Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-gtxcr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-20T04:12:20.274Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Evolving political science: Biological adaptation, rational action, and symbolism

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 May 2016

Dustin Tingley*
Affiliation:
Department of Politics 130 Corwin Hall Princeton University Princeton, New Jersey 08544-1012 dtingley@princeton.edu
Get access

Abstract

Political science, as a discipline, has been reluctant to adopt theories and methodologies developed in fields studying human behavior from an evolutionary standpoint. I ask whether evolutionary concepts are reconcilable with standard political-science theories and whether those concepts help solve puzzles to which these theories classically are applied. I find that evolutionary concepts readily and simultaneously accommodate theories of rational choice, symbolism, interpretation, and acculturation. Moreover, phenomena perennially hard to explain in standard political science become clearer when human interactions are understood in light of natural selection and evolutionary psychology. These phenomena include the political and economic effects of emotion, status, personal attractiveness, and variations in information-processing and decision-making under uncertainty; exemplary is the use of “focal points” in multiple-equilibrium games. I conclude with an overview of recent research by, and ongoing debates among, scholars analyzing politics in evolutionarily sophisticated terms.

Type
Field Notes
Copyright
Copyright © Association for Politics and the Life Sciences 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1.Pinker, Steven, The Blank Slate: The Modern Denial of Human Nature (New York: Viking Press, 2002).Google Scholar
2.Masters, Roger, “Biology and Politics: Linking Nature and Nurture,” Annual Review of Political Science, 2001, 4:345369.Google Scholar
3.Alford, John and Hibbing, John, “The Origin of Politics: An Evolutionary Theory of Politics,” Perspectives on Politics, 2004, 2(4):707723.Google Scholar
4.Somit, Albert and Peterson, Steven, “Rational Choice and Biopolitics: A (Darwinian) Tale of Two Theories.” PS: Political Science and Politics, 1999, 32(1).Google Scholar
5.Somit, Albert and Peterson, Steven, “From Human Nature to Public Policy: Evolutionary Theory Challenges the ‘Standard Model,”’ in Somit, Albert and Peterson, Steven, eds., Human Nature and Public Policy: An Evolutionary Approach (New York: Palgrave, 2003).Google Scholar
6.Elster, Jon, Explaining Technical Change (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1983), p. 57.Google Scholar
7.Little, Daniel, Varieties of Social Explanation (Boulder: West View Press, 1991), p. 92.Google Scholar
8.Mayr, Ernst, Toward a new philosophy of biology: observations of an evolutionist (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1988), chapter 3.Google Scholar
9.Oster, George and Wilson, Edward, “A Critique of Optimization Theory in Evolutionary Biology.” in Sober, Elliott, ed., Conceptual Issues in Evolutionary Biology (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1984).Google Scholar
10.Little, , Varieties of Social Explanation, p. 100.Google Scholar
11.Stone, Peter“What Sort of Rationality Does Social Criticism Require?” Manuscript under review, Department of Political Science, Stanford University, 2003.Google Scholar
12.Harsanyi, John, “Rational-Choice Models of Political Behavior vs. Functionalist and Conformist Theories,” World Politics, 1969, 21(4):514515.Google Scholar
13.Little, , Varieties of Social Explanation, p. 96.Google Scholar
14.Johnson, James, “Conceptual Problems as Obstacles to Theoretical Progress in Political Science: Four Decades of Political Culture Research,” Journal of Theoretical Politics, 2003, 15(1):9697, 102–103.Google Scholar
15.Elster, , Explaining Technical Change, p. 70.Google Scholar
16.Boudon, and Raymond, , “Social mechanisms without black boxes.” In Social Mechanisms: An Analytical Approach to Social Theory, Hedstrom, Peter and Swedberg, Richard, eds. (Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press, 1998).Google Scholar
17.Rational Choice, Elster, Jon, ed. (New York: New York University Press, 1986).Google Scholar
18.Little, , Varieties of Social Explanation, p. 97.Google Scholar
19.Jackson, William A., “Functional Explanation in Economics: A Qualified Defense,” Journal of Economic Methodology, 2002, 9(2):169189.Google Scholar
20.Elster, Jon, Nuts and Bolts for the Social Sciences (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989), p. 78.Google Scholar
21.Elster, Jon, “Rational Choice History: A Case of Excessive Ambition,” in “Review and Response to Analytic Narratives,” American Political Science Review, September 2000, 94(3):694.Google Scholar
22.Elster, , Explaining Technical Change, p. 56.Google Scholar
23.Elster, Jon. Solonomic Judgments: Studies in the Limitations of Rationality, (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1989), pp. 3032.Google Scholar
24.Little, , Varieties of Social Explanation, pp. 6263.Google Scholar
25.Elster, , Solonomic Judgments.Google Scholar
26.Little, , Varieties of Social Explanation, p. 76.Google Scholar
27.Bates, Robert, Figuerido, Rui de, and Weingast, Bary, “The Politics of Interpretation,” Politics and Society, 1998, 26:603642.Google Scholar
28.Bates, Robert, “Letter from the President: Area Studies and the Discipline,” APSA-CP: Newsletter of the APSA Organized Section on Comparative Politics, 1996, 7(1):12.Google Scholar
29.Laitin, David, Hegemony and Culture: Politics and Religious Change among the Yoruba (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1986).Google Scholar
30.Laitin, David, “Political Culture and Political Preferences,” American Political Science Review, 1988, 82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
31.Johnson, Chalmers, “Preconception vs. Observation, or the Contributions of Rational Choice Theory and Area Studies to Contemporary Political Science,” PS: Political Science and Politics, 1997.Google Scholar
32.Wedeen, Lisa, “Conceptualizing Culture: Possibilities for Political Science,” American Political Science Review, 2002, 96(4):713728.Google Scholar
33.Johnson, James, “How Conceptual Problems Migrate: Rational Choice, Interpretation, and the Hazards of Pluralism,” Annual Review of Political Science, 2002, 5.Google Scholar
34.Binmore, Ken, Essays on the Foundations of Game Theory, (Cambridge: Basil Blackwell, 1990), p. 152.Google Scholar
35.Lieberman, Matthew, Schreiber, Darren, and Ochsner, Kevin, “Is Political Cognition Like Riding a Bicycle? How Cognitive Neuroscience Can Inform Research on Political Thinking,” Political Psychology, 2003, 24(4): 681704.Google Scholar
36.Tingley, Dustin, “Neurological Imaging as Evidence in Political Science: A review, critique and guiding assessment,” Social Science Information, 2006, 45(1):533.Google Scholar
37.Glimcher, Paul, Decisions, Uncertainty, and the Brain: The Science of Neuroeconomics (Cambridge: MIT Press, 2003).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
38.Elster, Jon, “Social Norms and Economic Theory,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 1989, 3(4):99117.Google Scholar
39.Marcus, George, Neuman, W. Russell, and MacKuen, Michael, Affective Intelligence and Political Judgment, (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2000).Google Scholar
40.Pinker, Steven, The Blank Slate.Google Scholar
41.Peterson, Somit, “Rational Choice and Biopolitics.”Google Scholar
42.Peterson, Somit, “From Human Nature to Public Policy.”Google Scholar
43.Elster, , Explaining Technical Change, p. 86.Google Scholar
44.Wildavsky, Aaron, “Choosing Preferences by Constructing Institutions: A Cultural Theory of Preference Formation,” American Political Science Review, 1987, 81(1).Google Scholar
45.Laitin, David, “Political Culture and Political Preferences,” American Political Science Review, 1988, 82.Google Scholar
46.Gerring, John and Barresi, Paul, “Putting Ordinary Language to Work: A min-max strategy of concept formation in the social sciences,” Journal of Theoretical Politics, 2003, 15(2):211.Google Scholar
47.Tooby, John and Cosmides, Leda, “The Psychological Foundations of Culture.” In The Adapted Mind: Evolutionary Psychology and the Generation of Culture, in Barkow, Jerome, Cosmides, Leda, and Tooby, John, eds., (New York: Oxford University Press, 1992).Google Scholar
48.Schmaus, Warren, “Is Durkheim the Enemy of Evolutionary Psychology?” Philosophy of the Social Sciences, 2003, 33(1):2552.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
49.Cosmides, Leda and Tooby, John, “Better than Rational: Evolutionary Psychology and the Invisible Hand,” The American Economic Review, 1994, 84(2):331.Google Scholar
50.Brown, Donald E., Human Universals (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1991).Google Scholar
51.Johnson, , “How Conceptual Problems Migrate.”Google Scholar
52.Binmore, Ken, Essays on the Foundations of Game Theory, (Cambridge: Basil Blackwell, 1990), p. 119.Google Scholar
53.Ibid., p. 152.Google Scholar
54.Bates, de Figuerido, and Weingast, , “The Politics of Interpretation,” 1998.Google Scholar
55.Marcus, Neuman, and MacKuen, , Affective Intelligence and Political Judgment, 2000.Google Scholar
56.Lupia, Arthur and Menning, Jesse, “Politics and the Equilibrium of Fear: Can Strategies and Emotions Interact?” forthcoming in Crigler, Ann, MacKuen, Michael, Marcus, George E., and Neuman, W. Russell, eds., The Political Dynamics of Feeling and Thinking (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2006).Google Scholar
57.Frank, Robert, Choosing the Right Pond (New York: Oxford University Press, 1985), pp. 2026.Google Scholar
58.Frank, Robert, Passions Within Reason: The Strategic Role of the Emotions (New York: Norton, 1988), pp. 5153.Google Scholar
59.Hirshleifer, Jack, “The Expanding Domain of Economics,” The American Economic Review, 1985, 75(6): 5368.Google Scholar
60.Thaler, Richard, “Anomalies: The Winner's Curse,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 1988, 2(1): 191202.Google Scholar
61.Thaler, Richard, The Winner's Curse: Paradoxes and Anomalies of Economics Life, (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1992).Google Scholar
62.Camerer, Colin, Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2003).Google Scholar
63.Harsanyi, .Google Scholar
64.Camerer, , Behavioral Game Theory.Google Scholar
65.Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, 48th Economic Conference: “How Humans Behave: Implications for Economics and Economic Policy,” Conference Overview printed in New England Economic Review, first quarter 2004.Google Scholar
66.Dubner, Stephen, “Calculating the Irrational in Economics,” New York Times, 28 June 28 2003, p. B7.Google Scholar
67.Barkow, Jerome, Cosmides, Leda, and Tooby, John, eds., The Adapted Mind: Evolutionary Psychology and the Generation of Culture, (New York: Oxford University Press, 1992).Google Scholar
68.Pinker, Steven, The Blank Slate.Google Scholar
69.Laland, Kevin and Brown, Gillian, Sense and Nonsense: Evolutionary Perspectives on Human Behavior, (New York: Oxford University Press, 2002).Google Scholar
70.Sperber, D. and Hirschfeld, L., “The cognitive foundations of cultural stability and diversity,” TRENDS in Cognitive Sciences, 2004, 8(1):4046.Google Scholar
71.Ekman, P., “Cross-cultural studies of facial expression,” In Darwin and facial expression: A century of research in review, Ekman, P., ed. (New York: Academic Press, 1973).Google Scholar
72.Ekman, P. and Davidson, R., The Nature of Emotion, (New York: Oxford University Press, 1994).Google Scholar
73.Rilling, J., Gutman, D., Zeh, T., Pagnoni, G., Berns, G., and Kilts, C., “A Neural Basis for Social Cooperation,” Neuron, 2002, 35:395405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
74.Yamagishi, Toshio, Tanida, Shigehito, Mashima, Rie, Shimoma, Eri, and Kanazawa, Satoshi, “You can judge a book by its cover: Evidence that cheaters may look different from cooperators,” Evolution and Human Behavior, 2003, 24:290301.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
75.Dennett, D. C., “How to Study Human Consciousness Empirically: or, Nothing Comes to Mind.” Synthese, 1982, 53:159180.Google Scholar
76.Tooby, John and Cosmides, Leda, “The Psychological Foundations of Culture.” In The Adapted Mind: Evolutionary Psychology and the Generation of Culture, Barkow, Jerome, Cosmides, Leda, and Tooby, John, eds. (New York: Oxford University Press, 1992).Google Scholar
77.Pinker, , The Blank Slate.Google Scholar
78.Cronk, Lee, That complex whole: culture and the evolution of behavior (Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1999).Google Scholar
79.Dennett, D. C., The Intentional Stance, (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1987), p. 247.Google Scholar
80.Tingley, Dustin, “Facial Discrimination: The Animal of the Political,” Paper presented at the 2002 American Political Science Association annual meeting, IPSA research committee #12: Biology and Politics, Boston.Google Scholar
81.Mayr, Ernst, Evolution and the Diversity of Life (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1976), p. 696.Google Scholar
82.Mayr, Ernst, Toward a new philosophy of biology: observations of an evolutionist (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1988), pp. 4950, 62.Google Scholar
83.Symons, Donald, “On the Use and Misuse of Darwinism in the Study of Human Behavior,” In Barkow, Jerome, Cosmides, Leda and Tooby, John, eds., The Adapted Mind: Evolutionary Psychology and the Generation of Culture (Oxford University Press: New York, 1992).Google Scholar
84.Ekman, , “Cross-cultural studies of facial expression.”Google Scholar
85.Davidson, Ekman, The Nature of Emotion.Google Scholar
86.Moller, A. P. and Swaddle, J. P., Asymmetry, Developmental Stability and Evolution (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1997).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
87.Thornhill, R. and Moller, A. P., “Developmental Stability, Disease and Medicine,” Biological Review, 1997, 72:497548.Google Scholar
88.Thornhill, R. and Gangestad, S., “Facial Attractiveness,” Trends in Cognitive Sciences, 1999, 3(12):454460.Google Scholar
89.Grammer, K. and Thornhill, R., “Human Facial Attractiveness and Sexual Selection: The Role of Symmetry and Averageness,” Journal of Comparative Psychology, 1994, 108:233242.Google Scholar
90.Lemley, Brad, “Isn't She Lovely?” Discover, February 2000.Google Scholar
91.Brown, , Human Universals.Google Scholar
92.Johnson, James, “Symbol and Strategy in Comparative Political Analysis,” American Political Science Association-Comparative Politics: APSA-CP Newsletter, Summer 1997, p. 8.Google Scholar
93.Johnson, James, “Why Respect Culture?” American Journal of Political Science, 2000, 44(3):405418.Google Scholar
94.Johnson, , “How Conceptual Problems Migrate: Rational Choice, Interpretation, and the Hazards of Pluralism.”Google Scholar
95.Johnson, , “Conceptual Problems as Obstacles to Theoretical Progress in Political Science: Four Decades of Political Culture Research.”Google Scholar
96.Rambo, Eric, “Symbolic Interests and Meaningful Purposes: Conceiving Rational Choice as Cultural Theory,” Rationality and Society, 1999, 11(3):317342.Google Scholar
97.Kertzer, David, Ritual, Politics, and Power (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1988).Google Scholar
98.Kertzer, David, Politics and Symbols: the Italian Communist Party and the fall of communism (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1994).Google Scholar
99.Johnson, James, “Symbol and Strategy in Comparative Political Analysis.”Google Scholar
100.Geertz, Clifford, The Interpretation of Cultures (New York: Basic Books, 1973).Google Scholar
101.Ibid., p. 68.Google Scholar
102.Cosmides, Leda and Tooby, John, “Consider the Source: The Evolution of Adaptations for Decoupling and Metarepresentations,” in Metarepresentations: A Multidisciplinary Perspective (Vancouver Studies in Cognitive Science, 10) Sperber, Dan, ed. (New York: Oxford University Press, 2000).Google Scholar
103.Ibid., chapter 5.Google Scholar
104.Thayer, Bradley A., “Ethnic Conflict and State Building,” in Somit, Albert and Peterson, Steven, eds., Human Nature and Public Policy: An Evolutionary Approach (New York: Palgrave MacMillan, 2003).Google Scholar
105.Dennett, Daniel, “How to Study Human Consciousness Empirically: or, Nothing Comes to Mind.”Google Scholar
106.Robson, Arthur, “The Biological Basis of Economic Behavior,” Journal of Economic Literature, 2001, 14(1): 930.Google Scholar
107.Morikawa, Tomonori, Hanley, James, and Orbell, John, “Cognitive Requirements for Hawk-Dove Games: A Functional Analysis for Evolutionary Design,” Politics and the Life Sciences, 2002, 21(1):312.Google Scholar
108.Metarepresentations: A Multidisciplinary Perspective (Vancouver Studies in Cognitive Science, 10), Sperber, Dan, ed. (New York: Oxford University Press, 2000).Google Scholar
109.Brown, Laland, Sense and Nonsense: Evolutionary Perspectives on Human Behavior.Google Scholar
110.Pinker, , The Blank Slate, p. 287.Google Scholar
111.Sowell, Thomas, A Conflict of Visions: Ideological Origins of Political Struggles (New York: Basic Books, 2002).Google Scholar
112.Pinker, , The Blank Slate.Google Scholar
113.Cartwright, John, Evolution and Human Behavior: Darwinian Perspectives on Human Behavior (Great Britain: Palgrave, 2001).Google Scholar
114.Ehrlich, Paul, Human Natures: Genes, Cultures, and the Human Prospect (New York: Penguin Books, 2000).Google Scholar
115.Robson, , “The Biological Basis of Economic Behavior,” 2001, pp. 1133.Google Scholar
116.Rilling, Gutman, Zeh, , Pagnoni, , Berns, , and Kilts, , “A Neural Basis for Social Cooperation.”Google Scholar
117.Morikawa, Hanley, and Orbell, , “Cognitive Requirements for Hawk-Dove Games.”Google Scholar
118.Stone, Peter, “On linking cognitive mechanisms to game play: A critique of Morikawa, Hanley, and Orbell,” Politics and the Life Sciences, September 2003, 22(2):3340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
119.Hanley, James E., Morikawa, Tomonori, and Orbell, John, “Modeling cognitive evolution: A reply to Stone,” Politics and the Life Sciences, September 2003, 22(2):4143.Google Scholar
120.Frank, , Passions Within Reason.Google Scholar
121.Elster, Jon, Alchemies of the Mind: Rationality and the Emotions, (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999).Google Scholar
122.Elster, Jon, Ulysses Unbound, (USA: Cambridge University Press, 2000).Google Scholar
123.Loewenstein, G., “Emotions in Economic Theory and Economic Behavior,” American Economic Review, 2000, 90(2):426432.Google Scholar
124.Marcus, Neuman, and MacKuen, , Affective Intelligence and Political Judgment, 2000.Google Scholar
125.Marcus, George, “The Psychology of Emotion and Politics.” In Oxford Handbook of Political Pscyhology. Sears, David, Huddy, Leonie, and Jervis, Robert, eds. (New York: Oxford University Press, 2003).Google Scholar
126.Sullivan, Dennis and Masters, Roger, “Happy warriors: leaders' facial displays, viewers emotions, and political support,” American Journal of Political Science, 1988, 32(2):345368.Google Scholar
127.McDermott, Rose, “The Feeling of Rationality: The Meaning of Neuroscientific Approaches to Political Science,” Perspectives on Politics, 2004, 2(4):691706.Google Scholar
128.Menning, Lupia, “Politics and the Equilibrium of Fear: Can Strategies and Emotions Interact?” forthcoming inThe Affect Effect: Dynamics of Emotion in Political Thinking and Behavior, Crigler, Ann, MacKuen, Michael, Marcus, George E., and Neuman, W. Russell, eds. (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).Google Scholar
129.Kertzer, , Ritual, Politics, and Power.Google Scholar
130.Nesse, Randolph, review ofFrank, Robert, Luxury Fever, Evolution and Human Behavior, 2001, 22:7174.Google Scholar
131.Barkow, Jerome, “Beneath New Culture is Old Psychology: Gossip and Social Stratification,” in The Adapted Mind, Barkow, Jerome, Cosmides, Leda, and Tooby, John, eds.Google Scholar
132.Wilkinson, Richard, Mind the Gap: Hierarchies, Health, and Human Evolution (Yale: New Haven, 2001).Google Scholar
133.Frank, , Luxury Fever.Google Scholar
134.Hirshleifer, , “The Expanding Domain of Economics,” p. 59.Google Scholar
135.Robson, , “The Biological Basis of Economic Behavior,” pp. 2324.Google Scholar
136.Wilkinson, , Mind the Gap, chapter 3.Google Scholar
137.The Society and Population Health Reader: Income Inequality and Health, Kawachi, Ichiro, Kennedy, Bruce, and Wilkinson, Richard, eds. (New York: The New Press, 1999).Google Scholar
138.Wilkinson, , Mind the Gap, pp. 3132.Google Scholar
139.Peterson, Somit, “Rational Choice and Biopolitics,” p. 40.Google Scholar
140.Wilkinson, , Mind the Gap, p. 16.Google Scholar
141.Dipboye, R., Arvey, R. D., and Terpstra, D. E., “Sex and Physical Attractiveness of Applicants as Determinants of Resume Evaluations,” Journal of Applied Psychology, 1977, 62:288294.Google Scholar
142.Waters, R., “Beauty and Job Application,” Fairleigh Dickinson University Bulletin, Spring 1988.Google Scholar
143.Patzer, Gordon, The Physical Attractiveness Phenomena (New York: Plenum Press, 1985).Google Scholar
144.Morrow, Paula and McElroy, James, “The Effects of Physical Attractiveness and Other Demographic Characteristics on Promotion Decisions,” Journal of Management, December 1990.Google Scholar
145.Hamermesh, Daniel and Biddle, Jeff, “Beauty and the Labor Market.” The American Economic Review, 1994, 84(5):11741194.Google Scholar
146.Biddle, Jeff and Hamermesh, Daniel, “Beauty, Productivity, and Discrimination: Lawyers' Looks and Lucre,” Journal of Labor Economics, 1998, 16(1):172201.Google Scholar
147.Etcoff, Nancy, Survival of the Prettiest: The Science of Beauty (New York: Doubleday, 1999).Google Scholar
148.Economist, , “Pots of Promise,” The Economist, 24 May 2003.Google Scholar
149.Wallace, Jennifer, “Strength, Courage, and Confidence: What Facial Difference Teaches Us,” P.A.L.S. Foundation, 2003.Google Scholar
150.Rankin, Marlene and Borah, Gregory, “Perceived Functional Impact of Abnormal Facial Appearance,” Presented at the American Society of Plactic Surgeons Annual Scientific Meeting, Orlando, Florida, 2002.Google Scholar
151.Kahn, A., Hottes, J., and Davis, W. L., “Cooperation and Optimal Responding in the Prisoner's Dilemma Game: Effects of Sex and Physical Attractiveness,” Journal of Social Psychology, 1971.Google Scholar
152.Solnick, Sara and Schweitzer, Maurice, “The Influence of Physical Attractiveness and Gender on Ultimatum Game Decisions,” Organizational Behavior & Human Decision Processes, 1999, 79.Google Scholar
153.Camerer, , Behavioral Game Theory, p. 6768.Google Scholar
154.Schubert, J. and Curran, M. A., “Appearance effects in political careers: Do politicians with good genes get more votes,” paper presented at the Human Behavior and Evolution Society Meetings, 2001, London, England, cited inSaad, Gad, “Evolution and Political Marketing,” in Human Nature and Public Policy: An Evolutionary Approach, Somit, Albert and Peterson, Steven, eds. (New York: Palgrave, 2003).Google Scholar
155.Tingley, , “Facial Discrimination.”Google Scholar
156.Wolf, Naomi, The Beauty Myth: How Images of Beauty are Used Against Women (New York: Harper Collins, 2002).Google Scholar
157.Langlois, J., Kalakanis, L., Rubenstein, A. J., Larson, A., Hallam, M., and Smoot, M., “Maxims or myths of beauty? A Meta-analytic and Theoretical Review,” Psychological Bulletin, 2000, 126:390423.Google Scholar
158.Cunningham, M. R., Roberts, A. R., Wu, C. H., Barbee, A. P., and Druen, P. B., “Their Ideas about Beauty, on the Whole, are the same as ours: Consistency and Variability in the Cross-Cultural Perception of Female Physical Attractiveness,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 1995, 68:261279.Google Scholar
159.Etcoff, , Survival of the Prettiest.Google Scholar
160.Jones, D., “Physical Attractiveness and the Theory of Sexual Selection: Results From Five Populations,” Museum of Anthropology, University of Michigan, 1996.Google Scholar
161.Jones, D. and Hill, Kim, “Criteria of Facial Attractiveness in Five Populations.” Human Behavior, 1993, 4(3):271296.Google Scholar
162.Wise, Jeff, “American Beauty,” Elle, February 2003, p. 184.Google Scholar
163.Thornhill, R. and Gangestad, S., “Human Facial Beauty: Averageness, Symmetry, and Parasite Resistance,” Human Nature, 1993, 4:237269.Google Scholar
164.Thornhill, Grammer, “Human Facial Attractiveness and Sexual Selection.”Google Scholar
165.Buss, D. M., “Sex Differences in Human Mate Preferences: Evolutionary Hypotheses Tested in 37 Cultures,” Behavioral Brain Sciences, 1989, 12:114.Google Scholar
166.Scheib, Joanna, Gangestad, Steven, and Thornhill, Randy, “Facial Attractiveness, Symmetry, and Cues of Good Genes,” Proceedings of the Royal Society of London B, 1999, 266:19131917.Google Scholar
167.Gangestad, S. W., Thornhill, R., and Yeo, R. A., “Facial Attractiveness, Developmental Stability, and Fluctuating Asymmetry,” Ethology and Sociobiology, 1994, 15:7385.Google Scholar
168.Jones, B. C., Little, A. C., Penton-Voak, I. S., Tiddeman, B. P., Burt, D. M., and Perrett, D. I., “Facial Symmetry and Judgments of Apparent Health: Support for a” Good Genes “Explanation of the Attractiveness-Symmetry Relationship,” Evolution and Human Behavior, 2001, 22:417429.Google Scholar
169.Gangestad, Thornhill, and Yeo, , “Facial Attractiveness, Developmental Stability, and Fluctuating Asymmetry.”Google Scholar
170.Stone, Peter, personal communication.Google Scholar
171.Thaler, , The Winner's Curse.Google Scholar
172.Thaler, , “Anomalies: The Winner's Curse.”Google Scholar
173.Camerer, , Behavioral Game Theory.Google Scholar
174.Bendor, Jonathan, “Herbert Simon: Political Scientist,” Annual Review of Political Science, 2003, 6:437, 462.Google Scholar
175.Gigerenzer, Gerd, Adaptive Thinking: Rationality in the Real World (New York: Oxford University Press, 2000), chapter 8.Google Scholar
176.Pinker, , The Blank Slate, p. 302.Google Scholar
177.Gigerenzer, Adaptive Thinking, p. 168.Google Scholar
178.Bendor, Jonathan, “Herbert Simon: Political Scientist.”Google Scholar
179.Tooby, John and Cosmides, Leda, “The Psychological Foundations of Culture,” in The Adapted Mind.Google Scholar
180.Gigerenzer, , Adaptive Thinking, chapters 4, 12.Google Scholar
181.Cosmides, and Tooby, , “Better than Rational: Evolutionary Psychology and the Invisible Hand,” 1994, p. 330331.Google Scholar
182.Kahneman, D. and Tversky, A., “On the reality of cognitive illusions: a reply to Gigerenzer's critique,” Psychological Review, 1996, 103:582591.Google Scholar
183.Johnson, , “How Conceptual Problems Migrate.”Google Scholar
184.McKelvey, R. and Palfrey, T., “Quantal Response Equilibria for Normal Form Games,” Games and Economic Behavior, 1995, 10(1):638.Google Scholar
185.Camerer, C., Ho, T-H, and Chong, J-K, “A Cognitive Hierarchy Model of One-Shot Games,” Quarterly journal of Economics, 2004, 119(3):861898.Google Scholar
186.Fudenberg, Drew and Kreps, David. M., “Learning in Extensive-Form Games I: Self-Confirming Equilibrium,” Games and Economic Behavior, 8:2055.Google Scholar
187.Tingley, Dustin, “Believe what you want: the practice and possibilities of self-confirming equilibrium,” paper presented at the 2005 meeting of the Annual Political Science Association, Washington D.C.Google Scholar
188.Schelling, Thomas, The Strategy of Conflict (New York: Oxford University Press, 1963).Google Scholar
189.Johnson, , “Symbol and Strategy in Comparative Political Analysis.”Google Scholar
190.Janssen, Maarten, “Focal Points,” in New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law, Newman, P., ed. (London: MacMillan, 1998).Google Scholar
191.Schiemann, John, “Meeting Halfway between Rochester and Frankfurt: Generative Salience, Focal Points, and Strategic Interaction,” American Journal of Political Science, 2000, 44(1):116.Google Scholar
192.Wedeen, , “Conceptualizing Culture,” p. 719.Google Scholar
193.Ibid., p. 718.Google Scholar
194.Ibid., p. 714.Google Scholar
195.Schiemann, , “Meeting Halfway between Rochester and Frankfurt,” p. 10.Google Scholar
196.Thornhill, Randy, “Darwinian Aesthetics,” in Crawford, Charles and Krebs, Dennis, eds., Handbook of Evolutionary Psychology (London: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, 1998).Google Scholar
197.Thornhill, Randy, “Darwinian Aesthetics Informs Traditional Aesthetics,” in Darwinian Aesthetics, Grammer, K. and Voland, E., eds. (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2002).Google Scholar
198.Saad, , “Evolution and Political Marketing.”Google Scholar
199.Frank, , Passions Within Reason, chapter 6.Google Scholar
200.Schiemann, , “Meeting Halfway between Rochester and Frankfurt,” p. 12.Google Scholar
201.Johnson, , “Symbol and Strategy in Comparative Political Analysis.”Google Scholar
202.Johnson, , “How Conceptual Problems Migrate.”Google Scholar
203.Tingley, Dustin, “What types of data does a Darwinian political scientist need?” paper presented at the 2004 Annual Meeting of the Association for Politics and the Life Sciences, 2–5 September 2004, Chicago, IL.Google Scholar
204.Sowell, , A Conflict of Visions.Google Scholar
205.Tingley, , “Facial Discrimination.”Google Scholar
206.Peterson, Somit, “Rational Choice and Biopolitics.”Google Scholar
207.Hibbing, John and Alford, John, “Accepting Authoritative Decisions: Humans as Wary Cooperators,” American Journal of Political Science, 2003, 48(1): 6276.Google Scholar
208.McDermott, Rose, “The Feeling of Rationality.”Google Scholar