Hostname: page-component-7479d7b7d-k7p5g Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-13T19:02:41.887Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Fitness extraction and the conceptual foundations of political biology

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 May 2016

Mircea Boari*
Affiliation:
FreeTh&Ent Group 1–3, M. Kogălniceanu Bd, C. P. 62-44, 053-080 Bucharest Romania and ESSEC Business School Avenue Bernard Hirsch, B.P. 105 95021 Cergy-Pontoise Cedex France mirceab@tag.starnets.ro
Get access

Abstract

In well known formulations, political science, classical and neoclassical economics, and political economy have recognized as foundational a human impulse toward self-preservation. To employ this concept, modern social-sciences theorists have made simplifying assumptions about human nature and have then built elaborately upon their more incisive simplifications. Advances in biology, including advances in evolutionary theory, notably inclusive-fitness theory, have for decades now encouraged the reconsideration of such assumptions and, more ambitiously, the reconciliation of the social and life sciences. I ask if this reconciliation is feasible and test a path to the unification of politics and biology, called here “political biology.” Two new notions, “fitness extraction” and “fitness exchange,” are defined, then differentiated from each other, and lastly contrasted to cooperative gaming, the putative essential element of economics.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Association for Politics and the Life Sciences 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1. Boari, Mircea, “Ethnic Power,” Polis, 2000, 1:114154.Google Scholar
2. Wilson, E. O., Sociobiology: The New Synthesis (Belknap Press, 2000), p. 45, 314–315, 379–382.Google Scholar
3. Hobbes, Thomas, Leviathan (Cambridge University Press, 1996 [1651]), I, XIV, [64], 1, p. 91; I, XV, [73], 5, 103; I, XVI, [79], 36, p. 110; II, XVII, [85], 1, p. 117; II, XXVII, [157], 25, p. 208; II, XXVIII, [161/162], 2, p. 214; II, XXX, [175], 1, p. 231.Google Scholar
4. Locke, John, Two Treatises of Government (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1960 [1690]): I, IX, ∫ 86, 20, p. 205; I, IX, ∫ 87, 5, p. 206; II, V, ∫ 25, 1, p. 285.Google Scholar
5. Smith, Adam, The Theory of Moral Sentiments (Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 1984 [1759]), II.i.5.10, p. 77; II.ii.2.1, p. 82; VI.ii.1.1, p. 219; VII.i.4, p. 266; VII.ii.1.15–16.Google Scholar
6. Smith, Adam, An Inquiry Into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, (Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 1981 [1776]):, IV.ix.28, p. 674.Google Scholar
7. Strauss, Leo, Natural Right and History (University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 1963), pp. 165252.Google Scholar
8. Hobbes, , p. 14, 15, 19, 24, 46, 59, 85, 227, 472–473.Google Scholar
9. Hobbes, , I, XV, [79–80], pp. 110111; II, XVII, [85–88], pp. 117–121.Google Scholar
10. Locke, , II, V, ∫ 34, 5, P. 291; II, VI, ∫ 57, 1 ff “the law of reason,” p. 305 ff; II, IX, ∫ 124, 5, p. 351.Google Scholar
11. Hume, David, Treatise of Human Nature (Buffalo, New York: Prometheus Books, 1737/1992), III, ∫ VII, pp. 534539.Google Scholar
12. Smith, , Theory of Moral Sentiments, p. 272.Google Scholar
13. Boari, Mircea, “Capitalism: Foundations of Ethical Behavior” in Vranceanu, R. and Daianu, D., eds., Ethical Boundaries of Capitalism (Ashagate, 2005), pp. 106126, esp. pp. 111–114.Google Scholar
14. Hobbes, , I, VIII, [35], p. 53; I, XI, [47], p. 70.Google Scholar
15. Aristotle, Politica , in The Works of Aristotle (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1921), X 1257a151257b40; 1269b12–1270a15; 1295b17, 1300a7, 1310a22; 1253b25; 1257a6–34; 1258a1–13; 1263b20–28; 1266b25–30; 1267b, 3–5; 1257a 5–10; 1257a 9.Google Scholar
16. Smith, , Theory of Moral Sentiments, p. 272.Google Scholar
17. Alexander, R. D., The Biology of Moral Systems (New York: Aldine de Gruyter, 1987), pp. 4042.Google Scholar
18. Hamilton, W. D., “The Evolution of Altruistic Behavior,” The American Naturalist, 1963, 97:354–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
19. Hamilton, W. D., “The Genetical Evolution of Social Behavior I and II,” journal of Theoretical Biology, 1964, 7:1–16, 1732.Google Scholar
20. Trivers, R., “Parent-Offspring Conflict”, American Zoologist, 1974, 14:249264.Google Scholar
21. Buss, D., “Sexual Strategies Theory: An Evolutionary Perspective on Human Mating,” Psychological Review, 1993, 100(2):204232.Google Scholar
22. Buss, D., The Evolution of Desire: Strategies of Human Mating (New York: Basic Books, 1994).Google Scholar
23. Aristotle, Politica, I, cc 313, “Household Economy; Slaves; Property; Children and Wives.” Google Scholar
24. Locke, , II, VI, “Of Paternal Power”, pp. 308313.Google Scholar
25. Platon, , Republica, Editura Stiintifica si Enciclopedica, Bucuresti, 1986, IV 2 544cIV.5 576b.Google Scholar
26. Aristotle, Politica, III, cc 6–13, 1278b1284b.Google Scholar
27. Aristotle, Ethica Nicomachea , in The Works of Aristotle (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1915), IX, 10, 1180b–1181a, 1180a20–25.Google Scholar
28. Hobbes, , XIX, pp. 9599, 129–135.Google Scholar
29. Locke, , X, ∫ 132–133, pp. 354355.Google Scholar
30. Montesquieu, , The Spirit of the Laws (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989 [1784]), I, 3, pp. 230.Google Scholar
31. Boari, Mircea, The End of History and Fin de Siècle Politics: The Political Theory of Posthistory, Ph.D. Thesis, University of Hawaii, 1998.Google Scholar