Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-m9kch Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-30T13:45:49.928Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Covenants, Privity of Contract, and the Purchaser of Personal Property

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 January 2009

Get access

Extract

This article discusses an old but vexed question in the law of obligations: to what extent can a purchaser of personal property find himself bound to observe covenants relating to that property to which he was not party? Put shortly, how far can covenants bind personal property?

This question can, of course, arise in many guises. The issue may be whether a purchaser of shares in a private company is bound by a right of pre-emption in respect of those shares held by other shareholders in the same company; whether the seller of goods can impose restrictions on the price at which remote purchasers may resell those goods; whether the mortgagee of a ship can be prevented from using the vessel inconsistently with the rights of one who has booked space in her: issues whose sheer diversity makes it most difficult to achieve the aim in this article of developing general principles in this area of the law.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge Law Journal and Contributors 1982

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Previous treatments include the classic English and American discussions by Wade, E. C. S. (Restrictions on User (1928) 44 L.Q.R. 51)Google Scholar and Chafee, Z. (Equitable Servitudes on Chattels (1928) 41 Harv.L.R. 945)Google Scholar respectively; see too McCormack, (1952) 3 Sydney L.R. 295.Google Scholar There is brief but perceptive coverage en passant in Vaines, Personal Property, 5th ed., Chap. 8 and Palmer, N. E., Bailment, pp. 972et seq.Google Scholar

2 (1858) 4 DeG. & J. 276.

3 (1848) 2 Ph. 774.

4 Ibid., at p. 777.

5 Which give the charterer the right to have his goods carried in the vessel but not possession of it. See (1858) 4 De G. & J. at p. 295; Scrulton on Charterparlies, 18th ed., p. 45.Google Scholar

6 (1858) 4 De G. & J. 276, 282.

7 See per Knight Bruce L.J. (1858) 4 De G. & J. 276, 283; per Lord Chelmsford L.C. ibid., at p. 287.

8 Ibid., at p. 299, following Lumley v. Wagner (1852) 1 De G.M. & G. 604.Google Scholar

9 See (1858) 4 De G. & J. 276, 299–300, per Lord, Chelmsford L.C.Cf. per Knight, Bruce L.J. at pp. 282283.Google Scholar

10 An argument admittedly sub silentio in De Mattos, but later emphasised by Shaw, Lord in Lord Strathcona SS. Co. v. Dominion Coal Co. [1926] A.C. 108, 119Google Scholar; on this case see below, p. 71.

11 Including, where appropriate, a mortgagee.

12 On notice, see below, pp. 79–80.

13 On the other hand, Scots law accepts that a purchaser of personal property may be treated as though he were a party to contracts concerning that property. See M'Cosh v. Crowe (1903) 5 F. 670Google Scholar; Wm. Morton & Co. v. Muir, 1907 S.C. 1211Google Scholar (the latter accepted as good law in D. M. Walker, Contracts and Related Obligations in Scotland, s. 29.57). cfThough, Melrose v. Aitken Motors, 1918, 1 S.L.T. 109.Google Scholar

14 Discounting, for the sake of argument, the plaintiff's inability to carry out his side of the bargain. The extra effectiveness of injunctive remedies will always be increased where, as in De Mailos's case, the obligor is insolvent (though why, or whether, specific remedies should always prevail over insolvency is by no means obvious).

15 Or, for that matter, specifically enforceable rights. The parallel is explored below, pp. 63–64.

16 Cf. Bridge, J. 's reasoning in Esso Petroleum Co. Ltd. v. Kingswood Motors (Addlestone) Ltd. [1974] Q.B. 142, 156. A transferred land to B in breach of covenant with C: on the ground that otherwise equitable remedies would be ineffective C obtained an injunction ordering a reconveyance of the land to A.Google Scholar

17 See Hotroyd v. Marshall (1861) 10 H.L.C. 191Google Scholar; Joseph v Lyons (1884) 15 Q.B.D. 280.Google Scholar

18 This at least seems to be clear from Oughtred v. I.R.C. [1960] A.C. 206.Google Scholar

19 See Waters, D., The Constructive Trust, Chap. 2.Google Scholar

20 Such as, e.g., the availability of insurance monies and other statutory payments to the purchaser—see Rayner v. Preston (1881) 18 Ch.D. 1Google Scholar, and Re Hamilton-Snowball's Conveyance [1959] Ch. 308.Google Scholar

21 See, e.g., Day v. Brownrigg (1878) 10 Ch.D. 294, 305Google Scholar, per James, and Thesiger, L.JJ.; White v. Mellin [1895] A.C. 154, 167Google Scholar, per Lord Watson. Cf. the even more drastic restriction of injunctions to protecting property rights in Att.-Gen. v. Sheffield Gas Consumers Co. (1853) 3 De G.M. & G. 304, 320Google Scholar and Emperor of Austria v. Day (1861) 3 De G.F. & J. 217, 253Google Scholar: on which cf. the pertinent comments of the U.S. Supreme Court in Int. News Service v. Associated Press, 348 U.S. 234, 236 (1917).Google Scholar

22 For example, the obligation to respect confidential information: see Saltman Engineering v. Campbell (1948) 65 R.P.C. 203, finally establishing that such an obligation would exist independently of contract.Google Scholar

23 Emperor of Austria v. Day (1861) 3 De G.F. & J. 217 (foreign sovereign can restrain forgery of his banknotes).Google Scholar

24 Under tho Dramatic and Musical Performers' Protection Act 1958; Ex p. Island Records [1978] Ch. 122Google Scholar (performers can restrain “bootlegging”). Although certain suggestions in Ex parte Island Records were discountenanced by Diplock, Lord in Lonrho Ltd. v. Shell Petroleum Ltd. [1981] 2 All E.R. 456, 462463, his Lordship was there only concerned with actions for damages at common law, not injunctive relief, and it is submitted the point in the text still stands.Google Scholar

25 Turner L.J. in Emperor of Austria v. Day, n. 23 above, apparently accepted that forgery was not a tort. (Contra, Lord Campbell L.C. ibid., at p. 240; but his cited authority, Bank of England v. Anderson (1837) 2 Keen 328Google Scholar, is not in point.) The Performers' Protection Acts clearly found no action in tort—Musical Performers' Protection Assn. v. British International Pictures Ltd. (1930) 46 T.L.R. 485.Google Scholar

26 Buckley v. Tutty (1971) 125 CX.R. 353, 380.Google Scholar According to Cooke v. The Football Association, The Times, 24 March 1972, practices in restraint of trade do not give rise to liability in damages.Google Scholar

27 See Routh v. Webster (1847) 10 Beav. 561Google Scholar (defendant restrained from falsely stating that plaintiff associated with company floated by him). Cf. Walker v. Ashton [1902] 2 Ch. 282, though this case may merely be an embryonic instance of the tort of passing off.Google Scholar

28 See the spectacular decision of the Court of Appeal in Nagle v. Feilden [1966] 2 Q.B. 633, restraining the Jockey Club, a private but monopolistic licensing body, from discriminating against an applicant for a trainer's licence on grounds of sex, even in the absence of any possible liability at common law. The judgment of Lord Denning M.R. is specially instructive, and largely formed the basis of the decision in Buckley v. Tutty, n. 26 above.Google Scholar

29 [1926] A.C. 108, on which see below, p. 71.

30 [1958] 2 Q.B. 146.

31 l.e., as not in restraint of trade. See Elliman v. Carrington [1901] 2 Ch. 275.Google Scholar

32 [1904] 1 Ch. 354.

33 Ibid., at 358. De Mattos's case was not even cited in the judgment.

34 [1904] 2 Ch. 306.

35 As argued, for instance by Scrutton, L. J. in Barker v. Stichney [1919] 1 K.B. 121.Google Scholar

36 Elliman v. Carringtpn, n. 31 above.

37 A view for instance, expressed by Atiyah, P. S.; see his The Rise and Fall of Freedom of Contract, at p. 699.Google Scholar

38 National Phonograph Co. v. Menck [1911] A.C. 336, 347 (P.C.).Google Scholar

39 Indeed, American jurisprudence frequently did refuse to enforce price maintenance on restraint of trade grounds. See, e.g., Chafee, , Equitable Servitudes on Chattels (1928) 41 Harv.L.R. 945, 980Google Scholar; Park v. Hartman, 153 Fed. 24, 39 (1907)Google Scholar; Waring v. W.D.A.S. Broadcasting Systems Inc., 194 Atl. 631, 637 (1937) (Pennsylvania Sup.Ct.).Google Scholar

40 The House of Lords' decision in Dunlop v. Selfridge [1915] A.C. 847Google Scholar also seems at first sight (as it did to Diplock J. in the Port Line case, below) to preclude the enforcement of resale price maintenance at common law under De Mattos v. Gibson. In fact it does not, since the House of Lords there only discussed whether a manufacturer could take advantage of a contract between wholesaler and retailer, and not whether the latter would be bound by a contract between manufacturer and wholesaler, as De Mattos v. Gibson would suggest. Similarly limited were the judgments of Phillimore, J. (1913) 29 T.L.R. 270Google Scholar at first instance, and the Court of Appeal (1914) 30 T.L.R. 250. Thus in jurisdictions where the ius quaesitum tertio is recognised, price maintenance covenants can often be enforced on that basis—see D. Ghirardelli v. Hunsicker, 164 Cal. 355, 128 P. 1041 (1912) (California)Google Scholar; Morton v. Muir, 1907 S.C. 1210 (Scotland).Google Scholar

41 Previously the Resale Prices Act 1964.

42 Thus reversing Elliman v. Carrington, n. 31 above.

43 (1848) 2 Ph. 774.

44 Compare De Mattos's case (1858) 4 De G. & J. 276, 282Google Scholar with Tulk v. Moxhay, n. 43 above, at p. 777.Google Scholar

45 The land cases were Catt v. Tourle (1869) L.R. 4 Ch.App. 654, 657Google Scholar, and Luker v. Dennis (1877) 7 Ch.D. 227, 236Google Scholar (both holding a purchaser of a public house bound by a brewery tie; both later overruled). The ship cases were Messageries Impériales v. Baines (1863) 7 L.T. 763Google Scholar; Collins v. Lamport (1864) 11 L.T. 497Google Scholar; and Cory v. Stewart (1886) 2 T.L.R. 508.Google ScholarCf. The Celtic King [1894] P. 175.Google Scholar The principle does not appear to have been applied to any other form of personalty before 1920, when Peterson, J. in MacDonald v. Eyles [1921] 1 Ch. 631 applied it to a copyright.Google Scholar

46 A doctrine fully developed in Manchester Ship Canal Co. v. Manchester Racecourse Co. [1901] 2 Ch. 37.Google Scholar See too the extended discussion in Pritchard v. Briggs [1980] 1 All E.R. 294.Google ScholarOliver, J. 's suggestion in Taylor v. Liverpool Victoria etc. (1979) [1981] 1 All E.R. 879n that some pure contractual interests might bind land is not in point since it turns entirely on the effects of an early statute.Google Scholar

47 See L.C.C. v. Allen [1914] 3 K.B. 642, 655656, per Buckley, L. J.Google Scholar

48 [1914] 3 K.B. 642.

49 [1916] 2 A.C. 54.

50 Since the charterparty was not specifically enforceable.

51 Though not quite all. Restrictions on the transfer of shares in a private company may exist to protect the value of the major shareholdings. See, e.g. the facts of Greenhalgh v. Mallard [1943] 2 AH E.R. 234.Google Scholar

52 [1919] 1 K.B. 121 (more fully covered below, pp. 75–77).

53 See Chafee, , Equitable Servitudes on Chattels (1928) 41 Harv.L.R. 945, 963964Google Scholar, approved by the Californian court in Nadell v. Grasso, 346 P. 2d 505, 509510 (1959).Google Scholar

54 E.C.S. Wade (1928) 44 L.Q.R. 51, 62.

55 Thus in overruling Catt v. Tourle (1869) L.R. 4 Ch.App. 654Google Scholar and Luker v. Dennis (1877) 7 Ch.D. 227, L.C.C. v. Allen denied that brewery ties could be enforced against a purchaser of land; yet such ties clearly were for the benefit of the brewers' business interests, not their land holdings.Google Scholar

56 Cf. Re Waterson, Berlin & Snyder, 48 F. 2d 704, 708 (1931) (C.A. 2nd Circuit).Google Scholar

57 Cf. Law of Property Act 1925, s. 4 (1), limiting the power to create new equitable interests in land.Google Scholar

58 In, e.g., Swiss Bank Corpn. v. Lloyds Bank [1980] 2 All E.R. 419 (C.A.)Google Scholar and apparently in the unreported decision of Oliver J. in I.C.I, v. Sussman, 28 May 1976 (cited in Pritchard v. Briggs, above) holding a right of pre-emption in shares unenforceable against third parties.

59 Evans v. Rival Granite Quarries [1910] 2 K.B. 979, 999, per Buckley, L. J.Google Scholar

60 Wilson v. Kelland [1910] 2 Ch. 306.Google Scholar

61 Cheshire, , Modern Law of Real Property. 12th ed., p. 93.Google Scholar

62 On this aspect of L.C.C. v. Allen, cf. Jennings, , The Courts and Administrative Law (1936) 47 Harv.L.R. 426, 438.Google Scholar

63 [1926] A.C. 108. Ironically in English proceedings arising out of the same facts Hill J. had, shortly before, suggested (obiter) that De Mattos was wrong: The Lord Strathcona [1925] P. 143.Google Scholar

64 (1924) 57 N.S.R. 113.

65 Except of course that the plaintiffs were not, as in De Mattos, unable to carry out their side of the bargain.

66 [1926] A.C. 108, 119.

67 Ibid., at p. 125.

68 Ibid., at p. 121.

69 A conclusion supported by Lord Shaw's discussion only a few lines previously of the implications of L.C.C. v. Allen.

70 Clore v. Theatrical Properties [1936] 3 All E.R. 483, 490–471Google Scholar (but this case concerned land). See too Shell Oil v. Mcllwraith (1944) 45 S.R.(N.S.W.) 144, 150, per Jordan, C. J.Google Scholar

71 See Greenhalgh v. Mallard [1943] 2 All E.R. 234, 239.Google Scholar

72 See Sweeney v. Tristram [1936] S.R.Qd. 129. 134Google Scholar; Rutherford v. Poole [1953] V.L.R. 130, 141Google Scholar; Howie v. New South Wales Lawn Tennis Club (1955) 95 CX.R. 132, 156.Google Scholar

73 [1958] 2 Q.B. 146.

74 Compensation (Defence) Act 1939, s. 4 (3).

75 The question of notice is dealt with below, pp. 79–80.

76 See [1958] 2 Q.B. 146, 166 et seq. These were of course also grounds of Scrutton, L.J. 's criticism in Barker v. Stickney [1919] 1 K.B. 121, supra, p. 69, which Diplock J. followed.Google Scholar

77 See n. 70 above.

78 [1921] 1 Ch. 631. See also Re Waterson, Berlin & Snyder, 48 F. 2d 704 (1931).Google Scholar

79 Ontario Jockey Club v. McBride [1927] S.C.R. 84Google Scholar, upheld on other grounds by the Privy Council at [1927] A.C. 916. Cf. the remarkable British Columbia decision in Canadian Brotherhood etc. v. B.C.A. [1971] 1 W.W.R. 39 applying the principle by analogy to the goodwill of a business.Google Scholar

80 Tri-Continental Finance Corpn. v. Tropical Marine Enterprises Inc., 265 F.2d. 619 (1959).Google Scholar

81 Murphy v. Christian Press, 56 N.Y.S. 597 (1897).Google Scholar

82 Waring v. W.D.A.S. Broadcasting Systems Inc., 194 Atl. 631 (1937) (Pa.Sup.Ct.).Google ScholarCf. Waring V. Dunlea, 26 F.Supp. 787 (1939).Google Scholar

83 See Nadell v. Grasso, 141 Cal. 203, 346 P. 2d 505 (1959)Google Scholar; Clairol v. Cody's Inc. 353 Mass. 385, 231 N.E. 2d 912 (1967) (semble).Google Scholar

84 But for a different reason. Restrictive covenants against land must be negative, it is suggested, because of the analogy of negative easements.

85 l.e., the shareholder may be enjoined from abstaining as much as from voting inconsistently. See Puddephatt v. Leith [1916] 1 Ch. 200.Google Scholar

86 And see now the Law of Property Act 1925, s. 79, presuming that restrictive covenants relating to land are intended to bind the land itself.

87 [1943] 2 All E.R. 234.

88 [1919] 1 K.B. 121.

89 But cf. Re Waterson, Berlin & Snyder, 48 F. 2d 704 (1931), where an American court reached the opposite result.Google Scholar

90 See per Scrutton, L. J. in Barker's case, n. 88 at pp. 133134.Google Scholar

91 See Westhoughton V.D.C. v. Wigan Coal Co. [1919] 1 Ch. 159.Google Scholar

92 Nevertheless statute has attempted to save the author from the effects of his publisher's bankruptcy: see the Bankruptcy Act 1914, s. 60 (a singularly ineffectual reform, though, since most publishers are companies, and s. 60 does not apply in a winding-up: Re Health Promotion Ltd. [1932] 1 Ch. 65 and Barker's case itself).Google Scholar

93 [1977] Ch. 106, 300.

94 This was on the analogy of certain cases concerning covenants on land, notably Westhoughton U.D.C. v. Wigan Coal Co. [1919] 1 Ch. 159Google Scholar, Balsall v. Brizell [1957] Ch. 169Google Scholar and Radstock Co-operative Soc. v. Norton-Radstock U.D.C. [1967] Ch. 1094; [1968] Ch. 605. Whether such a broad analogy is sound is, with respect, open to question.Google Scholar

95 Cf. too, though Jessel, M. R. 's judgment in Werderman v. S'té Générale d'Electricité (1881) 19 Ch.D. 246 which suggests, contrary to the text, that mere collateral covenants to pay money can be enforced under De Mattos v. Gibson. But the suggestion was obiter; Lush L.J. 's decision in the same case is on different, sounder, grounds.Google Scholar

96 [1908] 2 Ch. 127

97 Palmer, N. E., Bailment, p. 982, a most instructive treatment of the subject.Google Scholar

98 Quaere if there was a busmen's strike and very few buses available for hire.

99 E.g., sale of a ship on terms that it is never to be used to compete with the seller's shipping business. See Tri-Continental Finance Corpn. v. Tropical Marine Enterprises Inc., 265 F. 2d 619 (1959)Google Scholar where, however, the American court enforced the covenant against a sub-purchaser having (oddly) decided it was not in restraint of trade. Cf. too Clairol v. Cody's Inc., 353 Mass. 385; 231 N.E. 2d 912 (1967).Google Scholar

1 Under, e.g., the. Restrictive Practices Act 1976, Resale Prices Act 1976, or art. 86 of the Treaty of Rome.

2 See Ontario lockey Club v. McBride [1927] S.C.R. 84Google Scholar, affirmed on other grounds [1927] A.C. 916 (P.C.). Contra, I.C.I, v. SussmanGoogle Scholar (Oliver, J., unreported, 28 May 1976, cited in Pritchard v. Briggs [1980] Ch. 338). It is submitted that decision is wrong and should not be followed.Google Scholar

3 Cf. Greenhalgh v. Mallard [1943] 2 All E.R. 234, above, n. 87.Google Scholar

4 Thus the Massachusetts court in Clairol v. Cody's Inc. above, n. 99, only allowed distribution to the general public of bottles of hair dye marked “For Professional use only” on condition that suitable warnings for the home user were included.

5 For instance, dangerous chemicals, perhaps?

6 141 Cal. 203, 346 P. 2d 505 (1959).

7 194 Atl. 631 (1937). Cf. Jefferys V. Boosey (1854) 4 H.L.C. 815, 963, per Brougham, Lord.Google Scholar

8 Ibid., at p. 637.

9 See per Knight, Bruce L.J. in De Mattos's case itself; (1858) 4 De G. & J. 276, 282.Google Scholar

10 Quaere if the defendant is a volunteer without notice, actual or constructive? On the analogy of equitable proprietary interests, it is submitted that a De Maitps v. Gibson claim will lie against him. But any injunction should be conditional on the plaintiff reimbursing the defendant his innocent expenditure on the property itself, and possibly any other loss he suffers through having in good faith changed his position.

11 Joseph v. Lyons (1884) 15 Q.B.D. 280Google Scholar; Maitland, , Equity, 2nd ed., ed. Brunyate, , p. 146.Google Scholar

12 E.g., Manchester Trust v. Furness [1895] 2 Q.B. 539, 545Google Scholar, per Lindley, L. J., Greer v. Downs Supply Co. [1927] 2 K.B. 28, 35,Google Scholarper Scrutton, L.J., County Laboratories v. Mindel [1957] Ch. 295, 297Google Scholar, per Harman, J.Diplock, J. 's mistrust of De Mattos and Strathcona in Port Line v. Ben Line was partly due to fear of constructive notice intruding on commercial law; see [1958] 2 Q.B. 146, esp. p. 167.Google Scholar

13 [1979] Ch. 548, 575. This assertion however loses much of its force because Browne, Wilkinson J. in Swiss Bank wrongly identified the rule in De Mattos v. Gibson with the tort of inducing breach of contract, for which actual notice of the contract is indubitably necessary.Google Scholar

14 The Celtic King [1894] P. 175.Google ScholarCf. Wilkes v. Spponer [1911] 2 K.B. 473 for an analogous rule concerning equitable interests in land.Google Scholar

15 The trial judge apparently awarded damages against the defendant in the Strathcona case (see [1926] A.C. 108). It is submitted that this award, which was accepted without question or comment by the Privy Council, can only be justified on the basis of Lord Cairns' Act. Quaere incidentally whether damages should be available where, had the defendant's predecessor in title still been in possession of the property concerned, no injunction would have issued against him. In such cases the unjust enrichment of the defendant, which lies behind De Mattos v. Gibson, might be difficult to prove.

16 As observed with some trepidation by Coleridge, J. in his dissenting judgment in Lumley v. Gye (1853) 2 E. & B. 216, 246.Google Scholar

17 [1949] Ch. 556.

18 Even where the customer and not the defendant makes the first approach. The tort is really one of knowing participation in a breach of contract. See Salvadori's case [1949] Ch. at p. 563; Sefton v. Tophams Ltd. [1965] Ch. 1140, 1160, per Stamp, J. (reversed on other grounds [1967] 1 A.C. 50).Google Scholar

19 [1979] Ch. 548 (the case was reversed on the facts in the House of Lords at [1981] 2 W.L.R. 893).

20 Ibid., at pp. 571–572.

21 Ibid., Diplock, J. made the same mistake in the Port Line case: [1958] 2 Q.B. 146, 165.Google Scholar

22 (1853) 2 E. & B. 216.

23 See B.M.T.A. v. Salvadori, n. 17, above.

24 See D. C. Thomson Ltd. v. Deakin [1952] Ch. 646, 680Google Scholar, per Evershed, M.R. (cf. per Upjohn, J. at p. 663)Google Scholar; Torquay Hotel Co. Ltd. v. Cousins [1969] 2 Ch. 106, 138, per Lord, Denning M.R.Google Scholar; Heydon, , Economic Torts, 2nd ed., p. 32.Google ScholarCf. Leitch v. Leydon, 1931 S.C.(H.L.) 1, 8, per Dunedin, Lord.Google Scholar

25 Compare the rule that an equitable assignee of a chose in action, despite the rule in Dearie v. Hail, always takes subject to previous equitable assignments (which may include promises to assign) of which he has notice. See Spencer v. Clarke (1878) 9 Ch.D. 137.Google Scholar

26 [1980] 3 W.L.R. 457.

27 Ibid., at p. 470.

28 This was quite apart from the question of notice, where the court agreed with Browne-Wilkinson J.

29 [1981] 2 W.L.R. 893.

30 See now the Patents Act 1977, s. 60 (1) (a). But sale of goods without overt restriction implies permission to use—e.g., Betti v. Willmott (1871) L.R. 6 Ch.App. 239 (esp. per Lord Hatherley at p. 245).Google Scholar

31 (1895) 12 R.P.C. 262.

32 See now the Patents Act 1977, s. 60 (1) (a).

33 (stc) (1922) 39 R.P.C. 239.

34 This is the effect of the Resale Prices Act 1976, ss. 9–10.

35 Patents Act 1977, s. 44 (re-enacting the Patents Act 1949, s. 57).

36 See, e.g.. Sterling Drug Co. v. C. H. Beck [1972] F.S.R. 529.Google Scholar

37 American courts have reached the same result even in the absence of specific provision—Coca-Cola Bottling Co. v. Bennett, 238 F. 513 (1916).Google Scholar

38 See Goode, R. M., Hire Purchase Law and Practice, 2nd ed. p. 35Google Scholar; Thornely, J. W. A. (1974) 13 J.S.P.T.L. 150, 151Google Scholar; Palmer, N. E., Bailment, p. 973.Google Scholar

39 As lucidly argued in Goode, R. M., Hire Purchase Law and Practice, n. 38 above.Google Scholar

40 Interestingly enough, cases in land law concerning whether licences are binding on third parties have normally involved licensees in possession: e.g., Erringlon v. Erringlon & Woods [1952] 1 K.B. 290Google Scholar; Binions v. Evans [1972] Ch. 359.Google Scholar Furthermore, the more notorious cases where such licensees have not prevailed over purchasers have often involved licensees without possession—see, e.g., Clore v. Theatrical Properties [1936] 3 All E.R. 483Google Scholar; King v. David Allen (Billposting) Ltd. [1916] 2 A.C. 54.Google Scholar

41 Cf. the rule in conversion, that a hire-purchaser who converts goods is liable to the owner only for the unpaid balance of the price; to the extent that he has paid, he had an interest in the goods. See Wickham Holdings v. Brooke House Motors [1967] 1 W.L.R. 295.Google Scholar

42 Compare the parallel question, raised in cases such as Britain & Overseas Trading (Bristles) Ltd. v. Brooks Wharf [1967] 2 Lloyd's Rep. 51Google Scholar, whether a purchaser of goods bailed to a third party is bound by any terms in the original contract limiting the bailee's liability. The present author has suggested that he is, on analogous reasoning to that in the text: see (1978) 29 N.I.L.Q. 40.