Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jkksz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-13T16:38:27.493Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Interest Groups, Veto Points, and Electricity Infrastructure Deployment

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 January 2006

Witold J. Henisz
Affiliation:
Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania. Philadelphia, henisz@wharton.upenn.edu
Bennet A. Zelner
Affiliation:
Walter A. Haas School of Business, University of California, Berkeley, zelnerb@haas.berkeley.edu
Get access

Abstract

In this article we examine the effects of interest group pressure and the structure of political institutions on infrastructure deployment by state-owned electric utilities in a panel of seventy-eight countries during the period 1970–94. We consider two factors that jointly influence the rate of infrastructure deployment: (1) the extent to which the consumer base consists of industrial consumers, which are capable of exerting discipline on political actors whose competing incentives are to construct economically inefficient “white elephants” to satisfy the demands of concentrated geographic interests, labor unions, and national engineering and construction lobbies; and (2) veto points in formal policymaking structures that constrain political actors, thereby reducing these actors' sensitivity to interest group demands. A higher fraction of industrial customers provides political actors with stronger incentives for discipline, reducing the deployment of white elephants and thus the infrastructure growth rate, ceteris paribus. Veto points reduce political actors' sensitivity to interest group demands in general and thus moderate the relationship between industrial interest group pressure and the rate of infrastructure deployment.Both authors contributed equally and list their names alphabetically on this joint work. Both authors acknowledge funding for this research from the University of California Energy Institute. Zelner acknowledges additional funding from the Lynde and Harry Bradley Foundation and the Edgar F. Kaiser Chair at the Haas School of Business, University of California, Berkeley. Henisz acknowledges additional funding from the Reginald H. Jones Center for Management Policy, Strategy, and Organization at the Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania. Thanks to Severin Borenstein, Rachel Croson, José de la Torre, Alexander Dyck, Tom Gilligan, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Edward Mansfield, Mathew McCubbins, Will Mitchell, David Mowery, Jeffrey Nugent, Dennis Quinn, George Tsebelis, Joel Waldfogel, Oliver Williamson, and Jan Zabojnik for their comments on previous drafts. Any errors are the responsibility of the authors.

Type
RESEARCH NOTES
Copyright
© 2006 The IO Foundation and Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Ames, Barry. 1995. Electoral Rules, Constituency Pressures and Pork Barrel: Bases of Voting in the Brazilian Congress. Journal of Politics 57 (2):32543.Google Scholar
Artana, Daniel, Fernando Navajas, and Santiago Urbiztondo. 2001. Regulation Policies Towards Utilities and Competitive Industries: The Case of Argentina. Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 41 (5):585607.Google Scholar
Baron, David P. 1991. Majoritarian Incentives, Pork Barrel Programs and Procedural Control. American Journal of Political Science 35 (1):5790.Google Scholar
Baron, David P. 1994. Electoral Competition with Informed and Uninformed Voters. American Political Science Review 88 (1):3345.Google Scholar
Baron, David P. 1999. Integrated Market and Nonmarket Strategies in Client and Interest Group Politics. Business and Politics 1 (1):734.Google Scholar
Baron, David P. 2001. Private Politics, Corporate Social Responsibility and Integrated Strategy. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 10 (1):745.Google Scholar
Beck, Thorsten, George Clarke, Alberto Groff, Philip Keefer, and Patrick Walsh. 2001. New Tools and New Tests in Comparative Political Economy: The Database of Political Institutions. World Bank Economic Review 15 (1):16576.Google Scholar
Bertero, Elisabetta, and Laura Rondi. 2000. Financial Pressure and the Behavior of Public Enterprises under Soft and Hard Budget Constraints: Evidence from Italian Panel Data. Journal of Public Economics 75 (1):7398.Google Scholar
Bortolotti, Bernardo, Marcella Fantini, and Domenico Siniscalco. 2000. Privatization and Institutions: A Cross-Country Analysis. CESifo Working Paper Series 375. Munich, Germany: Center for Economic Studies.
Bourbakri, Narjess, and Jean-Claude Cosset. 1997. The Financial and Operating Performance of Newly Privatized Firms: Evidence from Developing Countries. Journal of Finance 53 (3):1081110.Google Scholar
Boycko, Maxim, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny. 1996. A Theory of Privatization. Economic Journal 106 (435):30919.Google Scholar
Broz, J. Lawrence, and Jeffry A. Frieden. 2001. The Political Economy of International Monetary Relations. Annual Review of Political Science 4 (1):31743.Google Scholar
Cadot, Olivier, Lars-Hendrik Roller, and Andeas Stephan. 1999. A Political Economy Model of Infrastructure Allocation: An Empirical Assessment. Discussion Paper 99 (15). Berlin: Social Science Research Center.
Carey, John M., and Matthew Soberg Shugart. 1995. Incentives to Cultivate a Personal Vote: A Rank Ordering of Electoral Formulas. Electoral Studies 14 (4):41739.Google Scholar
Clark, William Roberts, and Mark Hallerberg. 2000. Mobile Capital, Domestic Institutions and Electorally Induced Monetary and Fiscal Policy. American Political Science Review 94 (2):32346.Google Scholar
Clark, William Roberts, Usha Nair Reichert, Sandra Lynn Lomas, and Kevin L. Parker. 1998. International and Domestic Constraints on Political Business Cycles in OECD Economies. International Organization 52 (1):87120.Google Scholar
Denzau, Arthur T., and Michael C. Munger. 1986. Legislators and Interest Groups: How Unorganized Interests Get Represented. American Political Science Review 80 (1):89107.Google Scholar
Driscoll, John C., and Aart C. Kraay. 1998. Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimation with Spatially-Dependent Panel Data. Review of Economic and Statistics 80 (4):54960.Google Scholar
D'Souza, Juliet, and William L. Megginson. 1999. The Financial and Operating Performance of Privatized Firms During the 1990s. Journal of Finance 54 (4):1397438.Google Scholar
Franzese, Robert J., Jr. 1999a. Partially Independent Central Banks, Politically Responsive Governments and Inflation. American Political Science Review 43 (3):681706.Google Scholar
Franzese, Robert J., Jr. 1999b. The Positive Political Economy of Public Debt: An Empirical Examination of the OECD Postwar Debt Experience. Unpublished, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor.
Friedrich, R. J. 1982. In Defense of Multiplicative Terms in Multiple Regression Equations. American Journal of Political Science 26 (4):797833.Google Scholar
Froot, Kenneth A. 1989. Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimation with Cross-Sectional Dependence and Heteroskedasticity in Financial Data. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 24 (3):33355.Google Scholar
Garrett, Geoffrey, and Peter Lange. 1995. Internationalization, Institutions and Political Change. International Organization 49 (4):62755.Google Scholar
Hallerberg, Mark, and Scott Basinger. 1998. Internationalization and Changes in Tax Policy in OECD Countries: The Importance of Domestic Veto Players. Comparative Political Studies 31 (3):32152.Google Scholar
Henisz, Witold Jerzy. 2000. The Institutional Environment for Economic Growth. Economics and Politics 12 (1):131.Google Scholar
Hird, John A. 1991. The Political Economy of Pork: Project Selection at the U.S. Army Corps of Engineers. American Political Science Review 85 (2):42956.Google Scholar
International Energy Agency. 1999. Energy Statistics. Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development.
Jaccard, James, Robert Turisi, and Choi K. Wan. 1990. Interaction Effects in Multiple Regression. London: Sage Publications.
Karp, Larry, and Jeffrey Perloff. 1995. Why Industrial Policies Fail: Limited Commitment. International Economic Review 36 (4):887905.Google Scholar
Kastner, Scott, and Chad Rector. 2003. International Regimes, Domestic Veto-Players and Capital Controls Policy Stability. International Studies Quarterly 47 (1):122.Google Scholar
Kunicova, Jana, and Susan Rose-Ackerman. 2003. Electoral Rules as Constraints on Corruption. Unpublished, Yale University, Hartford, Conn. Available at 〈http://lawweb.usc.edu/cslp/conferences/modeling_const_02/kunicova.pdf〉. Accessed 1 September 2005.
Laffont, Jean-Jacques, and Jean Tirole. 1991. Privatization and Incentives. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 7 (special issue):84103.Google Scholar
La Porta, Rafael, and Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes. 1999. The Benefits of Privatization: Evidence from Mexico. Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (4):1193242.Google Scholar
Levy, Brian, and Pablo T. Spiller. 1994. The Institutional Foundations of Regulatory Commitment: A Comparative Analysis of Telecommunications Regulation. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 10 (2):20146.Google Scholar
Levy, Brian, and Pablo T. Spiller. 1996. Regulations, Institutions and Commitment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Lohmann, Susanne. 1998. Federalism and Central Bank Independence: The Politics of German Monetary Policy, 1957–1992. World Politics 50 (3):40146.Google Scholar
Lohmann, Susanne, and Sharyn O'Halloran. 1994. Divided Government and U.S. Trade Policy: Theory and Evidence. International Organization 48 (4):595632.Google Scholar
Lyon, Thomas P., and John W. Mayo. 2000. Regulatory Opportunism and Investment Behavior. Unpublished, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor.
MacIntyre, Andrew. 2001. Institutions and Investors: The Politics of the Financial Crisis in Southeast Asia. International Organization 55 (1):81122.Google Scholar
Mansfield, Edward D., and Marc L. Busch. 1995. The Political Economy of Nontariff Barriers: A Cross-National Analysis. International Organization 49 (4):72349.Google Scholar
Martin, Lisa L. 2000. Democratic Commitments: Legislatures and International Cooperation. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
McCubbins, Matthew D., Roger G. Noll, and Barry R. Weingast. 1987. Administrative Procedures as Instruments of Political Control. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 3 (2):24377.Google Scholar
Megginson, William L., Robert C. Nash, and Matthias Van Randenborgh. 1994. The Financial and Operating Performance of Newly Privatized Firms: An International Empirical Analysis. Journal of Finance 49 (2):40352.Google Scholar
Megginson, William L., and Jeffry M. Netter. 2001. From State to Market: A Survey of Empirical Studies on Privatization. Journal of Economic Literature 39 (2):32189.Google Scholar
Milner, Helen V. 1987. Resisting the Protectionist Temptation: Industry and the Making of Trade Policy in France and the United States During the 1970s. International Organization 41 (4):63965.Google Scholar
Milner, Helen V. 1988. Trading Places: Industries for Free Trade. World Politics 40 (3):35076.Google Scholar
Milner, Helen V., and David B. Yoffie. 1989. Between Free Trade and Protectionism: Strategic Trade Policy and a Theory of Corporate Trade Demands. International Organization 43 (2):23972.Google Scholar
Myerson, R. 1993. Effectiveness of Electoral Systems for Reducing Government Corruption: A Game Theoretic Analysis. Games and Economic Behavior 5 (1):11832.Google Scholar
Newey, Whitney K., and Kenneth D. West. 1987. A Simple, Positive Semi-Definite, Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix. Econometrica 55 (5):7038.Google Scholar
Nollen, Stanley D., and Dennis P. Quinn. 1994. Endogenous Protection in the United States, 1900–1984. International Organization 48 (3):491525.Google Scholar
Oliner, Stephen D., Glenn D. Rudebusch, and Daniel E. Sichel. 1995. New and Old Models of Business Investment: A Comparison of Forecasting Performance. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 27 (3):80626.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Peltzman, Sam. 1976. Toward a More General Theory of Regulation. Journal of Law and Economics 19 (2):21148.Google Scholar
Peltzman, Sam. 1989. The Control and Performance of State-Owned Enterprises. In Privatization and State-Owned Enterprises, edited by Paul MacAvoy et al. Boston, Mass.: Kluwer Academic.
Rajan, Raghuram G., and Luigi Zingales. 2004. Saving Capitalism from the Capitalists. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Rodrik, Dani. 1994. What Does the Political Economy Literature on Trade Policy (Not) Tell Us That We Ought to Know. Working Paper 4870. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau for Economic Research.
Rogowski, Ronald. 1989. Commerce and Coalitions: How Trade Affects Domestic Political Alignments. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Rogowski, Ronald, and Mark Andreas Kayser. 2002. Majoritarian Electoral Systems and Consumer Power: Price-Level Evidence from the OECD Countries. American Journal of Political Science 46 (3):52639.Google Scholar
Salamon, Lester M., and John J. Sigfried. 1977. Economic Power and Political Influence: The Impact of Industry Structure on Public Policy. American Political Science Review 71:102643.Google Scholar
Shapiro, Carl, and Robert D. Willig. 1990. Economic Rationales for the Scope of Privatization. In The Political Economy of Public Sector Reform and Privatization, edited by Ezra Sulieman and John Waterbury. San Francisco: Westview Press.
Shepsle, Kenneth, and Barry R. Weingast. 1981. Political Preferences for the Pork Barrel: A Generalization. American Journal of Political Science 25 (1):96111.Google Scholar
Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert W. Vishny. 1994. Politicians and Firms. Quarterly Journal of Economics 109 (4):9951025.Google Scholar
Simmons, Beth. 1994. Who Adjusts? Domestic Sources of Foreign Economic Policy During the Interwar Years. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Snyder, James M., Jr. 1992. Committee Power, Structure-Induced Equilibria and Roll Call Votes. American Journal of Political Science 36 (1):130.Google Scholar
Spiller, Pablo T. 1993. Institutions and Regulatory Commitment in Utilities' Privatization. Industrial and Corporate Change 2 (3):387450.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J. 1971. The Theory of Economic Regulation. Bell Journal of Economic and Management Science 2 (1):321.Google Scholar
Treisman, Daniel. 2000. Decentralization and Inflation: Commitment, Collective Action or Continuity. American Political Science Review 94 (4):83757.Google Scholar
Tsebelis, George. 1995. Decision-Making in Political Systems: Veto Players in Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, Multicameralism and Multipartyism. British Journal of Political Science 25 (3):289325.Google Scholar
Tsebelis, George. 2003. Veto Players: How Political Institutions Work. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press and Russell Sage Foundation.
Vining, Aidan R., and Anthony E. Boardman. 1989. Ownership and Performance in Competitive Environments: A Comparison of the Performance of Private, Mixed and State-Owned Enterprises. Journal of Law & Economics 32 (1):133.Google Scholar
Wallack, Jessica Seddon, Alejandro Gaviria, Ugo Panizza, and Ernesto Stein. 2003. Political Particularism around the World. World Bank Economic Review 17 (1):13343.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry, and Mark Moran. 1983. Bureaucratic Discretion or Congressional Control? Regulatory Policymaking by the Federal Trade Commission. Journal of Political Economy 91 (5):765800.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1976. Franchise Bidding with Respect to CATV and in General. Bell Journal of Economics 7 (1):73104.Google Scholar
Willig, Robert D. 1994. Public Versus Regulated Private Enterprise. Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics, 1993:15580.
Wilson, James Q. 1980. The Politics of Regulation. In The Politics of Regulation, edited by James Q. Wilson, 31936. New York: Basic Books.
Yoffie, David B. 1988. How an Industry Builds Political Advantage. Harvard Business Review 66 (3):8289.Google Scholar