Hostname: page-component-7479d7b7d-q6k6v Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-10T19:07:33.310Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Political Representation in Concentrated Industries: Revisiting the “Olsonian Hypothesis”

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 January 2017

David M. Hart*
Affiliation:
Harvard University
*
Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, 79 John F. Kennedy, Cambridge, MA 02138, USA. E-mail: david_hart@harvard.edu

Abstract

This paper considers whether highly concentrated industries are better represented in the political process, as Olson's Logic of Collective Action suggests, and, if they are, whether this is so for the reasons that the Logic claims. It begins with a review and critique of the quantitative literature that has largely tried and failed to substantiate Olson's view. The bulk of the paper consists of five longitudinal case studies of firms that dominate or have dominated industries: IBM, Intel, Microsoft, America Online, and Cisco. The cases suggest that there is merit to the Olsonian view, but that alone it does not constitute an adequate political theory of the concentrated industry or the dominant firm. Additional variables drawn from organizational and institutional theory need to be incorporated into such a theory, including variables that bear on the allocation of attention, threat perception, and information flow within dominant firms.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © V.K. Aggarwal 2003 and published under exclusive license to Cambridge University Press 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Ansolabehere, Stephen, Snyder, James M. and Tripathi, Micky. 2002. ‘Are PAC Contributions and Lobbying Linked? New Evidence from the 1995 Lobbying Disclosure Act.’ Business and Politics 4: 131156.Google Scholar
Bank, David. 2001. Breaking Windows: How Bill Gates Fumbled the Future of Microsoft. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Bauer, Raymond, de Sola Pool, Ithiel and Anthony Dexter, Lewis. 1972. American Business, Public Policy, and the Politics of Foreign Trade, 2nd edn. Chicago, IL: Aldine-Atherton.Google Scholar
Baumgartner, Frank R. and Leech, Beth L. 1999. ‘The Business Advantage in the Washington Lobbying Community: Evidence from the 1996 Lobbying Disclosure Reports.’ Midwest Political Science Association.Google Scholar
Baumgartner, Frank R. and Leech, Beth L. 1998. Basic Interests: The Importance of Groups in Politics and Political Science. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Betts, Mitch. 1988. ‘Software Firms Unite, Aim to Keelhaul Pirates.’ Computerworld 17 October.Google Scholar
Bridis, Ted. 2000. ‘Intel Chairman Says He Favors Sales Tax on Internet Purchases.’ Wall Street Journal 7 June: B6.Google Scholar
Chandler, Alfred D. 1993. Inventing the Electronic Century. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Coen, David. 1999. ‘The Impact of US Lobbying Practices on the European Business-Government Relationship.’ California Management Review Summer: 2744.Google Scholar
Crabtree, Susan. 2000. ‘Culture Clash Affects Merger.’ Roll Call 9 March.Google Scholar
Cyert, Richard M. and March, James G. 1963. The Behavioral Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Damania, R. and Fredriksson, P.G. 2000. ‘On the Formation of Industry Lobby Groups.’ Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 41: 315335.Google Scholar
DiMaggio, Paul J. and Powell, Walter W. 1983. ‘The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields.’ American Sociological Review 48: 147160.Google Scholar
Eckstein, Harry. 1975. ‘Case Study and Theory in Political Science.’ In: Handbook of Political Science, Volume 7, edited by Greenstein, Fred I. and Polsby, Nelson W. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley: 79137.Google Scholar
Eilperin, Juliet. 1997. ‘High-Tech Lobbying: Microsoft Steps Up Effort.’ Roll Call 27 October 27.Google Scholar
Epstein, Edwin M. 1969. The Corporation in American Politics. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Esty, Daniel C. and Caves, Richard E. 1983. ‘Market Structure and Political Influence: New Data on Political Expenditures, Activity, and Success.’ Economic Inquiry 21: 2438.Google Scholar
Fligstein, Neil H. 1990. The Transformation of Corporate Control. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Garr, Doug. 1999. IBM Redux. New York: Harper Business.Google Scholar
Godwin, R. Kenneth and Seldon, Barry J. 2002. ‘What Corporations Really Want from Government: The Public Provision of Private Goods.’ In Interest Group Politics, 6th edn., edited by Cigler, Allan J. and Loomis, Burdett. CQ Press.Google Scholar
Governmental Programs at IBM. Harvard Business School case 8-389-109 (1988).Google Scholar
Gray, Virginia and Lowery, David. 1997. ‘Reconceptualizing PAC Formation: it's not a Collective Action Problem and it may be an Arms Race.’ American Politics Quarterly 25: 319346.Google Scholar
Grier, Kevin B., Munger, Michael C. and Roberts, Brian E. 1991. ‘The Industrial Organization of Corporate Political Participation.’ Southern Economic Journal 57: 727738.Google Scholar
Grier, Kevin B., Munger, Michael C. and Roberts, Brian E. 1994. ‘The Determinants of Industrial Political Activity, 1978–1986.’ American Political Science Review 88: 911926.Google Scholar
Grossman, Gene M. and Helpman, Elhanan. 1994. ‘Protection for Sale.’ American Economic Review 84: 833850.Google Scholar
Grove, Andrew S. 1996. Only the Paranoid Survive. New York: Currency.Google Scholar
Hansen, Wendy L. and Mitchell, Neil J. 2000. ‘Disaggregating and Explaining Corporate Political Activity: Domestic and Foreign Corporations in National Politics.’ American Political Science Review 94: 891903.Google Scholar
Heilemann, John. 2000. ‘The Truth, the Whole Truth, and Nothing But the Truth: The Untold Story of the Microsoft Case.’ Wired November: 260311.Google Scholar
Inclan, Carla, Quinn, Dennis P. and Shapiro, Robert Y. 1991. ‘Origins and Consequences of Changes in US Corporate Taxation.’ American Journal of Political Science 45: 179201.Google Scholar
Inside Washington.’ National Journal, 19 December 1998, 2967.Google Scholar
Intel Corporation. 1993. ‘Defining Intel: 25 Years/25 Events.Google Scholar
Keller, Amy. 1999. ‘Microsoft Takes D.C. to Washington.’ Roll Call 15 November.Google Scholar
Krugman, Paul. 2002. ‘Clueless in Crawford.’ New York Times 13 August: A19.Google Scholar
Lacey, Marc and Schmitt, Eric. 2000. ‘Gates Keeps Washington Dates.’ New York Times 6 April: D1.Google Scholar
Levi, Margaret. 1988. Of Rule and Revenue. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Lichtenberg, Frank R. 1989. ‘Contributions to Federal Elections Campaigns by Government Contractors.’ Journal of Industrial Economics 38: 3148.Google Scholar
Mao, Wen and Zaleski, Peter. 2001. ‘The Effect of Industry Concentration on Free Riding.’ Review of Industrial Organization 19: 295303.Google Scholar
Martin, Cathie J. 2000. Stuck in Neutral: Business and the Politics of Human Capital Investment Policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Miles, Sara. 2001. How To Hack a Party Line: The Democrats and Silicon Valley. New York: Farrar, Straus, & Giroux.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Neil J., Hansen, Wendy L. and Jepsen, Eric M. 1997. ‘The Determinants of Domestic and Foreign Corporate Political Activity.’ Journal of Politics 59: 10961113.Google Scholar
Mitra, Devasish. 1999. ‘Endogenous Lobby Formation and Endogenous Protection: A Long-Run Model of Trade Policy Determination.’ American Economic Review 89: 11161134.Google Scholar
Moore, W. John. 1998. ‘Ganging Up on Microsoft.’ National Journal 7 February: 301.Google Scholar
Mundo, Philip A. 1992. ‘Semiconductor Industry Association.’ In Interest Groups: Cases and Characteristics. Chicago: 4166.Google Scholar
Munro, Neil. 1998. ‘Cisco Puts Money, Effort in Lobbying, Working with DC Trade Groups.’ National Journal 3 October: 2325.Google Scholar
Munro, Neil. 1999. ‘Building a Case.’ National Journal 31 July: 2218.Google Scholar
Newman, Barry. 1972. ‘Churches Mount First Joint Campaign Against US Firms in Southern Africa.’ Wall Street Journal 15 February.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1982. The Rise and Decline of Nations. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur and Zeckhauser, Richard. 1966. ‘An Economic Theory of Alliances.’ Review of Economics and Statistics 48: 266279.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the Commons: Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Mary Ann. 2000. ‘Gore Maintains Lead with California Voters.’ San Jose Mercury-News 20 June.Google Scholar
Pecorino, Paul. 1998. ‘Is There a Free Rider Problem in Lobbying? Endogenous Tariffs, Trigger Strategies, and the Number of Firms.’ American Economic Review 88: 652660.Google Scholar
Pecorino, Paul. 2002. ‘Market Structure, Tariff Lobbying, and the Free Rider Problem.’ Public Choice 106: 203220.Google Scholar
Pittman, Russell J. and Werden, Gregory J. 1990. ‘The Divergence of SIC Industries from Antitrust Markets.’ Economic Letters 33: 283286.Google Scholar
Potters, Jan and Sloof, Randolph. 1996. ‘Interest Groups: A Survey of Empirical Models that Try to Assess Their Influence.’ European Journal of Political Economy 12: 403442.Google Scholar
Quinn, Dennis P. and Shapiro, Robert Y. 1991. ‘Business Political Power: The Case of Taxation.’ American Political Science Review 85: 851874.Google Scholar
Rehbein, Kathleen and Schuler, Douglas A. 1999. ‘Testing the Firm as a Filter of Corporate Political Action.’ Business and Society 38: 144166.Google Scholar
Rodrik, Dani. 1995. ‘The Political Economy of Trade Policy.’ In Handbook of International Economics, vol. 3, edited by Grossman, Gene and Rogoff, Kenneth. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science: 14581494.Google Scholar
Roeder, Edward. ‘Declaration,’ U.S. v. Microsoft, civil action 98–1232, US District Court for the District of Columbia.Google Scholar
Rohm, Wendy Goldman. 1998. The Microsoft File: The Secret Case Against Bill Gates. New York: Times Books.Google Scholar
Salisbury, Robert H. 1984. ‘Interest Representation: The Dominance of Institutions.’ American Political Science Review 78: 6476.Google Scholar
Sarasohn, Judy. 2000. ‘Microsoft's Image Operators.’ Washington Post 23 March: A27.Google Scholar
Schattschneider, E.E. 1960. The Semi-Sovereign People. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston.Google Scholar
Schlender, Brent. 1998. ‘An Interview with Gates,’ Fortune 8 June: 152.Google Scholar
Schlender, Brenton R. 1987. ‘Software Hardball: Microsoft's Gates Uses Products and Pressure To Gain Power in PCs.’ Wall Street Journal 25 September.Google Scholar
Schuler, Douglas A. 1999. ‘Corporate Political Action: Rethinking the Economic and Organizational InfluencesBusiness and Politics 1: 8397.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1942. Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Scott, Thurm. 2000. ‘Safe Conduct: Microsoft's Behavior Is Helping Cisco Avoid Antitrust Trouble.’ Wall Street Journal 1 June: A1.Google Scholar
Segal, David. 1999. ‘FTC Cancels Probe of Cisco's Talks With Rivals,’ Washington Post 2 June: E2.Google Scholar
Shapiro, Carl and Varian, Hal R. 1999. Information Rules. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Slovic, Paul, Fischhoff, Baruch and Lichtenstein, Sarah. 1979. ‘Rating the Risks.’ Environment 21 (3): 1420, 36–39.Google Scholar
Stokes, Bruce. 1990. ‘Sematech Chief's Personal Magnetism.’ National Journal 26 May.Google Scholar
Swisher, Kara. 1998. AOL.com. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
van Winden, Fran. 1999. ‘On the Economic Theory of Interest Groups.’ Public Choice 100: 129.Google Scholar
Vandehei, Jim. 1999. ‘Microsoft Plans to Boost Lobbying Presence on Hill.’ Roll Call 11 November.Google Scholar
Vogel, David J. 1996. ‘The Study of Business and Politics.’ California Management Review 38: 146165.Google Scholar
Watson, Thomas J. Jr. and Petre, Peter. 1990. Father, Son, and Company. New York.Google Scholar
Watts, Chris. 1997. ‘Proposition 211.’ Stanford University, Graduate School of Business case S-P-23, October.Google Scholar
Williams, John T. and Collins, Brian K. 1997. ‘The Political Economy of Corporate Taxation.’ American Journal of Political Science 41: 208244.Google Scholar
Zardkoohi, Asghar. 1985. ‘On the Political Participation of the Firm in the Electoral Process.’ Southern Economic Journal 51: 804817.Google Scholar