Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-pjpqr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-07T01:55:28.037Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

A Note on the Efficiency of Income Redistribution with Simple and Combined Policies

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 September 2016

David S. Bullock
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural and Consumer Economics, University of Illinois
Klaus Salhofer
Affiliation:
Universität für Bodenkultur Wien, Department of Economics, Politics, and Law, Vienna, Austria
Get access

Abstract

Recent studies have investigated the efficiencies of policies that use several policy instruments simultaneously (for example, a policy that uses a production subsidy combined with a production quota). Several studies of very specific cases find that optimal combination of two policy instruments is more efficient than optimal independent use of either. In this note we demonstrate using set theory and maximization theory, that all such specific results are examples of a more general result, which is that by combining m instruments efficiently, a government can always be at least as efficient as when using a subset of those m instruments. This result holds for any of the several definitions of “efficiency” in the literature.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © 1998 Northeastern Agricultural and Resource Economics Association 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alston, J.M., and Hurd, B.H. 1990. “Some Neglected Social Costs of Government Spending in Farm Programs.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 72: 149–56.Google Scholar
Alston, J.M., Carter, C.A., and Smith, V.H. 1993. “Rationalizing Agricultural Export Subsidies.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 75: 10001009.Google Scholar
Alston, J.M., Carter, C.A., and Smith, V.H. 1995. “Rationalizing Agricultural Export Subsidies: Reply.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77: 209–13.Google Scholar
de Gorter, H., and Swinnen, J.F.M. 1992. Can Price Support Negate the Social Gains from Public Research Expenditures in Agriculture. Working Paper 94-06. Department of Agricultural, Resource, and Managerial Economics, Cornell University. June.Google Scholar
de Gorter, H., Nielson, D.J., and Rausser, G.C. 1992. “Productive and Predatory Public Policies: Research Expenditures and Producer Subsidies in Agriculture.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 74: 2737.Google Scholar
Gardner, B.L. 1988. “Export Policy, Deficiency Payments, and a Consumption Tax.” Journal of Agricultural Economics Research 40: 1719.Google Scholar
Gardner, B.L. 1992. Price Supports and Optimal Spending. Working Paper no. 92-20. Department of Agricultural and Research Economics, University of Maryland. November.Google Scholar
Gisser, M. 1993. “Price Support, Acreage Controls, and Efficient Redistribution.” Journal of Political Economy 101: 584611.Google Scholar
Guyomard, H., and Mahé, L.-P. 1994. “Is a Production Quota Pareto Superior to Price Support Only?European Review of Agricultural Economics 21(1): 3136.Google Scholar
Innes, R. 1990. “Uncertainty, Incomplete Markets and Government Farm Programs.” Southern Journal of Economics 57: 4765.Google Scholar
Innes, R.D., and Rausser, G.C. 1989. “Incomplete Markets and Government Agricultural Policy.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 71: 915–31.Google Scholar
Just, R.E. 1984. Automatic Adjustment Rules for Agricultural Policy Controls. AEI Occasional Papers. Washington D.C.: American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research.Google Scholar
Nerlove, M. 1958. The Dynamic of Supply. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press.Google Scholar
Tweeten, L., and Coggins, J. 1992. “Political Preference Functions and Agricultural Policy Reform: Comment.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 71: 717–29.Google Scholar
Wallace, T.D. 1962. “Measures of Social Costs of Agricultural Programs.” Journal of Farm Economics 44: 580–94.Google Scholar