Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-rkxrd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-17T12:32:29.108Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Role of Experts in Assessing Damages – A Law and Economics Account

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 January 2017

Michael Faure
Affiliation:
METRO, Maastricht University and Rotterdam Institute of Law and Economics (RILE), Erasmus University Rotterdam.
Louis Visscher
Affiliation:
Rotterdam Institute of Law and Economics (RILE), Erasmus University Rotterdam.

Abstract

In this contribution we focus on the role of experts in the assessment of tort damages from an economic point of view. We distinguish two different aspects.

First, we examine the role which economists might play in assessing damages in tort cases. This approach focuses on the insights that Law and Economics provides regarding the correct assessment of damages. We pay specific attention to two problematic forms of losses where economic insights may play an important role: pure economic loss and personal injury damage (both loss of income and compensation for immaterial losses due to fatal and non-fatal accidents).

Second, we investigate from a Law and Economics point of view the role of experts in general (not only economists) in the assessment of damages. We discuss i.a. the question why experts may be involved in the assessment of damages, the potential problems (and the possible solutions) when using experts, and differences between party appointed experts and court appointed experts.

It turns out that the economic analysis can provide a different, insightful viewpoint in some respects, such as the fact that market based mechanisms may help to provide incentives to party appointed experts to provide an accurate and objective damage assessment.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Verkerk explains that in common law countries the expert is often called an “expert witness”, and in continental jurisdictions an “expert”. This is caused by the fact that the former jurisdictions are more adversarial and the latter more non-adversarial. See Verkerk, Remme, “Comparative aspects of expert evidence in civil litigation”, 13 The International Journal of Evidence and Proof (2009), pp. 167 et sqq., at pp. 167, 170CrossRefGoogle Scholar; see also Verkerk, Remme, Fact Finding in Civil Litigation. A Comparative Perspective (Antwerp: Intersentia, 2010), at p. 160.Google Scholar

2 See in this respect Lopatka, John and Page, William, “Economic Authority and the Limits of Expertise in Antitrust Cases”, 90 Cornell Law Review (2004–2005), pp. 617 et sqq. Google Scholar

3 See, for example, Gregory Werden, “The Admissibility of Expert Economic Testimony in Antitrust Cases”, in American Bar Association, Issues in Competition Law and Policy (2008), pp. 801 et sqq.

4 See Waelbroeck, Denis, Slater, Donald and Even-Shoshan, Gil, Study on the Conditions of Claims for Damages in Case of Infringement of EC Competition Rules – Comparative Report (Brussels: Ashurst, 31 August 2004).Google Scholar

5 See in this respect inter alia Mandel, Michael, “Going for the Gold: Economics as Expert Witnesses”, 13 Journal of Economic Perspectives (1999), pp. 113 et sqq. CrossRefGoogle Scholar

6 See Brookshire, Michael and Slesnick, Frank, “Prevailing Practice in Forensic Economics”, 10 Journal of Forensic Economics (1997), pp. 1 et sqq. CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Thornton, Robert and Ward, John, “The Economist in Tort Litigation”, 13 Journal of Economic Perspectives (1999), pp. 101 et sqq. CrossRefGoogle Scholar

7 See, for example, Deakin, Simon, Johnston, Angus and Markesinis, Basil, Markesinis and Deakin's Tort law, 6th ed. (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 2008), at p. 52 Google Scholar; Dobbs, Dan, The law of torts (St. Paul, Minnesota: West Publishing Co., 2000), at pp. 12, 13Google Scholar; Fleming, John, The law of torts, 8th ed. (Sydney: Law Book Company, 1992), at p. 1 Google Scholar; Keeton, Page et al., Prosser and Keeton on the Law of Torts, 5th student ed. (St. Paul, Minnesota: West Publishing Co., 1984), at pp. 5, 6Google Scholar; Magnus, Ulrich, “Comparative Report on the Law of Damages”, in Magnus, Ulrich (ed.), Unification of Tort Law: Damages (The Hague: Kluwer Law International, 2001), pp. 185 et sqq., at p. 185Google Scholar; Rogers, Horton, Winfield & Jolowicz on Tort, 17th ed. (London: Sweet and Maxwell, 2006), at pp. 2, 3.Google Scholar

8 This basic insight follows from the early writing of Calabresi, Guido, The Costs of Accidents. A Legal and Economic Analysis, 5th printing (New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press, 1977)Google Scholar and has been worked out inter alia by Shavell, Steven, “Strict Liability versus Negligence”, 9 Journal of Legal Studies (1980), pp. 1 et sqq. CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Shavell, Steven, Foundations of Economic Analysis of Law (Cambridge, Massachusetts: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, 2004), at pp. 178 et sqq. Google Scholar; Posner, Richard, Economic Analysis of Law (New York: Aspen Publishers 6th edition, 2003), at pp. 167 et sqq.Google Scholar

9 See in this respect also Thornton and Ward, “Economist in Tort Litigation”, supra note 6.

10 These costs are referred to by Calabresi as the so-called “tertiary accident costs” and would by some be referred to as “transaction costs”. However, since formally no transactions take place between a victim and an injurer in a tort case, we rather refer to these as “administrative costs”.

11 See Spier, Jaap, Verbintenissen uit de wet en schadevergoeding, 3rd ed. (Deventer: Kluwer, 2003), at p. 207.Google Scholar

12 See for a similar conclusion Baumann, Florian and Friehe, Tim, “On the Superiority of Damage Averaging in the Case of Strict Liability”, 29 International Review of Law and Economics (2009), pp. 138 et sqq. CrossRefGoogle Scholar

13 This point has been made by Kaplow, Louis and Shavell, Steven, “Accuracy in the Assessment of Damages”, 39 Journal of Law and Economics (1996), pp. 191 et sqq. CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Kaplow, Louis and Shavell, Steven, Fairness versus Welfare (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 2002), at pp. 265 et sqq.Google Scholar

14 A difference exists in that respect between strict liability and negligence: under strict liability, compensation should be full since this will provide incentives to the potential injurer to correctly weigh costs and benefits of additional care. Under a negligence rule, full compensation is not necessary. As long as the court bases the level of due care on a weighing of costs and benefits of care, the damages should only be high enough to make it financially more attractive for the injurer to take due care (thus avoiding liability) than to be negligent (thus paying the compensation). This difference between strict liability and negligence has been proven by Cooter, Robert, “Prices and Sanctions”, 84 Columbia Law Review (1984), pp. 1343 et sqq. CrossRefGoogle Scholar For practical purposes in this paper we, however, refer to a necessity of “full compensation” although the reader should be aware that this is formally only required under a strict liability rule, not under negligence.

15 For a summary of this literature see Faure, Michael, “Compensation of Non-pecuniary Loss: An Economic Perspective”, in Magnus, Ulrich and Spier, Jaap (eds), European Tort Law. Liber Amicorum for Helmut Koziol (Frankfurt am Main: Peter Lang Verlag, 2000), pp. 143 et sqq. Google Scholar

16 Polinsky, Mitchell and Shavell, Steven, “Punitive Damages: An Economic Analysis”, 111 Harvard Law Review (1998), pp. 869 et sqq. CrossRefGoogle Scholar; see also Visscher, Louis, “Economic Analysis of Punitive Damages”, in Koziol, Helmut and Wilcox, Vanessa (eds), Punitive Damages: Common Law and Civil Law Perspectives (Vienna: Springer, 2009), pp. 219 et sqq., at pp. 222 et sqq.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

17 See, for example, Bussani, Mauro and Palmer, Vernon (eds), Pure Economic Loss in Europe (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 2003)CrossRefGoogle Scholar and Bussani, Mauro, Palmer, Vernon and Parisi, Fransesco, “Liability for Pure Financial Loss in Europe: An Economic Restatement”, 51 American Journal of Comparative Law (2003), pp. 113 et sqq. CrossRefGoogle Scholar

18 Barendrecht, Maurits, “Pure Economic Loss in the Netherlands”, in Hondius, Ewoud, Netherlands Reports to the Fifteenth International Congress of Comparative Law (Groningen: Intersentia Rechtswetenschappen, 1998), pp. 115 et sqq. Google Scholar; van Dunné, Jan, “Liability for Pure Economic Loss: Rule or Exception? A Comparatist's View of the Civil Law – Common Law Split on Compensation of Non-Physical Damage in Tort Law”, 7 European Review of Private Law (1999), pp. 397 et sqq. Google Scholar

19 For a nuanced summary of the literature in this respect see De Mot, Jef, “Pure Economic Loss”, in Faure, Michael (ed.), Tort Law and Economics (Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 2009), pp. 201 et sqq. Google Scholar

20 These are cases where e.g. a contractor breaches a utility cable as a result of which a firm looses profit because it has to close down temporarily for being out of electricity. The question then arises whether the economic loss suffered by the enterprise has to be compensated by the contractor.

21 See Bishop, William, “Economic Loss in Tort”, 2 Oxford Journal of Legal Studies (1982), pp. 1 et sqq. CrossRefGoogle Scholar; see also the special of the International Review of Law and Economics (2007), pp. 1–110.

22 For an overview of the economic literature in this domain see Dari-Mattiacci, Giuseppe, “The Economics of Pure Economic Loss and the Internationalization of Multiple Externalities”, in van Boom, Willem, Koziol, Helmut, and Witting, Christian (eds), Pure Economic Loss. Tort and Insurance Law (Vienna: Springer 2004), pp. 167 et sqq. CrossRefGoogle Scholar

23 With this we do not suggest that it would be socially optimal never to award compensation for small losses, due to administrative costs. This could be problematic since the activity may shift to cause several small losses instead of a few larger ones. Moreover, if the court system works well, there may be fewer cases and thus administrative costs can be lower since parties could anticipate the results of the court case and would thus settle.

24 Lewis, Richard, McNabb, Robert, Robinson, Helen and Wass, Victoria, “Court Awards of Damages for Loss of Future Earnings: An Empirical Study and an Alternative Method of Calculation”, 20 Journal of Law and Society (2002), pp. 406 et sqq., at p. 412.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

25 Lewis et al., “Loss of Future Earnings”, supra note 24, at p. 414.

26 Ibid., at p. 415.

27 Rogers, Horton, “Comparative Report of a Project Carried Out By the European Centre for Tort and Insurance Law”, in Rogers, Horton (ed.), Damages for Non-Pecuniary Loss in a Comparative Perspective (Vienna: Springer, 2001), pp. 245 et sqq., at. p. 247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

28 Of course we do realise that, especially to the extent that personal injury or death are caused intentionally, criminal law may apply and may provide incentives for prevention as well. Here, however, we focus on incentives provided by tort law. For the possible role of punitive damages in this respect, see supra note 16.

29 Viscusi, Kip and Aldy, Joseph, “The Value of a Statistical Life: A Critical Review of Market Estimates throughout the World”, 27 The Journal of Risk and Uncertainty (2003), pp. 5 et sqq. CrossRefGoogle Scholar

30 Sunstein, Cass, “Lives, Life-Years, and Willingness to Pay”, 104 Columbia Law Review (2004), pp. 205 et sqq., at p. 205CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Posner, Eric and Sunstein, Cass, “Dollars and Death”, 72 University of Chicago Law Review (2005), pp. 537 et sqq., at p. 563.Google Scholar

31 Viscusi and Aldy, “Value of a Statistical Life”, supra note 29, at p. 63.

32 Kenkel, Don, “WTP- and QALY-Based Approaches to Valuing Health for Policy: Common Ground and Disputed Territory”, 34 Environmental & Resource Economics (2006), pp. 419 et sqq., at p. 421.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

33 See also Weinstein, Milton, “Spending Health Care Dollars Wisely: Can Cost-Effectiveness Analysis Help?”, Sixteenth Annual Herbert Lourie Memorial Lecture of Health Policy 2005, at pp. 5, 6Google Scholar; Ashenfelter, Orley, “Measuring the Value of a Statistical Life: Problems and Prospects”, 116 The Economic Journal (2006), pp. C10 et sqq. CrossRefGoogle Scholar

34 See, e.g., Devlin, Nancy and Parkin, David, “Does NICE have a Cost Effectiveness Threshold and What Other Factors Influence its Decisions? A Binary Choice Analysis”, 13 Health Economics (2004), pp. 437 et sqq., at p. 450.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

35 Hirth, Richard, Chernew, Michael, Edward, et al., “Willingness to Pay for a Quality-adjusted Life Year: In Search of a Standard”, 20 Medical Decision Making (2000), pp. 332 et sqq., at pp. 338, 340.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed

36 Miller, Ted, “Valuing Nonfatal Quality of Life Losses with Quality Adjusted Life Years: The Health Economist's Meow”, 13 Journal of Forensic Economics (2000), pp. 145 et sqq., at p. 161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

37 EuroVaQ, European Value of a Quality Adjusted Life YearFinal Report (2011), available on the Internet at <http://research.ncl.ac.uk/eurovaq/EuroVaQ_Final_Publishable_Report_and_Appendices.pdf> (last accessed on 5 August 2011), at pp. 72, 74.

38 A further refinement could consist of taking into account that with increasing age the QALY will decrease (as a result of elderly illnesses et cetera), in which case the compensation would also be lower.

39 See Karapanou, Vaia and Visscher, Louis, “Towards a Better Assessment of Pain and Suffering Damages”, 1 Journal of European Tort Law (2010), pp. 48 et sqq. CrossRefGoogle Scholar

40 Calabresi, The Costs of Accidents, supra note 8, at pp. 24 et sqq.

41 Galanter, Mark, “Why the ‘Haves’ Come Out Ahead: Speculations on the Limits of Legal Change”, 9 Law & Society Review (1974), pp. 95 et sqq., at p. 97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

42 This is to a large extent due to the adversarial trial. Thus it is often forgotten that in a way parties also have concurring interests, such as the quick resolvement of the case at relatively low costs.

43 See in that respect also Mandel, “Going for the Gold”, supra note 5, at p. 116.

44 Meadow, William and Sunstein, Cass, “Statistics, Not Experts”, 51 Duke Law Journal (2001), pp. 629 et sqq. CrossRefGoogle Scholar

45 For a summary of these studies see Slovic, Paul, Fischoff, Baruch and Lichtenstein, Sarah, “Rating the Risks”, in Slovic, Paul (ed.), The Perception of Risk (London: Earthscan Publications Ltd., 2000), pp. 104 et sqq., at pp. 109–110.Google Scholar

46 Meadow and Sunstein, “Statistics, Not Experts”, supra note 44, at p. 634.

47 See Rowe, Gene and Wright, George, “Differences in Expert and Lay Judgments of Risks: Myths or Reality?”, 21 Risk Analysis (2001), pp. 341 et sqq., at p. 342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

48 Wright, George, Bolger, Fergus and Rowe, Gene, “An Empirical Test of the Relative Validity of Expert and Lay Judgments of Risk”, 22 Risk Analysis (2002), pp. 1107 et sqq., at p. 1110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

49 See Ulen, Thomas, “Rational Choice Theory in Law and Economics”, in Bouckaert, Boudewijn and De Geest, Gerrit (eds), Encyclopaedia of Law and Economics, Vol. I, The History and Methodology of Law and Economics (Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 2000), pp. 790 et sqq., at pp. 804–806.Google Scholar

50 Parker, Jeffrey, “Daubert's Debut: The Supreme Court, The Economics of Scientific Evidence, and the Adversarial System”, 4 Supreme Court Economic Review (1995), pp. 1 et sqq. CrossRefGoogle Scholar

51 Ibid., at p. 37.

52 Ibid., at p. 47.

53 See Jonathan Tomlin and David Cooper, “When Should Judges Appoint Experts? A Law and Economics Perspective”, Bepress Legal Series. Working Paper 1699 (2006), available on the Internet at <http://law.bepress.com/expresso/eps/1699> (last accessed on 5 August 2011), at p. 10.

54 See Sarvadi, David and Blackwood, Amy, “Expert Testimony in the Silica-Cases: The Fallacy of Scientific Objectivity – Some Observations”, 14 Journal of Chemical Health & Safety (2007), pp. 31 et sqq., at p. 34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

55 Tomlin, Jonathan and Cooper, David, “Expert Testimony, Daubert, and the Determination of Damages”, 4 Review of Law & Economics (2008), pp. 213 et sqq., at pp. 220, 221.Google Scholar

56 Lee, Tahirih, “Court-Appointed Experts and Judicial Reluctance: A proposal to Amend Rule 706 of the Federal Rules of Evidence”, 6 Yale Law & Policy Review (1988), pp. 480 et sqq., at p. 482.Google Scholar

57 Mandel, “Going for the Gold”, supra note 5, at p. 113.

58 Sales, Bruce and Shuman, Daniel, Experts in Court. Reconciling Law, Science, and Professional Knowledge (Washington: American Psychological Association, 2005), at pp. 6, 7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

59 In the words of Thornton and Ward: “This tends to create strong if sometimes subtle pressure upon the economist to directly or indirectly advocate the position of the side that has hired him”; Thornton and Ward, “Economist in Tort Litigation”, supra note 6, at p. 106.

60 In the words of Mandel: “Lawyers are persuasive characters. If you're not prepared for it, you can find yourself saying things you would never say to your colleagues”; Mandel, “Going for the Gold”, supra note 5, at p. 119.

61 Krafka, Carol, Dunn, Meghan, Johnson, Molly Treadway et al., “Judge and Attorney Experiences, Practices, and Concerns Regarding Expert Testimony in Federal Civil Trials”, 8 Psychology, Public Policy, and Law (2002), pp. 309 et sqq., at p. 328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

62 Tomlin and Cooper, “When Should Judges Appoint Experts”, supra note 53, at p. 11.

63 113 S Ct 2786 (1993).

64 See on this Daubert case law and the subsequent Supreme Court case law also “Reliable Evaluation of Expert Testimony” (note), 116 Harvard Law Review (2002–2003), pp. 2142 et sqq.; Werden, “Admissibility of Expert Economic Testimony”, supra note 3.

65 Tomlin and Cooper, “When Should Judges Appoint Experts”, supra note 53, at p. 5.

66 In Re Silica Products Liability Litigation, no. 2:05-CV-00121, S.D. Tex. 30 June, 2005.

67 See for a discussion of this interesting case Sarvadi and Blackwood, “Expert Testimony in the Silica-Cases”, supra note 54.

68 These were based inter alia on an x-ray of the chest, a prior history of exposure to silica and the exclusion of other possible sources of the disease.

69 Posner, Richard, “The Law and Economics of the Economic Expert Witness”, 13 Journal of Economic Perspectives (1999), pp. 91 et sqq., at pp. 94, 95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

70 Verkerk, Remme, “Procesrechtelijke waarborgen voor een betrouwbaar deskundigenonderzoek”, 24 Nederlands Tijdschrift voor Burgerlijk Recht (2007), pp. 491 et sqq. Google Scholar; see also Verkerk, Fact Finding in Civil Litigation, supra note 1, at p. 166.

71 Posner, “Economic Expert Witness”, supra note 69, at p. 94.

72 Thornton and Ward, “Economist in Tort Litigation”, supra note 6, at p. 108.

73 The use of lists does, however, not go undisputed either. To the extent that courts would only appoint experts on the list and not others of equal quality these lists could lead to an effective monopoly. We will discuss this problem in the next subsection. However, removing a bad expert from a list could provide appropriate incentives to the expert for a higher quality testimony, even if being party appointed.

74 See generally on self-regulation Ogus, Anthony, “Self-regulation”, in Bouckaert, Boudewijn and De Geest, Gerrit (eds), Encyclopaedia of Law and Economics, Vol. V, The Economics of Crime and Litigation (Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 2000), pp. 587 et sqq. Google Scholar; Ogus, Anthony, “Rethinking Self-regulation”, 15 Oxford Journal of Legal Studies (1995), pp. 97 et sqq. CrossRefGoogle Scholar

75 See the contributions in Faure, Michael, Finsinger, Jörg, Siegers, Jacques and Van den Bergh, Roger (eds), Regulation of Professions: A Law and Economics Approach to the Regulation of Attorneys and Physicians in the U.S., Belgium, the Netherlands, Germany and the U.K. (Antwerp: Maklu, 1993).Google Scholar

76 Bosscha, Nico, “Verkeersongevallenanalyse: een vak apart?”, in Asser, Willem et al., De rol van de deskundige in het schaderegelingsproces: inleiding, gehouden op het symposion van de Vereniging van Letselschade Advocaten 2001 (Lelystad: Koninklijke Vermande, 2001), pp. 13 et sqq., at p. 16.Google Scholar

77 Nederlands Instituut van Register Experts (NIVRE).

78 Associatie van Belgische Experten (ABEX).

79 Smith, Adam, An Inquiry into the Nature and the Causes of the Wealth of Nations, 5th ed. (New York: The Modern Library, reprint 1937), at pp. 127128.Google Scholar

80 Thornton and Ward, “Economist in Tort Litigation”, supra note 6, at p. 110.

81 Elliott, Donald, “Toward Incentive Based Procedures: Three Approaches for Regulating Scientific Evidence”, 69 Boston University Law Review (1989), pp. 487 et sqq., at p. 492.Google Scholar

82 Elliott, “Toward Incentive Based Procedures”, supra note 81, at pp. 501 et sqq.

83 Huber, Peter, “A Comment on Toward Incentive Based Procedures: Three Approaches for Regulating Scientific Evidence”, 69 Boston University Law Review (1989), pp. 513 et sqq., at p. 514.Google Scholar

84 Schwartz, Robert, “There is No Archbishop of Science – A Comment on Elliott's Toward Incentive Based Procedures: Three Approaches for Regulating Scientific Evidence”, 69 Boston University Law Review (1989), pp. 517 et sqq., at pp. 519, 520.Google Scholar

85 Posner, “Economic Expert Witness”, supra note 69, at p. 93; see also Lee, “Court-Appointed Experts”, supra note 56, at pp. 484, 488.

86 Tomlin and Cooper, “When Should Judges Appoint Experts”, supra note 53, at pp. 14 et sqq.; Tomlin and Cooper, “Expert Testimony”, supra note 55, at p. 11.

87 Tomlin and Cooper, “When Should Judges Appoint Experts”, supra note 53, at p. 28.

88 Parker, Jeffrey and Kobayashi, Bruce, “Evidence”, in Bouckaert, Boudewijn and G., Gerrit De Geest (eds), Encyclopaedia of Law and Economics, Vol. V, The Economics of Crime and Litigation (Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 2000), pp. 290 et sqq., at pp. 294, 295.Google Scholar

89 Froeb, Luke and Kobayashi, Bruce, “Naïve, Biased, Yet Bayesian: Can Juries Interpret Selectivity Produced Evidence?”, 12 The Journal of Law, Economics & Organization (1996), pp. 257 et sqq., at pp. 275–276.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

90 This corresponds with the simple example provided at the end of Section IV.3 supra.

91 This is strongly related to the behavioural bias of the “anchoring effect” discussed above.

92 Tomlin and Cooper, “When Should Judges Appoint Experts”, supra note 53, at pp. 12, 13.

93 Froeb, Luke and Kobayashi, Bruce, “Evidence production in adversarial vs. inquisitorial regimes”, 70 Economics Letters (2001), pp. 267 et sqq. CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Tomlin and Cooper, “When Should Judges Appoint Experts”, supra note 53, at p. 14; Tomlin and Cooper, “Expert Testimony”, supra note 55, at p.8.

94 See Posner, “Economic Expert Witness”, supra note 69, at p. 96.

95 Sales and Shuman, Experts in Court, supra note 58, at p. 132.

96 Verkerk, Comparative aspects, supra note 1, at pp. 168 et sqq.

98 Ibid., at p. 175.

98 Ibid., at p. 180.

99 Ibid., at p. 193.

100 Mandel, “Going for the Gold”, supra note 5, at p. 119.

101 Posner, “Economic Expert Witness”, supra note 69, at pp. 94, 95.

102 See, for example, Hall, Robert and Lazear, Victoria, “Reference Guide on Estimation of Economic Losses in Damage Awards”, in Reference Manual on Scientific Evidence, 2nd ed. (Federal Judicial Center, 2000), pp. 277 et sqq. Google Scholar

103 See Meyst-Michels, Jacqueline, “De normen die gelden voor een geneeskundig adviseur in particuliere verzekeringszaken”, 10 PIV Bulletin (October 2007), pp. 1 et sqq.Google Scholar

104 Note Harvard Law Review, Reliable Evaluation of Expert Testimony, supra note 64, at pp. 2160–2162.

105 Tomlin and Cooper, “When Should Judges Appoint Experts”, supra note 53, at p. 31.

106 See Sarvadi and Blackwood, “Expert Testimony in the Silica-Cases”, supra note 54, at p. 34.

107 Tomlin and Cooper, “When Should Judges Appoint Experts”, supra note 53, at p. 32.

108 Alemanno, Alberto, “Science and Risk Regulation: The Role of Experts in Decision-Making and Judicial Review”, in Vos, Ellen (ed.), European Risk Governance – Its Science, its Inclusiveness and its Effectiveness, CONNEX Report Series Nr 06 (2008), pp. 37 et sqq., at pp. 65 et sqq.Google Scholar