Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-5c6d5d7d68-thh2z Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-08-09T02:10:29.880Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

6 - Are successful parents the secret to success?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 September 2009

Erik Plug
Affiliation:
Senior Researcher University of Amsterdam
Joop Hartog
Affiliation:
Universiteit van Amsterdam
Henriëtte Maassen van den Brink
Affiliation:
Universiteit van Amsterdam
Get access

Summary

Introduction

Almost all studies, varying over countries and times, show that when parents are rich and better educated their children tend to receive more schooling and income as well. In the United States, for example, intergenerational correlations of schooling and earnings are close to 0.4 (Solon 1992). And even in Sweden, where education is heavily subsidized, the intergenerational correlations are substantial and move between 0.2 and 0.3 (Björklund and Jäntti, 1997). Recently Haveman and Wolfe (1995) reviewed the mobility literature and came to the conclusion that the human capital of parents, typically measured by the number of years of schooling attained, is the most fundamental factor in explaining the child's success in school. Apparently the evidence on family background is quite persuasive: if you want to be successful, just have successful parents.

But if parents are indeed the secret to success, does this mean that if we – or policy-makers for that matter – make people more successful, their future children will do better as well? This question will serve as the outline of this chapter. Answers will not come easily as our understanding of why successful parents have successful children is at most tentative (Solon, 1999). There could be many family factors at work. Are, for example, parental abilities responsible for economic success passed on genetically to the next generation? Or are better-educated and richer parents better in providing an intellectually stimulating environment for their children? Or do poorer parents face credit constraints when financing their children's education?

Type
Chapter
Information
Human Capital
Advances in Theory and Evidence
, pp. 81 - 98
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2007

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Antonovics, Kate and Goldberger, Arthur (2005). Does increasing women's schooling raise the schooling of the next generation? Comment. American Economic Review, 95: 1738–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ashenfelter, Orley and Cecilia Rouse (1999). Schooling, intelligence, and income in America: cracks in the Bell Curve. NBER Working Paper 6902. Cambridge, MACrossRef
Becker, Gary and Tomes, Nigel (1986). Human capital and the rise and fall of families. Journal of Labor Economics, 4: 1–39.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Behrman, Jere and Rosenzweig, Mark (2002). Does increasing women's schooling raise the schooling of the next generation? American Economic Review, 92: 323–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Björklund, Anders and Jäntti, Markus (1997). Intergenerational income mobility in Sweden compared to the United States. American Economic Review, 87: 1009–18.Google Scholar
Björklund, Anders, Mikael Lindahl and Erik Plug (2004). Intergenerational effects in Sweden: what can we learn from adoption data? IZA Working Paper 1194, Bonn.
Black, Sandra, Devereux, Paul and Salvanes, Kjell (2005). Why the apple doesn't fall far: understanding intergenerational transmission of human capital. American Economic Review, 95: 437–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cawley, John, Heckman, James and Vytlacil, Edward (1999). Meritocracy in America: an examination of wages within and across occupations. Industrial Relations, 38: 250–96.Google Scholar
Chevalier, Arnaud (2004). Parental education and child's education: a natural experiment. IZA Working Paper 1153, Bonn.
Currie, Janet and Thomas, Duncan (1999). The intergenerational transmission of intelligence: down the slippery slopes of the Bell Curve. Industrial Relations, 38: 297–330.Google Scholar
Goldberger, Arthur and Manski, Charles (1995). Review article: The Bell Curve by Herrnstein and Murray. Journal of Economic Literature, 33: 762–76.Google Scholar
Griliches, Zvi (1997). Estimating the returns to schooling: some econometric problems. Econometrica, 45: 1–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haveman, Robert and Wolfe, Barbara (1995). The determinants of children attainments: a review of methods and findings. Journal of Economic Literature, 33: 1829–78.Google Scholar
Heckman, James and Hotz, Joseph (1986). The sources of inequality for males in Panama's labor market. Journal of Human Resources, 42: 507–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herrnstein, Richard (1973). IQ in the Meritocracy. Boston: Little Brown.Google Scholar
Herrnstein, Richard and Murray, Charles (1994). The Bell Curve: Intelligence and Class Structure in American Life. New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Hill, Anne and Elizabeth, King (1995). Women's education and women's well-being. Feminist Economics, 1: 21–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jencks, Christopher (1972). Inequality: A Reassessment of the Effects of Family and Schooling in America. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Jensen, Arthur R. (1973). Genetics and Education. New York: Methuen.Google Scholar
Korenman, Sanders and Christopher Winship (2000). A reanalysis of The Bell Curve: intelligence, family background, and schooling, in Arrow, Kenneth, Bowles, Samuel and Durlauf, Stephen (eds.), Meritocracy and Economic Inequality. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Oreopoulos, Philip, Marianne Page and Anne Hu Stevens (2003). Does human capital transfer from parent to child? The intergenerational effects of compulsory schooling. NBER Working Paper 10164, Cambridge, MA.CrossRef
Plug, Erik (2004). Estimating the effect of mother's schooling on children's schooling using a sample of adoptees. American Economic Review, 94: 358–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Plug, Erik and Vijverberg, Wim (2003). Schooling, family background, and adoption: is it nature or is it nurture? Journal of Political Economy, 111: 611–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Plug, Erik and Vijverberg, Wim(2005). Does family income matter for schooling outcomes? Using adoption as a natural experiment. Economic Journal, 115: 879–906.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sacerdote, Bruce (2000). The nature and nurture of economic outcomes. NBER Working Paper 7949, Cambridge, MA.CrossRef
Sewell, William H. and Robert M. Hauser (1992). A review of the Wisconsin Longitudinal Study of social and psychological factors in aspiration and achievement, 1963–1993. Center for Demography and Ecology, Working Paper 92–01, University of Wisconsin-Madison.
Solon, Gary (1992). Intergenerational income mobility in the United States. American Economic Review, 82: 393–408.Google Scholar
Solon, Gary(1999). Intergenerational mobility in the labor market, in Ashenfelter, Orley and David Card (eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics, vol. III. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×