List, C., and Goodin, R. E. Epistemic democracy: Generalizing the condorcet jury theorem. Journal of Political Philosophy (2001).Google Scholar
Morimoto, K. Coordination behavior and optimal committee size. Tech. rep., Osaka University, Graduate School of Economics and Osaka School of International Public Policy (OSIPP), 2010.Google Scholar
Morris, S., and Shin, H. S. Social value of public information. The American Economic Review (2002).Google Scholar
Moulin, H., and Young, H. P. Condorcet, marie jean antoine nicolas cari- tat, marquis de (17431794). In The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, S. N. Durlaufand L. E. Blume, Eds. Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke, 2008.Google Scholar
Moutot, P., Jung, A., and Mongelli, F. P. The workings of the eurosystem monetary policy preparations and decision-making selected issues. Tech. rep., ECB Occasional Papers, 2008.Google Scholar
Ruge-Murcia, A. R. F. J. Preference heterogeneity in monetary policy committees. International Journal of Central Banking (2008).Google Scholar
Spencer, C. Consensus formation in monetary policy committees. Tech. rep., Department of Economics, University Of Surrey, 2005.Google Scholar
Vandenbussche, J. Elements of optimal monetary policy committee design. Tech. rep., International Monetary Fund, 2006.Google Scholar
Visser, B., and Swank, O. H. On committees of experts. Quarterly Journal of Economics (2007).Google Scholar