Hostname: page-component-7479d7b7d-c9gpj Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-12T21:10:38.758Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Growth–Employment Relationship and Leijonhufvud's Corridor

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 August 2016

Jean-Marie Le Page*
Affiliation:
Paris II Panthéon-Assas University Paris, France
Get access

Summary

Since 2008, the euro area unemployment rate has increased constantly, while this economy's GDP was the same at the end of 2012 as it was in 2008. The recent trend of aggregate economic activity in this area illustrates the risk that an economy leaves its stability corridor, in which it usually progresses in a cyclical way, to enter an area of turbulence. In this area, the automatic stabilizers have weak feedback forces. To examine this kind of situation in a theoretical framework, this paper presents a model that relies both on Leijonhufvud's corridor and on Harrod's instability principle. This model allows a threshold to be defined beyond which the economy runs the risk of entering a cumulative process of simultaneous declines in growth and employment. However, the existence of such a process requires unemployment to have a sufficiently direct effect on the growth in aggregate demand, as seems to be the case nowadays.

À partir de 2008, le taux de chômage de la zone euro n'a cessé d'augmenter alors que le PIB de cette zone était encore à la fin de 2012 au même niveau qu'en 2008. Cette évolution récente de l'activité globale illustre le risque couru par une économie de quitter le couloir de stabilité à l'intérieur duquel elle progresse d'une manière cyclique pour entrer dans une zone de turbulence. Dans cette zone, les stabilisateurs automatiques n'exercent qu'une faible force de rappel. Pour étudier à un niveau théorique ce type de situation, cet article présente un modèle qui associe le corridor de Leijonhufvud au principe d'instabilité de Harrod. Ce modèle met en évidence un seuil au-delà duquel l'économie risque de connaître un processus cumulatif de déclin simultané de la croissance et de l'emploi. Un tel mécanisme n'existe cependant que lorsque le chômage a une influence directe sur la demande globale comme cela semble être le cas dans la période actuelle.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain, Institut de recherches économiques et sociales 2015 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

1

I am grateful for helpful comments and suggestions from an anonymous reviewer. Paris II Panthéon-Assas University, Paris, France; mail address (personal); 37, rue du départ, 75014 Paris; E-mail: jean.lepage@wanadoo.fr; Tel: (33)1 43 22 20 27.

References

Akerlof, G. and Shiller, R. J. (2009), Animal Spirits, Princeton, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Aspromourgos, T. (2012), “Keynes’s General Theory after 75 Years: Chapter 24 and the Character of Keynesian Policy”, Economic Record, Special Issue, vol. 88, June, pp. 149157.Google Scholar
Ball, L.M. (2009), “Hysteresis in Unemployment: Old and New Evidence”, NBER Working Papers Series, W14818, March.Google Scholar
Bean, C. R. and Pissarides, C. (1993), “Unemployment, consumption and growth”, European Economic Review, vol. 37, pp. 837859.Google Scholar
Cross, R. (ed.) (1988), Unemployment, Hysteresis & the Natural Rate Hypothesis, Oxford, New York, Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
ECB (2012), “Recent Developments in the Okun Relationship in the Euro Area”, Box 3 of Economic and Monetary Developments, ECB Monthly Bulletin, July.Google Scholar
Haberler, G. (1937) Prosperity and Depression, New York, Harvard University Press, reprinted by Atheneum, 1963.Google Scholar
Hahn, F.H. and Matthews, R.C.O. (1964), “The Theory of Economic Growth: A Survey”, Economic Journal, vol. 74, pp. 779902.Google Scholar
Harrod, R. (1939) “An Essay in Dynamic Theory”, Economic Journal, vol. 49, (1), pp. 1433.Google Scholar
Harrod, R. (1973), Economic Dynamics, London, Macmillan.Google Scholar
Hoover, K. (2012), “Was Harrod Right?”, Duke University, CHOPE Working Papers, Center for the History of Political Economy at Duke University, Durham, January.Google Scholar
Krugman, P. (2009), The Return of Depression Economics and the Crisis of 2008, New York, London, W.W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
Krugman, P. (2012), End this Depression Now!, New York, London, W. W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
Leijonhufvud, A. (1973), “Effective Demand Failures”, Swedish Economic Journal, vol. 75 (1), pp. 2748, and chapter 6 in Information and Coordination, New York, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 1981; pp. 103–129.Google Scholar
Leijonhufvud, A. (2008), “Keynes and the Crisis”, CEPR Policy Insight, 23, May.Google Scholar
Medio, A. and Lines, M. (2001), Non Linear Dynamics, A Primer, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Minsky, H.P. (1986), Stabilizing an Unstable Economy, New York, McGraw Hill, new edition by Yale University Press, 2008.Google Scholar
OECD (2010), OECD Indicators on Employment Protection, Annual Time Series Data 1985–2008. Paris.Google Scholar
Robinson, J. (1962), Essays in the Theory of Economic Growth, london, Macmillan.Google Scholar
Skidelsky, R. (2009), Keynes, the Return of the Master, London, Allan Lane.Google Scholar
Zezza, G. (2008), “US Growth, the Housing Market, and the Distribution of Income”, Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, Spring, Vol. 30, (3), pp. 375401.Google Scholar
Zipperer, B. and Skott, P. (2011), “Cyclical Patterns of Employment, Utilization, and Profitability”, Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, Fall, vol. 34 (1), pp. 2557.Google Scholar