Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-cjp7w Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-22T08:18:54.092Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Nudges, regulations, and behavioral public choice

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  30 August 2023

Samuel G. B. Johnson
Affiliation:
Department of Psychology, University of Waterloo, Waterloo, ON, Canada. samuel.johnson@uwaterloo.ca; http://www.sgbjohnson.com/ School of Management, University of Bath, Bath, UK Department of Psychology, University of Warwick, Coventry, UK
Jason Dana
Affiliation:
School of Management, Yale University, New Haven, CT, USA; jason.dana@yale.edu; https://som.yale.edu/faculty-research/faculty-directory/jason-dana

Abstract

Chater & Loewenstein have done a service to the field by raising the fundamental issue of how the political process distorts well-intentioned efforts at behavioral public policy. We connect this argument to broader research on government failure, particularly public choice theory in economics. We further suggest ways that behavioral research can help identify and mitigate such failures.

Type
Open Peer Commentary
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Bhattacharjee, A., Dana, J., & Baron, J. (2017). Anti-profit beliefs: How people neglect the societal benefits of profit. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 113, 671696.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Brennan, J. (2016). Against democracy. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent: Logical foundations of constitutional democracy. University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Caplan, B. (2007). The myth of the rational voter: Why democracies choose bad policies. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. Harper & Brothers.Google Scholar
Elliot, J., & Kiel, P. (2019). Inside TurboTax's 20-year fight to stop Americans from filing their taxes for free. ProPublica. https://www.propublica.org/article/inside-turbotax-20-year-fight-to-stop-americans-from-filing-their-taxes-for-freeGoogle Scholar
Franck, C., Grandi, S. M., & Eisenberg, M. J. (2013). Agricultural subsidies and the American obesity epidemic. American Journal of Preventive Medicine, 45, 327333.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Jamison, P., Zahniser, D., & Reyes, E. A. (2105). L.A. labor leaders seek minimum wage exemption for firms with union workers. Los Angeles Times. https://www.latimes.com/local/lanow/la-me-ln-los-angeles-minimum-wage-unions-20150526-story.htmlGoogle Scholar
Johnson, S. G. B., & Nagatsu, M. (2023). Structural and psychological explanation in folk and scientific economics. In Schupbach, J. N. & Glass, D. H. (Eds.), Conjunctive explanations: New essays on the nature, epistemology, and psychology of explanatory multiplicity (pp. 4983). Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, S. G. B., Zhang, J., & Keil, F. C. (2022). Win–win denial: The psychological underpinnings of zero-sum thinking. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 151, 455474.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Jolls, C., Sunstein, C. R., & Thaler, R. (1998). A behavioral approach to law and economics. Stanford Law Review, 50, 14711550.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahan, D. M., & Braman, D. (2006). Cultural cognition and public policy. Yale Law & Policy Review, 24, 147170.Google Scholar
Khon, Z., Johnson, S. G. B., & Hang, H. (2020). Lay theories of manipulation: Do consumers believe they are susceptible to marketers’ trickery? Working paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lerner, J. S., & Tetlock, P. E. (1999). Accounting for the effects of accountability. Psychological Bulletin, 125(2), 255275.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lucas, G., & Tasic, S. (2015). Behavioral public choice and the law. West Virginia Law Review, 118, 199266.Google Scholar
Maynard, M. (2008). Did ending regulation help fliers? The New York Times. https://www.nytimes.com/2008/04/17/business/17air.htmlGoogle Scholar
Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public choice III. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Pollack, A. (2015). Drug goes from $13.50 a tablet to $750, overnight. The New York Times. https://www.nytimes.com/2015/09/21/business/a-huge-overnight-increase-in-a-drugs-price-raises-protests.htmlGoogle Scholar
Polman, E., & Wu, K. (2020). Decision making for others involving risk: A review and meta-analysis. Journal of Economic Psychology, 77, 102184.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2, 321.Google Scholar
Sunstein, C. R. (2016). People prefer system 2 nudges (kind of). Duke Law Journal, 66, 121168.Google Scholar
Thomas, M. D. (2019). Reapplying behavioral symmetry: Public choice and choice architecture. Public Choice, 180, 1125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Viscusi, W. K., & Gayer, T. (2015). Behavioral public choice: The behavioral paradox of government policy. Harvard Journal of Law & Public Policy, 38, 9731007.Google Scholar