Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-25wd4 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-26T04:43:54.849Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

L'ATTIVITÀ LEGISLATIVA DEL PARLAMENTO ITALIANO: CONSOCIATIVISMO? POLARIZZAZIONE?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 July 2018

Introduzione

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

Pochi termini politologici hanno avuto altrettanto successo nella polemica politica italiana della parola consociativismo. Nonostante la sua origine specialistica, che non rimanda a nessuna nozione giuridica né ad alcuna dottrina politica o sociale, è difficile assistere ad un dibattito politico senza che qualcuno dei partecipanti non lanci alla parte avversa l'accusa di essere consociativo. Strano destino. Il successo ha un prezzo per gli uomini come per i concetti: coniato da Lijphart (1968) per rendere conto dell'esistenza di democrazie stabili e relativamente felici, che la scienza politica degli anni '50 (Almond 1956) ignorava e per le quali al tempo stesso prevedeva un tribolato avvenire, il termine consociativismo ha assunto nel nostro paese una connotazione quasi esclusivamente negativa. Consociativa è la spartizione partitica, la corruzione, l'immobilismo, la mancanza di rigore finanziario. In breve, consociativa pare essere stata tutta la Prima Repubblica e consociativi tutti i guai da essa prodotti.

Summary

Summary

The article explores the problem of the «consociational» nature of Italian democracy during the First Republic. The Author focuses on the oversized legislative coalitions that supported «particularistic» bills during this period. Two alternative approaches to explain the pattern of behavior in the Italian Parliament are discussed. The first approach emphasizes the polarized nature of Italian politics and denies the existence of real «consociationalism» in Italy. Large legislative coalitions would have passed only residual and minor laws since the main Italian parties were mutually mistrustful to agree on big issues. In contrast, the second approach explains the bulk of legislative behavior as «consociational», that is, a consistent pattern of party consensus on distributive and particularistic policies. An interpretation of law-making in the Italian Parliament is advanced, using rational choice models. The Author suggests that a nested games – approach can illuminate how rules work and help to understand the effects of institutional changes in the law-making process.

Type
Ricerche
Copyright
Copyright © Societ Italiana di Scienza Politica 

References

Riferimenti bibliografici

Almond, G.A. (1956), Comparative Political Systems, in «Journal of Politics», vol. 18, pp. 391409.Google Scholar
Alt, J.E., Putnam, R.D. e Shepsle, K.A. (1988), The Architecture of Linkage, mimeo.Google Scholar
Alt, J.E. e Eichengreen, B. (1989), Parallel and Overlapping Games: Theory and an Application to the European Gas Trade, in «Economics and Politics», 2, pp. 119144.Google Scholar
Arrow, K.J. (1951, 1963), Social Choice and Individual Values, New York-New Haven, Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Black, D. (1958), The Theory of Committees and Elections, London, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Brady, D.W. (1988), Critical Elections and Congressional Policy Making, Stanford, Stanford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caciagli, M., Cazzola, F., Morlino, L. e Passigli, S. (a cura di) (1994), L'Italia fra crisi e transizione, Roma-Bari, Laterza.Google Scholar
Cain, B., Ferejohn, J. e Fiorina, M. (1987), The Personal Vote: Constituency Service and Electoral Independence, Cambridge (Mass.), Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Cavazza, F.L. e Graubard, S.R. (1974), Il caso italiano, Milano, Garzanti.Google Scholar
Cazzola, F. (1972), Consenso e opposizione nel parlamento italiano. Il ruolo del PCI dalla I alla IV legislatura, in «Rivista Italiana di Scienza Politica», vol. 2, pp. 171196.Google Scholar
Chubb, J.E. e Peterson, P.E. (a cura di) (1989), Can the Government Govern?, Washington D.C., The Brookings Institutions.Google Scholar
Copeland, G. e Patterson, S. (a cura di) (1994), Parlaments in the Modern World. Changing Institutions, Ann Arbor, The University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Cotta, M. (1994a), Il governo di partito in Italia, in Caciagli, Cazzola, Morlino e Passigli, pp. 119139.Google Scholar
Western, B. (1994b), The Rise and Fall of the Centrality of the Italian Parliament. Transformation of Executive-legislative Subsystem after the Second World War, in Copeland e Patterson, pp. 5984.Google Scholar
Western, B. (1996), La crisi del governo di partito all'italiana, in Cotta e Isernia, pp. 1152.Google Scholar
Cotta, M. e Isernia, P. (a cura di) (1996), Il gigante dai piedi di argilla. La crisi del regime partitocratico in Italia, Bologna, Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Cox, G.W e McCubbins, M.D. (1993), Legislative Leviathan. Party Government in the House, Berkeley, University of California Press.Google Scholar
Crecine, J.P. (a cura di) (1981), Research in Public Policy Analysis and Management, Greenwich, Jai Press.Google Scholar
De Micheli, C. (1994), Crisi del Policentrismo? Alcuni aspetti del funzionamento del parlamento italiano dal 1983 al 1992, Relazione presentata al convegno annuale SISP.Google Scholar
Western, B. (1997), L'attività legislativa dei governi al tramonto della prima repubblica, in «Rivista Italiana di Scienza Politica», vol. 27, pp. 149187.Google Scholar
Denzau, A., Riker, W. e Shepsle, K. (1985), Farquharson and Fenno: Sophisticated Voting and Home Style, in «American Political Science Review», vol. 79, pp. 11171135.Google Scholar
Di Palma, G. (1978), Sopravvivere senza governare. I partiti nel Parlamento italiano, Bologna, Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Di Palma, G. (1987), Parlamento-arena o parlamento di trasformazione?, in «Rivista Italiana di Scienza Politica», vol. 17, pp. 179202.Google Scholar
Fabbrini, S. (1994), Quale democrazia. L'Italia e gli altri, Bari, Laterza. Fiorina, M. (1981), Universalism, Reciprocity, and Distributive Policymaking in Majority Rule Institutions, in Crecine, pp. 197221.Google Scholar
Di Palma, G. (1987), Alternative Rationales for Restrictive Procedures, in «Journal of Law, Economics, and Organizations 3, pp. 337343.Google Scholar
Giuliani, M. (1995), Le politiche pubbliche fra sistemi di partito e policy networks, in Regonini, G. (a cura di), Politiche pubbliche e democrazia, Napoli, Esi, pp. 219240.Google Scholar
Giuliani, M. (1996), Measures of Consensual Law-making: the Italian «Consociativismo», Quaderno di Ricerca Poleis, n. 12.Google Scholar
Krehbiel, K. (1987), Sophisticated Committees and Structure Induced Equilibria in Congress, in McCubbins e Sullivan, pp. 376402.Google Scholar
Giuliani, M. (1988), Spatial Models of Legislative Choice, in «Legislative Studies Quaterly», vol. 13, pp. 259321.Google Scholar
Giuliani, M. (1991), Information and Legislative Organization, Ann Arbor, The University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Giuliani, M. (1993), Where's the Party? in «British Journal of Political Science», vol. 23, pp. 235266.Google Scholar
Lijphart, A. (1968), Typologies of Democratic Systems, in «Comparative Political Studies», vol. 1, pp. 344.Google Scholar
Lijphart, A. (1984), Democracies. Patterns of Majoritarian and Consensus Government in Twenty-One Countries, New Haven, Yale University Press; trad. it. Le Democrazie Contemporanee, Bologna, Il Mulino, 1988.Google Scholar
Mayhew, D. (1974), Congress: The Electoral Connection, New Haven, Yale University Press.Google Scholar
McCubbins, M. e Sullivan, T. (a cura di) (1987), Congress: Structure and Policy, Cambridge-New York, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
McKelvey, R. (1976), Intransitivities in Multidimensional Voting Models with Some Implications for Agenda Control, in «Journal of Economic Theory», vol. 12, pp. 472482.Google Scholar
Morisi, M. (1992), Le leggi del consenso. Partiti e interessi nei primi parlamenti della Repubblica, Soveria Mannelli, Rubbettino.Google Scholar
Oleszek, W. (1989), Congressional Procedure and the Policy Process, Washington, Congressional Quarterly (3a ed.).Google Scholar
Pappalardo, A. (1979), Le condizioni della democrazia consociativa. Una critica logica ed empirica, in «Rivista Italiana di Scienza Politica», vol. 9, pp. 367446.Google Scholar
Pizzorno, A. (1993), Le difficoltà del consociativismo, in A. Pizzorno, Le radici della politica assoluta, Milano, pp. 285313.Google Scholar
Plott, C.R. (1967), The Notion of Equilibrium and its Possibility under Majority Rule, in «American Economic Review», vol. 57, pp. 787806.Google Scholar
Regonini, G. (1994), Partiti, reti, giochi, politiche pubbliche, in Caciagli, Cazzola, Morlino e Passigli, pp. 163189.Google Scholar
Lijphart, A. (1996), Partiti e pensioni: legami mancanti, in Cotta e Isernia, pp. 73137.Google Scholar
Riker, W.H. (1962), The Theory of Political Coalitions, New Haven, Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Rohde, D.W. e Shepsle, K.A. (1973), Democratic Committee Assignments in the House of Representatives: Strategic Aspects of a Social Choice Process, in «American Political Science Review», vol. 67, pp. 889905.Google Scholar
Sartori, G. (1963), Dove va il Parlamento in Italia, in Somogy, Lotti, Predieri e Sartori, pp. 281386.Google Scholar
Sartori, G. (1974), Rivisitando il pluralismo polarizzato, in Cavazza e Graubard, pp. 296323.Google Scholar
Scharpf, F. (1990), Games Real Actors Could Play: The Problem of Mutual Predictability, in «Rationality and Society», 2, pp. 471494.Google Scholar
Schofield, N. (1978), Instability of Simple Dynamics Games, in «Review of Economic Studies», vol. 45, pp. 575594.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K.A. (1978), The Giant Jigsaw Puzzle, Chicago, The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Sartori, G. (1979a), The role of Institutional Structure in the Creation of Policy Equilibrium, Beverly Hills-London, Sage, pp. 249281.Google Scholar
Sartori, G. (1979b), Institutional Arrangements and Equilibrium in Multidimensional Voting Models, in «American Journal of Political Science», vol. 23, pp. 2760.Google Scholar
Sartori, G. (1989), The Changing Textbook of Congress, in Chubb e Peterson, pp. 238266.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K.A. e Weingast, B. (1981a), Political Preference for the Pork Barrel: A Generalization, in «American Journal of Political Science», vol. 25, pp. 96111.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K.A. e Weingast, B. (1981b), Structure-induced Equilibrium and Legislative Choice, in «Public Choice», vol. 37, pp. 503519.Google Scholar
Somogyi, S., Lotti, L., Predieri, A. e Sartori, G. (1963), Il parlamento italiano: 1946-1963, Napoli, Esi.Google Scholar
Strom, G.S. (1990), The Logic of Lawmaking: A Spatial Theory Approach, Baltimore, The Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Tsebelis, G. (1990), Nested Games. Rational Choice in Comparative Politics, Berkeley, University of California Press.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K.A. e Weingast, B. (1995), Decision Making in Political Systems: Veto Players in Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, Multicameralism and Multipartyism, in «British Journal of Political Science», vol. 25, pp. 289325.Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (1981), Why so much stability?, in «Public Choice», vol. 37, pp. 189202.Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (1984), La motivazione del voto, in Carrubba, S. e Da Empoli, D. (a cura di), Scelte pubbliche, Firenze, Le Monnier, pp. 3797.Google Scholar
Weingast, B. (1979), A Rational Choice Perspective on Congressional Norms, in «American Journal of Political Science», vol. 23, pp. 245262.Google Scholar
Weingast, B. e Marshall, W. (1988), The Industrial Organization of Congress, in «Journal of Political Economy», vol. 96, pp. 132163.Google Scholar
Zucchini, F. (1995), Giochi della rappresentanza e parlamento negli Stati Uniti ed in Italia, Tesi di dottorato.Google Scholar