Hostname: page-component-84b7d79bbc-rnpqb Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-26T09:27:29.890Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Strike costs and public policy*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 November 2008

Peter Enderwick
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, The Queen's University of Belfast

Abstract

Strike costs provide incentives for bargaining parties to seek agreement by effective negotiation. To perform this role efficiently both the magnitude and distribution of such costs are crucial. Despite the apparently low aggregate costs of strikes the extreme concentration of stoppages indicates that costs may be sufficient. The burden of such costs appears inefficient in certain situations. In such cases government intervention may be required. Impending legislative changes in Britain contribute little to strike containment and are likely to manifest their effect in bargaining outcomes as opposed to the bargaining process. Increases in the strike costs suffered by one side in wage negotiations serve only to increase the relative bargaining power of the other side. Reductions in state subsidies to the strike costs suffered by labour appear more effective as a device for controlling wage growth than strike activity. A poor level of understanding of the strike process makes this an area where public policy must incorporate gradualism and pragmatism.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1982

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Baldamus, W. (1961) Efficiency and Effort. London: Tavistock.Google Scholar
Batstone, E., Boraston, I. and Frenkel, S. (1978) The Social Organisation of Strikes. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Bernstein, I., Enarson, H. L. and Fleming, R. W. (1966) Emergency Disputes and National Policy. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Brittan, S. (1976) The political economy of British union monopoly, Three Banks Review, 111, 332.Google Scholar
Brown, W. (ed.) (1981) The Changing Contours of British Industrial Relations. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Burton, J. (1978) Are trade unions a public good/‘bad’?: the economics of the closed shop. In Robbins, L. (ed.), Trade Unions: Public Goods or Public ‘Bads’? London: Institute of Economic Affairs.Google Scholar
Burton, J. (1980) Trade unions' role in the British disease: an interest in inflation? In Seldon, A. (ed.), Is Monetarism Enough? London: Institute of Economic Affairs.Google Scholar
Caves, R. E. (1980) Productivity differences among industries. In Caves, R. E. and Krause, L. B. (eds.), Britain's Economic Performance. Washington D.C.: The Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Chamberlain, N. W. and Schilling, J. M. (1954) The Impact of Strikes: Their Social and Economic Costs. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Chermesh, R. (1979) Strikes: the issue of social responsibility, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 17, 337–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clack, C. (1967) How unofficial strikes help industry, Business, 07, 42–7.Google Scholar
Cmnd 3623 (1968) Royal Commission on Trade Unions and Employers Associations, 1965–68, Report (Donovan Report). London: HMSO.Google Scholar
Cmnd 8128 (1981) Trade Union Immunities. London: HMSO.Google Scholar
Cole, W. J. (1975) The financing of the individual striker: a case study in the building industry, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 13, 94–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Creigh, S. W., Donaldson, N. and Hawthorne, E. (1980) Stoppage activity in OECD countries, Department of Employment Gazette, 88, 1174–81.Google Scholar
Creigh, S. W. and Makeham, P. (1980) Variations in strike activity within UK manufacturing industry, Industrial Relations Journal, 11, 32–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Nisi, A. and Dworkin, J. B. (1981) Final-offer arbitration and the naive negotiator, Industrial and Labour Relations Review, 35, 7887.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Department of Employment (1982a) The new Employment Bill, Department of Employment Gazette, 61–3.Google Scholar
Department of Employment (1982b) Stoppages caused by industrial disputes in 1981, Department of Employment Gazette, 289–95.Google Scholar
Eaton, B. C. (1972) The worker and the profitability of the strike, Industrial and Labour Relations Review, 26, 670–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edwards, P. K. (1980) Size of plant and strike-proneness, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 42, 145–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edwards, P. K. (1981) Strikes in the United States 1881–1974. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Edwards, P. K. (1981) The strike-proneness of British manufacturing establishments, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 19, 135–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Enderwick, P. (1982) Collective bargaining and strikes: an exit-voice analysis, International Journal of Manpower, 3.Google Scholar
Enderwick, P. and Buckley, P. J. (1982) The determinants of strike activity in foreign-owned plants: evidence from British manufacturing industry 1971–1973. Mimeographed.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farber, H. S. (1980a) Does final-offer arbitration encourage bargaining? Industrial Relations Research Association, 33rd meeting.Google Scholar
Farber, H. S. (1980b) An analysis of final-offer arbitration, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 24, 683705.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farber, H. S. (1981) Splitting the difference in interest arbitration, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 35, 70–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geare, A. J. (1978) Final-offer arbitration: a critical examination of the theory, Journal of Industrial Relations, 20, 373–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gennard, J. (1981) The effects of strike activity on households, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 19, 327–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gennard, J. and Lasko, R. (1975) The individual and the strike, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 13, 346–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ghali, M. A. (1973) On measuring ‘third party’ effects of a strike, Western Economic Journal, 11, 214–27.Google Scholar
Hameed, S. M. A. and Lomas, T. (1975) Measurement of production losses due to strikes in Canada: an input-output analysis, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 13, 8693.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hicks, J. R. (1932) The Theory of Wages. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Hildebrand, G. H. (1966) An economie definition of the national emergency dispute. In Bernstein, I., Enarson, H. L. and Fleming, R. W. (eds.), Emergency Disputes and National Policy. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Hudson, R. (1981) The effects of dock strikes on UK international trade, Applied Economics, 13, 6777.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hunter, L. C. (1977) Economic issues in conciliation and arbitration, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 15, 226–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hyman, R. (1972) Strikes. London: Fontana.Google Scholar
Hyman, R. (1975) Industrial Relations: A Marxist Introduction. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jackson, M. P. (1977) Industrial Relations. London: Croom Helm.Google Scholar
Kennan, J. (1980) Pareto optimality and the economics of strike duration, Journal of Labour Research, 1, 7795.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laidler, D. E. W. and Parkin, J. M., (1975) Inflation - a Survey, Economic Journal, 85, 741809.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marceau, L. and Musgrave, R. A. (1949) Strikes in essential industries: a way out, Harvard Business Review, 27, 286–92.Google Scholar
Mayhew, K. (1979) Economists and strikes, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 41, 119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCalmont, D. B. (1962) The semi-strike, Industrial and Labour Relations Review, 15, 191208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meade, J. E. (1982) Stagflation Vol. 1: Wage Fixing. London: George Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Ministry of Labour (1960) Ministry of Labour Gazette, 68, 184.Google Scholar
Palomba, N. A. and Palomba, G. A. (1974) The economic costs of strikes: a suggested measure, Mississippi Valley Journal of Business and Economics, 10, 1223.Google Scholar
Prais, S. J. (1981) Productivity and Industrial Structure. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Purdy, D. L. and Zis, G. (1973) Trade unions and wage inflation in the UK: a reappraisal. In Parkin, J. M. and Nobay, A. R. (eds.) Essays in Modern Economics. London: Longman.Google Scholar
Reder, M. W. and Neumann, G. R. (1980) Conflict and Contract: the case of strikes, Journal of Political Economy, 88, 867–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ross, A. M. and Hartman, P. T. (1960) Changing Patterns of Industrial Conflict. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Rowley, C. K. (1979) Buying out the obstructors? In S. C. Littlechild et al., The Taming of Government. London: Institute of Economic Affairs.Google Scholar
Shorey, J. (1976) An inter-industry analysis of strike frequency, Economica, 43, 349–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Siebert, W. S. and Addison, J. T. (1981) Are strikes accidental?, Economie Journal, 91, 389404.Google Scholar
Smith, C. T. B., Clifton, R., Makeham, P., Creigh, S. W. and Burn, R. V. (1978) Strikes in Britain. London: HMSO.Google Scholar
Stevens, C. M. (1966) Is compulsory arbitration compatible with bargaining?, Industrial Relations, 5, 3851.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stieber, J. (1968) Unauthorised strikes under the American and British industrial relations systems, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 6, 232–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swidinsky, R. (1982) Bargaining power under compulsory unionism, Industrial Relations, 21, 6272.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Turkington, D. J. (1976) The Economic Effects of Industrial Conflict. Wellington N.Z.: Victoria University of Wellington, Occasional Papers in Industrial Relations, No. 19.Google Scholar
Turner, H. A. (1969) Is Britain Really Strike-Prone? A Review of the Incidence, Character and Costs of Industrial Conflict. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Turner, H. A., Clack, G. and Roberts, B. (1967) Labour Relations in the Motor Industry. London: Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Webb, N. (ed.) (1981) The Gallup Report, London: Sphere Books.Google Scholar
Wheeler, H. N. (1975) Compulsory arbitration: a ‘narcotic’ effect? Industrial Relations, 14, 117–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whittington, T. G. and Towers, B. (1971) Strikes and the economy, National Westminster Bank Quarterly Review, November, 3342.Google Scholar