Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-sxzjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-24T14:31:04.264Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Defining hospital markets for antitrust enforcement: new approaches and their applicability to The Netherlands

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 January 2008

MARCO VARKEVISSER*
Affiliation:
Erasmus University Rotterdam
CORY S. CAPPS
Affiliation:
Bates White, LLC
FREDERIK T. SCHUT
Affiliation:
Erasmus University Rotterdam
*
*Corresponding author: M. Varkevisser, Institute of Health Policy and Management (iBMG) and Erasmus Competition and Regulation institute (ECRi), Erasmus University Rotterdam, Room L3-125, PO Box 1738, 3000 DR Rotterdam, The Netherlands. Tel: +31 (0)10 408 8950. Email: varkevisser@bmg.eur.nl.

Abstract

Effective antitrust enforcement is of crucial importance for countries with a market-based health care system in which hospitals are expected to compete. Assessing hospital market power – a central issue to competition policy – is, however, complicated because the presence of third party payers and the general unobservability of prices make it difficult to apply the standard methods of market definition. Alternative, less formal methods historically employed in the hospital industry have proven inaccurate; these methods were even called inapplicable in a recent US court decision. In this paper, we discuss the strengths and weaknesses of several new approaches to defining hospital markets that are suggested in the recent economic literature. In particular, we discuss the applicability of the time-elasticity approach, competitor-share approach, and option-demand approach to the recently partly deregulated Dutch hospital market. We conclude that the appropriate approach depends crucially on how health insurers contract with hospitals and how patients select their hospital.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2008

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acton, J.P. (1975), ‘Nonmonetary factors in the demand for medical services: some empirical evidence’, Journal of Political Economy, 83(3):595614CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baker, J.B. (1988), ‘The antitrust analysis of hospital mergers and the transformation of the hospital industry’, Law and Contemporary Problems, 51(2): 93164CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Capps, C.S., Dranove, D.Greenstein, S. and Satterthwaite, M. (2001), ‘The silent majority fallacy of the Elzinga–Hogarty criteria: a critique and new approach to analyzing hospital mergers’, Working Paper 8216, National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), Cambridge, MACrossRefGoogle Scholar
Capps, C.S., Dranove, D., Greenstein, S. and Satterthwaite, M. (2002), ‘Antitrust policy and hospital mergers: recommendations for a new approach’, Antitrust Bulletin, 47(4):677714CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Capps, C.S., Dranove, D. and Satterthwaite, M. (2003), ‘Competition and market power in option demand markets’, RAND Journal of Economics, 34(4):737763CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Capps, C.S. and Dranove, D. (2004), ‘Hospital consolidation and negotiated PPO prices’, Health Affairs, 23(2):175181CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Danger, K.L. and Frech, H.E. (2001), ‘Critical thinking about “critical loss” in antitrust’, Antitrust Bulletin, 46(2): 339355CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DOJ and FTC (2004), ‘Improving health care: a dose of competition’, US Department of Justice and the US Federal Trade Commission, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Dranove, D. and Ludwick, R. (1999), ‘Competition and pricing by nonprofit hospitals: a reassessment of Lynk's analysis’, Journal of Health Economics, 18(1):8798CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elzinga, K.G. and Hogarty, T.F. (1973), ‘The problem of geographic market delineation in antimerger suits’, Antitrust Bulletin, 18(1): 4581CrossRefGoogle Scholar
FTC (2005), ‘In the matter of Evanston Northwestern Healthcare Corporation: initial decision’, Docket No. 9315, US Federal Trade Commission, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
FTC (2007), ‘In the matter of Evanston Northwestern Healthcare Corporation: opinion of the Commission’, Docket No. 9315, US Federal Trade Commission, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Gaynor, M. and Vogt, W.B. (2000), ‘Antitrust and competition in health care markets’, in Cuyleren en, A.J., Newhouse, J.P. (eds), Handbook of Health Economics, volume I:14051487, Amsterdam: Elsevier ScienceGoogle Scholar
Harris, B. and Simons, J. (1989), ‘Focusing market definition: how much substitution is necessary?’, Research in Law & Economics, 12:207226Google Scholar
Katz, M.L. and Shapiro, C. (2003), ‘Critical loss: let's tell the whole story’, Antitrust, 17(2): 4956Google Scholar
Keeler, E., Melnick, G. and Zwanziger, J. (1999), ‘The changing effects of competition on non-profit and for-profit hospital pricing behaviour’, Journal of Health Economics,18(1):6986CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Langenfeld, J. and Li, W. (2001), ‘Critical loss analysis in evaluating mergers’, Antitrust Bulletin, 46(2):299337CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Motta, M. (2004), Competition Policy: Theory and Practice, Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
NMa (2005), ‘Decision no. 3897/156: Ziekenhuis Hilversum – Ziekenhuis Gooi-Noord’, The Netherlands Competition Authority, The HagueGoogle Scholar
NZa (2006), ‘Monitor onderhandelingen B-segment’ (‘Monitor report on the hospital– insurer negotiations for deregulated hospital care’), Dutch Healthcare Authority, UtrechtGoogle Scholar
O'Brien, D.P. and Wickelgren, A.L. (2004), ‘A critical analysis of critical loss’, Antitrust Law Journal, 71(1): 161184Google Scholar
Sacher, S. and Silvia, L. (1998), ‘Antitrust issues in defining the product market for hospital services’, International Journal of the Economics of Business, 5(2):181202CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scholten, G.R.M. and van der Grinten, T.E.D. (2002), ‘Integrating medical specialists and hospitals: the growing relevance of collective organization of medical specialists for Dutch hospital governance’, Health Policy, 62(2):131139CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Scholten, G.R.M. and van der Grinten, T.E.D. (2005), ‘The integration of medical specialists in hospitals: Dutch hospitals and medical specialists on the road to joint regulation’, Health Policy, 72(2):165173CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Schut, F.T. and van de Ven, W.P.M.M. (2005), ‘Rationing and competition in the Dutch health-care system’, Health Economics, 14(S1):S59S74CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Simpson, J. (2003), ‘Geographic markets in hospital mergers: a case study’, International Journal of the Economics of Business, 10(3):291303CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stole, L. and Zwiebel, J. (1996), ‘Intra-firm bargaining under non-binding contracts’, Review of Economic Studies, 63(3):375410CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tay, A. (2003), ‘Assessing competition in hospital care markets: the importance of accounting for quality differentiation’, RAND Journal of Economics, 34(4):786814CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Town, R.J. and Vistnes, G. (2001), ‘Hospital competition in HMO networks’, Journal of Health Economics, 20(5): 733–53CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Van de Ven, W.P.M.M. and Ellis, R.P. (2000), ‘Risk adjustment in competitive health plan markets’, in Culyer, A.J. and Newhouse, J.P. (eds), Handbook of Health Economics, volume I, pp. 755845, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.Google Scholar
Van Vliet, R.C.J.A. (2004), ‘Deductibles and health care expenditures: empirical estimates of price sensitivity based on administrative data’, International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics, 4(4):283305CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Varkevisser, M. and van der Geest, S.A. (2007), ‘Why do patients bypass the nearest hospital? An empirical analysis for orthopaedic care and neurosurgery in The Netherlands’, European Journal of Health Economics, 8(3): 287295CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Varkevisser, M., van der Geest, S.A. and Schut, F.T. (2004), ‘Concurrentie tussen Nederlandse ziekenhuizen: de deelmarkt voor reguliere klinische zorg’ (‘Competition among Dutch hospitals: the submarket for regular inpatient care’), Erasmus University RotterdamGoogle Scholar
Varkevisser, M., Polman, N. and van der Geest, S.A. (2006), ‘Zorgverzekeraars moeten patienten kunnen sturen’ (‘Health insurers must be able to channel patients’), Economisch Statistische Berichten, 4478: 3840Google Scholar
Werden, G.J. (1989), ‘The limited relevance of patient migration data in market delineation for hospital merger cases’, Journal of Health Economics, 8(4):363376CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Zwanziger, J., Melnick, G. and Eyre, K.M. (1994), ‘Hospitals and antitrust: defining markets, setting standards’, Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law, 19(2):423447CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed