Hostname: page-component-84b7d79bbc-4hvwz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-28T20:15:46.794Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Urban Rationing in Communist China1

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 February 2009

Extract

From an economic point of view, a ration coupon can serve at least three purposes: it can control the movement of people from one place to another, thereby easing employment, housing and transportation problems; it can distribute basic necessities, such as foodstuffs, more evenly in times of scarcity; and it can shift purchasing power away from certain goods, thus helping to maintain stable prices on these goods during periods of inflationary pressure. However, while each of these goals can be analysed in a narrowly economic framework, it is important to consider their political consequences as well. Inflation, for example, may cause political discontent even before it brings about economic dislocation. Any consideration of Peking's rationing policies, therefore, must touch on both the economic and non-economic aspects of the problem.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The China Quarterly 1966

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

2 Ta-chung, Liu and Kung-chia, YenThe Economy of the Chinese Mainland: National Income and Economic Development 1933–1959 (Santa Monica: The RAND Corporation, 1963), Vol. 1, p. 110Google Scholar .

3 In 1962 the problem of bloated payrolls had still not been solved to the régime's satisfaction. See Kan-ch-eng, Hsiang, “Strict Control and Rational Use of Wage Funds,” Lao-lung (Labor), No. 14, 08 18, 1962Google Scholar , in Selections from China Mainland Magazines (SCMM) (Hong Kong: U.S. Consulate-General), No. 334.

4 The relevant concept is really marginal productivity, and it is unlikely that this was increasing very much. However, the Chinese tended to base their wage policy on average productivity. See Perkins, Dwight H., “Price Stability and Development in Mainland China (1951–1963),” The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. LXXII (08 1964), pp. 365366Google Scholar .

5 Tse-tung, Mao, “On the Correct Handling of Contradictions among the People,” in Selected Readings from the Writings of Mao Tse-tung (Peking: Jen-min Ch'u-pan She, 1964), Vol. 1, p. 485Google Scholar .

6 Current Background (CB) (Hong Kong: U.S. Consulate-General), No. 405.

7 Perkins, , op. cit., p. 363Google Scholar . Corroborative data appear in Liu, and Yeh, , op. cit., Vol. 1, p. 380Google Scholar .

8 Kia-ngau, Chang, The Inflationary Spiral: The Experience in China, 1939–1950 (Cambridge: Technology Press, 1958), pp. 371373Google Scholar .

9 Perkins, , op. cit., p. 361Google Scholar .

10 Derived from data in Liu, and Yen, , op. cit., Vol. 1, p. 155Google Scholar .

11 Shang-hai Chieh-fang Ch'ien-hou Wu-chia Tzu-liao Hui-plen (Compendium of Materials on Commodity Prices in Shanghai before and after Liberation) (Shanghai: Jen-min Ch'u-pan She, 1958), p. 460Google Scholar .

12 “State Council Directive on Strengthening Leadership in Banking Deposits and Promoting the People's Savings,” Chung-hua Jen-mln Kung-ho-kuo Fa-kuei Hui-pien (Compendium of the Laws and Regulations of the People's Republic of China) (Peking: Fa-lu Ch'u-pan She, 1955-present), Vol. IXGoogle Scholar . This series is cited hereafter as the Fa-kuei Hui-pien.

13 Reiitsu, Kojima, “Grain Acquisition and Supply in China,” Contemporary China, Vol. V (1963), p. 75Google Scholar .

14 CB, No. 339.

15 MacFarquhar, Roderick, The Hundred Flowers Campaign and the Chinese Intellectuals (New York: Praeger, 1960), p. 232Google Scholar .

16 Kojima, , op. cit., p. 70Google Scholar .

17 Price Gaps between Industrial Products and Farm Products: Their Changes in Post-Liberation Years,” T'ung-chl Kung-tso (Statistical Work) No. 17 (09 14, 1957)Google Scholar , in Extracts from China Mainland Magazines (ECMM) (Hong Kong: U.S Consulate-General), No. 104.

18 Mao, , op. cit., p. 467Google Scholar .

19 “Directive of the Government Affairs Council on Discouraging the Blind Influx of Peasants into the Cities,” Chung-yang Jen-min Cheng-fu Fa-ling Hui-pien (Compendium of the Laws and Orders of the Central People's Government) (Peking: Fa-lu Ch'u-pan She, 19521955), Vol. VI, p. 274Google Scholar . This series is cited hereafter as the Fa-ling Hui-pien.

20 “Concerning the Continued Implementation of the Directive Discouraging the Blind Influx of Peasants into the Cities,” Fa-ling Hui-pien, Vol. VII, pp. 147–148.

21 Based on an unpublished manuscript by Professor Ezra Vogel of Harvard University.

22 For a description of the American experience, see Thompson, Victor A., The Regulatory Process in OP A Rationing (New York: King's Crown Press, 1950)Google Scholar . For England, see Impresario, , The Market Square: The Story of the Food Ration Book, 1940–1944, (London: 1944)Google Scholar .

23 The text is given in Survey of the China Mainland Press (SCMP) (Hong Kong: U.S. Consulate-General), No. 45.

24 Fa-ling Hui-pien, Vol. VI, pp. 129–131.

25 Ibid. p. 129.

26 Vogel, op. cit.

27 Fa-ling Hui-pien, Vol. VII, p. 62.

28 CB. No. 398.

29 Thompson, , op. cit., p. 48Google Scholar .

30 Fa-kuei Hui-pien, Vol. 1, pp. 243–244.

31 Fa-kuei Hui-pien, Vol. 1, pp. 171–175.

32 Important Measures to Improve the Work of Basic-Level State Power in the Cities,” People's Daily, 01 2, 1955, in CB, No. 310Google Scholar .

34 Fa-kuei Hui-pien, Vol. II, p. 567–568.

35 Vogel, op. cit.

36 Fa-kut Hui-pien, Vol. II, pp. 567–568.

37 A Review of Urban Food Rationing and Some Suggestions for Improvement of the System,” Liang-shih (Grain), No. 8 (08 25, 1957)Google Scholar , in ECMM, No. 110.

38 Let Us Improve the Work of Grain Supply in the Towns,” Liang-shih Kung-tso (Grain Work), No. 3 (03 14, 1956)Google Scholar , in ECMM, No. 37.

39 Fa-kuei Hui-pien, Vol. II, p. 567.

40 ECMM, No. 37.

41 Vogel, op. cit.

42 Kojima, op. cit., p. 81.

43 Perkins, , op. cit., p. 369Google Scholar .

44 Fa-kuet Hui-pien, Vol. V, p. 187.

45 Thompson, , op. cit., p. 56Google Scholar .

46 Fa-kuei Hui-pien, Vol. II, p. 567.

47 Vogel, op. cit.

48 Fa-ling Hui-pien, Vol. VII, p. 63.

49 SCMP, No. 759, p. 5.

50 Fa-ling Hui-pien, Vol. VI, p. 130.

51 Blaustein, Albert P., ed., Fundamental Legal Documents of Communist China (South Hackensack, N.J.: Rothman & Co., 1962), p. 218Google Scholar .

52 Kuo-chun, Chao, Economic Planning and Organization in Mainland China: A Documentary Study (1949–1957) (Cambridge: Harvard Un. Press, 19591960), Vol. II, p. 46Google Scholar .

53 Mao, . op. cit. pp. 443444Google Scholar .

54 CB, No. 405, p. 3.

55 CB, No. 497, p. 2.

56 ECMM, No. 62, p. 20.

57 ECMM, No. 136, p. 28.

58 See, for example, CB, No. 511, p. 44.

59 Fa-kuel Hui-pien, Vol. VI, pp. 229–231.