Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-nmvwc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-26T01:13:43.229Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Quantification, Regulation, and Risk Assessment

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 February 2022

Douglas MacLean*
Affiliation:
Center for Philosophy and Public Policy, University of Maryland

Extract

One of the roles of government is to regulate new technologies and control the risks to life and health that they impose. This will be true according to any plausible theory of government or politics. There are many reasons for centralizing the control of technological risk. First, the problem can elude individual or decentralized solutions because the transaction costs for bargaining to take place are too high, either because many different actors each impose slight risks which are intolerable only in their aggregate, or else because one actor imposes significant risks which are distributed thinly over very many individuals. A second reason is that technological risks are often invisible, delayed, and exceptionally complex, so the costs of gathering enough information to make reasonable decisions can be so prohibitively high that they are incapable of being borne except at the most centralized levels of government where resources can be pooled.

Type
Part V. Technology and Risk Assessment
Copyright
Copyright © 1983 Philosophy of Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

1

My research has been supported by the National Science Foundation, grant number PRA-80-20019.

References

Coohran, Thomas B.; MacLean, Douglas; Pollard, Robert D.; and Weiss, Ellyn R. (1981). “Comments on the NRC Office of Policy Evaluation's ‘Discussion Paper: Safety Goals for Nuclear Power Plants.’” Unpublished.Google Scholar
Douglas, Mary and Wildavsky, Aaron. (1982). Risk and Culture. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Dubos, Rene. (1981). “Half-Truths About the Future.” The Wall Street Journal May 8: 26.Google Scholar
Hampshire, Stuart. (1978). “Morality and Pessimism.” In Public & Private Morality. Edited by Hampshire, Stuart. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Pages 1-22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lowranoe, William W. (1976). Of Acceptable Risk. Los Altos: William Kaufmann, Inc.Google Scholar
MacLean, Douglas. (1983a). “Quantified Risk Assessment and the Quality of Life.” In Uncertain Power: The Struggle for a national Energy Policy. Edited by Zinberg, Dorothy. New York: Pergamon Press, Inc.Google Scholar
MaoLean, Douglas. (1983b). “Social Values and the Distribution of Risk.” College Park, Md.: Center for Philosophy and Public Policy, University of Maryland. Unpublished.Google Scholar
Russell, Clifford. (1981). “The Morality of Cost-Benefit.” Regulation: 5(3): 2.Google Scholar
Slovic, Paul; Fischhoff, Baruch and Lichtenstein, Sarah. (1982). “Facts Versus Fears: Understanding Perceived Risk.” In Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases. Edited by Daniel Kahneman et al. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Pages 463-489.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Starr, Chauncey. (1969). “Social Benefit versus Technological Risk.” Science 165: 1232-1238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Starr, Chauncey. and Whipple, Chris. (1980). “Risks of Risk Decisions.” Science 208: 1114-1119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thompson, Michael. (1980). “An Outline of the Cultural Theory of Risk.” IIASA Working Paper WP-80-177. Laxenberg, Austria: International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis.Google Scholar
Thompson, Michael. (1983). “To Hell With the Turkeys: A Diatribe Directed at the Pernicious Trepidity of the Current Intellectual Debate on Risk.” Center for Philosophy and Public Policy Working Paper RC-5. College Park, Md.: Center for Philosophy and Public Policy, University of Maryland.Google Scholar
U.S. Nuclear Regulatory Commission. (1980). An Approach to Quantitative Safety Goals for Nuclear Power Plants. Advisory Committee on Reactor Safeguards. NUREG-0739. October 1980. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
U.S. Nuclear RegulatoryCommission. (1981a). Workshop on Frameworks for Developing a Safety Goal. NUREG/CP-0018, BNL-NUREG-51419. June 1981. Washington, D.C.: U.S Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
U.S. Nuclear Regulatory Commission. (1981b). Workshop on A Proposed Safety Goal. NUREG/CP-0020. September 1981. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
U.S. Nuclear Regulatory Commission. (1982). Safety Goals for Nuclear Power Plants: A Discussion Paper. NUREG-0880. February 1982. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Weisbrod, Burton A. (1968). “Income Redistribution Effects and Benefit-Cost Analysis.” In Problems in Public Expenditure Analysis. Edited by Chase, Samuel. Washington, D.C: The Brookings Institute. Pages 177-222.Google Scholar
Weiss, Ellyn R. (1981). “Union of Concerned Scientists Comments on Development of a Safety Goal.” Unpublished Memorandum. June 26, 1981.Google Scholar
Zeckhauser, Richard. (1975). “Procedures for Valuing Lives.” Public Policy 23: 419-464.Google Scholar