Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-5c6d5d7d68-xq9c7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-09-01T11:28:24.814Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

13 - VINTAGE MODELS AND FIXED PROPORTIONS IN NEOCLASSICAL THEORY

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 October 2011

Get access

Summary

Introduction

To some extent, ‘technological progress’ can occur in the absence of gross investment. In the models treated in chapters 11 and 12, technological progress was strictly of this ‘disembodied’ type. Other innovations require only small modifications of existing capital equipment and, therefore, negligible capital expenditures. However, certain innovations can be introduced only by scrapping old capital equipment and replacing it by new capital equipment that ‘embodies’ the new technology. Such changes in technology are brought about only by significant gross investment.

One may add to this ‘fact’ another ‘fact’ of some importance: once a piece of capital equipment has been installed, there is often very little scope for factor substitution, certainly not the scope posited in the ‘neoclassical fairy tale’. Two questions immediately arise. First, if capital equipment existing at a given moment is in fact heterogeneous, is it possible to define a capital aggregate such as that used in simple neoclassical theory? Second, if machine operation requires fixed or almost-fixed proportions, can one deduce the marginal equivalences upon which neoclassical theory rests?

The first question, while long recognized, was explicitly posed in 1953 by Mrs Robinson and Champernowne. Solow provided the answer. If a production function involves more than one kind of capital good, it can be written in terms of a capital aggregate if the production function satisfies the condition of Leontief's theorem on separable functions. In this context, the Leontief theorem requires that the marginal rate of technical substitution between different types of capital equipment be independent of the amount of labor used. This, of course, is a very restrictive condition.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 1969

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×