Hostname: page-component-5c6d5d7d68-lvtdw Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-08-16T15:04:28.342Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Public entrepreneurship and the economics of reform

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2007

JAN SCHNELLENBACH*
Affiliation:
Ruprecht-Karls-University, Heidelberg, Alfred-Weber Institute for Economics. Email: jan.schnellenbach@awi-uni-heidelberg.de.

Abstract:

Public entrepreneurship is commonly understood as the outcome of the activities of a Schumpeterian political innovator. However, empirical research suggests that changes to a more efficient economic policy, even if it is known and technically easy to implement, are usually delayed. This is difficult to reconcile with Schumpeterian notions of public entrepreneurship. In this paper, it is argued that the attempt to transfer a Schumpeterian approach to the public sector is fundamentally flawed. Institutional checks and balances that characterize most modern liberal democracies make the strategy of bold leadership an unlikely choice for an incumbent. If change occurs, it occurs normally as a response to the fact that the status quo has become untenable. From a normative point of view, it is argued that if public entrepreneurship nevertheless occurs, it will often be associated with unwanted consequences. A dismantling of formal institutional checks and balances is therefore not reasonable.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The JOIE Foundation 2007

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alesina, Alberto and Alan, Drazen 1991, ‘Why Are Stabilizations Delayed?’, American Economic Review, 81: 11701188.Google Scholar
Banerjee, Abhijit 1993, ‘The Economics of Rumors’, Review of Economic Studies, 60: 309327.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, Timothy and Case, Anne C. 1995, ‘Incumbent Behaviour, Vote-Seeking, Tax-Setting and Yardstick Competition’, American Economic Review, 84: 394414.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M. and Gordon, Tullock 1962, The Calculus of Consent, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Carter, Ralph G., Scott, James M., and Rowling, Charles M. 2004, ‘Setting a Course: Congressional Foreign Policy Entrepreneurs in Post World War II US Foreign Policy’, International Studies Perspectives, 5: 278299.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coughlin, Peter J. 1992, Probabilistic Voting Theory, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Denzau, Arthur T. and North, Douglass C. 1994, ‘Shared Mental Models: Ideologies and Institutions’, Kyklos, 47: 331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dopfer, Kurt 1991, ‘Toward a Theory of Economic Institutions: Synergy and Path Dependency’, Journal of Economic Issues, 25: 535550.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dopfer, Kurt 2001, ‘Evolutionary Economics: Framework for Analysis’, in Dopfer, Kurt (ed.), Evolutionary Economics: Program and Scope, Boston: Kluwer, pp. 144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dosi, Giovanni, Luigi, Marengo, Andrea, Bassanini, and Marco, Valente 1999, ‘Norms as Emergent Properties of Adaptive Learning: The Case of Economic Routines’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 9: 526.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drazen, Alan 1996, ‘The Political Economy of Delayed Reform’, Policy Reform, 1: 2546.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heine, Klaus 2003, Regulierungswettbewerb im Gesellschaftsrecht, Berlin: Duncker & Humblot.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heiniger, Yves, Thomas, Straubhaar, Hans, Rentsch, Stefan, Flückiger, and Thomas, Held 2004a, Ökonomik der Reform: Wege zu mehr Wachstum in Deuschland, Zürich: Orell Füssli.Google Scholar
Heiniger, Yves, Thomas, Straubhaar, Hans, Rentsch, Stefan, Flückiger, and Thomas, Held 2004b, Ökonomik der Reform: Wege zu mehr Wachstum in der Schweiz, Zürich: Orell Füssli.Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. 1997, ‘The Ubiquity of Habits and Rules’, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 21: 663684.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kamarck, Elaine 2004, Government Innovation around the World, Kennedy School of Government Working Paper RWP 04010, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University.Google Scholar
Kerber, Wolfgang 2004, ‘Evolutorische Ökonomik und Wirtschaftspolitik: Probleme und Perspektiven am Beispiel des Wettbewerbsföderalismus’, in Kurt, Dopfer (ed.), Studien zur Evolutorischen Ökonomik VIII. Evolutorische Wirtschaftspolitik – Grundlagen und Anwendungsmodelle, Berlin: Duncker & Humblot, pp. 6797.Google Scholar
Kingdon, John W. 1995, Agendas, Alternatives and Public Policies, New York: Harper Collins.Google Scholar
Kirchgässner, Gebhard 1992, ‘Towards a Theory of Low Cost Decisions’, European Journal of Political Economy, 8: 305320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirzner, Israel M. 2000, The Driving Force of the Market. Essays in Austrian Economics, London and New York: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuran, Timur 1987, ‘Preference Falsification, Policy Continuity and Collective Conservativism’, Economic Journal, 97: 642665.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Langlois, Richard N. 1998, ‘Personal Capitalism as Charismatic Authority: The Organizational Economics of a Weberian Concept’, Industrial and Corporate Change, 7: 195214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loury, Glenn C. 1994, ‘Self-Censorship in Public Discourse’, Rationality and Society, 6: 428461.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
March, James G. and Olsen, Johan P. 1989, Rediscovering Institutions: The Organizational Basis of Politics, New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Matsusaka, John G. 2004, For the Many or the Few: The Initiative Process, Public Policy and American Democracy, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meier, Alfred and Christof, Haudenschild 1991, Der wirtschaftspolitische Problemlösungsprozess, Chur: Rüegger.Google Scholar
Meier, Alfred and Tilman, Slembeck 1997, Wirtschaftspolitik. Ein kognitiv-evolutionärer Ansatz, 2nd revised edition, Munich: Oldenbourg.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mintrom, Michael 1997, ‘Policy Entrepreneurs and the Diffusion of Innovation’, American Journal of Political Science, 41: 738770.Google Scholar
Mintrom, Michael 2000, Policy Entrepreneurs and School Choice, Washington, DC: Georgetown University Press.Google Scholar
Mintrom, Michael and Sandra, Vergari 1998, ‘Policy Networks and Innovation Diffusion: The Case of State Education Reforms’, Journal of Politics, 60: 126148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mueller, Dennis C. 2003, Public Choice III, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oates, Wallace E. 1999, ‘An Essay on Fiscal Federalism’, Journal of Economic Literature, 37: 11201149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor 1990, Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 2003, Law, Pragmatism and Democracy, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Potts, Jason 2003, ‘Toward an Evolutionary Theory of Homo Oeconomicus: The Concept of Universal Nomadism’, in John, Laurent (ed.), Evolutionary Economics and Human Nature, Cheltenham: Elgar.Google Scholar
Rodrik, Dani 1996, ‘Understanding Economic Policy Reform’, Journal of Economic Literature, 34: 941.Google Scholar
Savage, Robert L. 1985,’Diffusion Research Traditions and the Spread of Policy Innovations in a Federal System’, Publius, 15: 127.Google Scholar
Schneider, Mark, Paul, Teske, and Michael, Mintrom 1995, Public Entrepreneurs: Agents for Change in American Government, Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schnellenbach, Jan 2004a, Dezentrale Finanzpolitik und Modellunsicherheit, Tübingen: Mohr.Google Scholar
Schnellenbach, Jan 2004b, Learning from Decentralised Policy: The Demand Side, presented at the Royal Economic Society 2004 annual conference in Swansea (Wales).Google Scholar
Schnellenbach, Jan 2005a, ‘The Dahrendorf Hypothesis and Its Implications for (the Theory of) Economic Policy’, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 29: 9971009.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schnellenbach, Jan 2005b, ‘Model Uncertainty and the Rationality of Economic Policy: An Evolutionary Approach’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 15: 101116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schnellenbach, Jan 2006, ‘Gradualism and Public Entrepreneurship in the Change of Formal Institutions’, in Christian, Schubert and Georg von, Wangenheim (eds), Evolution and Design of Institutions, London: Routledge, pp. 123146.Google Scholar
Scitovsky, Tibor 1976, The Joyless Economy, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1911, Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung, Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1942/1950, Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, New York: Harper & Brothers.Google Scholar
Tsebelis, George 2002, Veto Players: How Political Institutions Work, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Walker, Jack L. 1969, ‘The Diffusion of Innovation Among the American States’, American Political Science Review, 63: 880899.Google Scholar
Witt, Ulrich 1989, ‘The Evolution of Economic Institutions as a Propagation Process’, Public Choice, 62: 155172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Witt, Ulrich 1998, ‘Imagination and Leadership: The Neglected Dimension of an Evolutionary Theory of the Firm’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 35: 161177.Google Scholar
Witt, Ulrich 2003, ‘Economic Policy Making in Evolutionary Perspective’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 13: 7794.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wohlgemuth, Michael 2000, ‘Political Entrepreneurship and Bidding for Political Monopoly’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 10: 273295.Google Scholar
Wohlgemuth, Michael 2002, ‘Evolutionary Approaches to Politics’, Kyklos, 55: 223246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar