Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-9pm4c Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-27T05:13:43.960Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Globalization, Superstars, and Reputation: Theory & Evidence from the Wine Industry*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  08 June 2012

Michael Gibbs
Affiliation:
University of Chicago Booth School of Business, Chicago, IL 60637 and Center for the Study of Labor (IZA), Bonn,Germany, email: michael.gibbs@chicagobooth.edu
Mikel Tapia
Affiliation:
Universidad Carlos III de Madrid, Department of Business Administration, C/ Madrid, 126–28903 Getafe (Madrid)Spain, email: mtapia@emp.uc3m.es
Frederic Warzynski
Affiliation:
Aarhus School of Business, Aarhus University, Department of Economics, Fuglesangs Allé 4, 8230 Aarhus,Denmark, email: fwa@asb.dk

Abstract

We develop a simple model of the effects of reputation on prices. An increasing fraction of consumers who are “naive” (less informed about quality) results in a stronger sensitivity of prices to ratings of quality. We then argue that this may be a factor in price dynamics for goods that become more widely traded as a result of globalization. We then provide some empirical analysis of these ideas using data on prices and Robert Parker's ratings of wines. Wine prices are strongly related to ratings, and even more so for higher quality wine categories. In addition, changes in Parker ratings for the same wine result in large price changes. Price elasticities with respect to ratings have risen dramatically since 1993. One plausible explanation for this is the growing globalization of the fine wine market, which increases the prevalence of naive wine consumers. (JEL Classification: D8, F1, L1, Q1)

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © American Association of Wine Economists 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Becker, G. and Murphy, K. (1988). A theory of rational addiction. Journal of Political Economy, 96, 675700.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cabral, L. (2005). The economics of trust and reputation: a primer. Unpublished manuscript, New York University.Google Scholar
Crozet, M., Head, K. and Mayer, T. (2009). Quality sorting and trade: firm-level evidence for French wine. Working Paper, University of Reims.Google Scholar
Hadj Ali, H., Lecocq, S. and Visser, M. (2008). The impact of gurus: Parker grades and en primeur wine prices. Economic Journal, 118, F158–F174.Google Scholar
Parker, R. (various years). Website available at: http://www.eRobertParker.com.Google Scholar
Roberts, P. and Reagans, R. (2007). Critical exposure and price-quality relationships for new world wines in the U.S. market. Journal of Wine Economics, 1(2), 8497.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosen, S. (1981). The economics of superstars. American Economic Review, 71(5), 845858.Google Scholar
Schumacher, H. (2009). Reputation and competition in a market for differentiated products. Working Paper, Goethe-University Frankfurt.Google Scholar
Shapiro, C. (1983). Premiums for high quality products as returns to reputations. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98(4), 659679.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tapia, M. and Warzynski, F. (2006). The dynamics of price and performance and the role of reputation: an empirical study of French and Spanish wines. Working Paper, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid, Madrid, Spain.Google Scholar