Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-7479d7b7d-t6hkb Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-11T06:27:33.259Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

5 - Decomposition and growth: biological metaphors in economics from the 1880s to the 1980s

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 September 2009

Geoffrey M. Hodgson
Affiliation:
Professor of Economics, University of Hertfordshire Business School, Hertford, Herts, United Kingdom
Kurt Dopfer
Affiliation:
Universität St Gallen, Switzerland
Get access

Summary

Introduction

In economics, the word ‘evolutionary’ is currently in fashion. Since the 1980s the number of economics books and articles with ‘evolution’ in their title has increased rapidly. This revolution is not confined to heterodoxy. Leading neoclassical economists such as Kenneth Arrow and Frank Hahn have turned away from mechanics, seeing biology as the possible inspiration for the economics of the future (Anderson, 1995; Arrow 1995; Hahn, 1991, p. 48).

The relationship between biology and economics has waxed and waned over the centuries and has worked in both directions. The influence of the economists Adam Smith and Thomas Robert Malthus on Charles Darwin is widely known, even if some of the details remain controversial (Hodgson, 1993b, 1995). Ideas of competition and struggle in the writings of Smith and Malthus simultaneously inspired economics and biology. Accordingly, to some degree, biological metaphors have always been present in the foreground or background of modern economic theory. What is striking, however, is the temporal variation in the degree of their explicit popularity and use.

With the emergence of neoclassical economics in the 1870s, its principal inspiration was not biology but physics (Mirowski, 1989; Ingrao and Israel, 1990). Yet by the end of the nineteenth century the picture in economics was again modified. Alfred Marshall wrote that ‘the Mecca of the economist lies in economic biology’ (Marshall, 1890, p. xiv). Furthermore, leading heterodox economists such as Thorstein Veblen enthusiastically embraced biology.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2005

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alchian, A. A. (1950), ‘Uncertainty, evolution and economic theory’, Journal of Political Economy 58 (3): 211–21. [Reprinted in Witt (1993).]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alland, A., Jr. (1967), Evolution and Human Behavior, New York: Natural History Press
Allen, P. M., and M. Lesser (1991), ‘Evolutionary human systems: learning, ignorance and subjectivity’, in P. P. Saviotti and J. S. Metcalfe (eds.), Evolutionary Theories of Economic and Technological Change: Present Status and Future Prospects, Reading: Harwood, 160–71
Anderson, P. W. (1995), ‘Viewpoint: the future’, Science 267, 17 March, 1617–18CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, K. J. (1995), ‘Viewpoint: the future’, Science 267, 17 March, 1617CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arthur, W. B. (1989), ‘Competing technologies, increasing returns and lock-in by historical events’, Economic Journal 394: 116–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ayres, C. E. (1921), ‘Instinct and capacity – Ⅰ: the instinct of belief-in-instincts’, Journal of Philosophy 18(21): 561–65CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ayres, C. E. (1935), ‘Moral confusion in economics’, International Journal of Ethics 45: 170–99. [Reprinted in W. Samuels (ed.) (1988), Institutional Economics, Aldershot: Edward Elgar, vol. 2.]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ayres, C. E. (1944), The Theory of Economic Progress, Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina Press
Ayres, C. E. (1952), The Industrial Economy, Cambridge, MA: Houghton Mifflin
Ayres, C. E. (1958), ‘Veblen's theory of instincts reconsidered’, in D. F. Dowd (ed.), Thorstein Veblen: A Critical Appraisal, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 25–37
Ayres, C. E. (1961), Toward a Reasonable Society: The Values of Industrial Civilization, Austin, TX: University of Texas Press
Barber, W. J. (1994), ‘The divergent fates of two strands of “Institutionalist” doctrine during the New Deal years’, History of Political Economy 26(4): 569–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1976), ‘Altruism, egoism, and genetic fitness: economics and sociobiology’, Journal of Economic Literature 14(2): 817–26. [Reprinted in Hodgson (1995).]Google Scholar
Bellomy, D. C. (1984), ‘Social Darwinism revisited’, Perspectives in American History, New Series, 1: 1–129Google Scholar
Bhaskar, R. (1975), A Realist Theory of Science, Leeds: Leeds Books. [2nd edn., 1978, Brighton: Harvester.]
Bhaskar, R. (1979), The Possibility of Naturalism: A Philosophic Critique of the Contemporary Human Sciences, Brighton: Harvester
Biddle, J. E. (1996), ‘A citation analysis of the sources and extent of Wesley Mitchell's reputation’, History of Political Economy 28(2): 137–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, M. (1962), Models and Metaphors: Studies in Language and Philosophy, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press
Boulding, K. E. (1950), A Reconstruction of Economics, New York: Wiley
Boulding, K. E. (1978), Ecodynamics: A New Theory of Societal Evolution, Beverly Hills and London: Sage
Boulding, K. E. (1981), Evolutionary Economics, Beverly Hills and London: Sage
Bowler, P. J. (1983), The Eclipse of Darwinism: Anti-Darwinian Evolution Theories in the Decades around 1900, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press
Boyd, R., and Richerson, P. J. (1980), ‘Sociobiology, culture and economic theory’, Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization 1 (1): 97–121. [Reprinted in Witt (1993).]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burrow, J. W. (1966), Evolution and Society: A Study of Victorian Social Theory, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
Burt, C. (1962), ‘The concept of consciousness’, British Journal of Psychology 53: 229–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camic, Charles (1986), ‘The matter of habit’, American Journal of Sociology, 91(5): 1039–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, D. T. (1965), ‘Variation and selective retention in socio-cultural evolution’, in H. Barringer, G. I. Blanksten and R. W. Mack (eds.), Social Change in Developing Areas: a Reinterpreation of Evolutionary Theory, Cambridge, MA: Schenkman Publishing Co., 19–47
Chomsky, N. (1959), ‘Review of Verbal Behavior by B. F. Skinner’, Language 35: 26–58CrossRef
Clark, J. B. (1885), The Philosophy of Wealth: Economic Principles Newly Formulated, London and New York: Macmillan
Commons, J. R. (1934), Institutional Economics – Its Place in Political Economy, New York: Macmillan. [Reprinted in 1990 with a new introduction by M. Rutherford, New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction.]
Copeland, M. A. (1931), ‘Economic theory and the natural science point of view’, American Economic Review 21 (1): 67–79. [Reprinted in W. Samuels (ed.) (1988), Institutional Economics, vol. 2, Aldershot: Edward Elgar.]Google Scholar
Copeland, M. A. (1958), ‘On the scope and method of economics’, in D. F. Dowd (ed.), Thorstein Veblen: A Critical Appraisal, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 57–75. [Reprinted in Hodgson (1995).]
Copeland, M. A. (1981), Essays in Socioeconomic Evolution, New York: Vantage Press
David, P. A. (1985), ‘Clio and the economics of QWERTY’, American Economic Review 75(2): 332–37Google Scholar
Degler, C. N. (1991), In Search of Human Nature: The Decline and Revival of Darwinism in American Social Thought, Oxford: Oxford University Press
Depew, D. J., and B. H. Weber (1995), Darwinism Evolving: Systems Dynamics and the Genealogy of Natural Selection, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press
Dillard, D. (1948), The Economics of John Maynard Keynes: The Theory of a Monetary Economy, London: Crosby Lockwood
Dobzhansky, T. (1955), Evolution, Genetics and Man, London: Wiley
Downie, J. (1958), The Competitive Process, London: Duckworth
Durkheim, E. (1984), The Division of Labour in Society, translated from the French edition of 1893 by W. D. Halls with an introduction by L. Coser, London: Macmillan
Edgell, S. (1975), ‘Thorstein Veblen's theory of evolutionary change’, American Journal of Economics and Sociology 34(July): 267–80CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ely, R. T. (1903), Studies in the Evolution of Industrial Society, New York: Macmillan
Enke, S. (1951), ‘On maximizing profits: a distinction between Chamberlin and Robinson’, American Economic Review 41(3): 566–78Google Scholar
Farrell, M. J. (1970), ‘Some elementary selection processes in economics’, Review of Economic Studies 37: 305–19CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fleetwood, S. (1995), Hayek's Political Economy: The Socio-Economics of Order, London: Routledge
Ford, H. J. (1915), The Natural History of the State, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
Foss, N. J. (1991), ‘The suppression of evolutionary approaches in economics: the case of Marshall and monopolistic competition’, Methodus 3(2): 65–72. [Reprinted in Hodgson (1995).]Google Scholar
Foss, N. J. (1994a) ‘Realism and evolutionary economics’, Journal of Social and Evolutionary Systems 17(1): 21–40CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foss, N. J. (1994b) ‘The biological analogy and the theory of the firm: Marshall and monopolistic competition’, Journal of Economic Issues 28(4): 1115–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freeden, M. (ed.) (1988), J. A. Hobson: A Reader, London and Boston: Unwin Hyman
Freeman, C. (ed.) (1990), The Economics of Innovation, Aldershot: Edward Elgar
Friedman, M. (1953), ‘The methodology of positive economics’, in M. Friedman, Essays in Positive Economies, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 3–43
Georgescu-Roegen, N. (1971), The Entropy Law and the Economic Process, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press
Ghiselin, M. T. (1974), The Economy of Nature and the Evolution of Sex, Berkeley: University of California Press
Giddings, F. A. (1896), The Principles of Sociology, New York: Macmillan
Gould, S. J. (1989), Wonderful Life: The Burgess Shale and the Nature of History, New York: Norton
Gowdy, J. M. (1987), ‘Bio-economics: social economy versus the Chicago school’, International Journal of Social Economics 14(1): 32–42. [Reprinted in Hodgson (1995).]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gruchy, A. G. (1948), ‘The philosophical basis of the new Keynesian economics’, International Journal of Ethics 58(4): 235–44Google Scholar
Gruchy, A. G. (1972), Contemporary Economic Thought: The Contribution of Neo-Institutional Economics, London and New York: Macmillan
Haavelmo, T. (1954), A Study in the Theory of Economic Evolution, Amsterdam: North-Holland
Hahn, F. (1991), ‘The next hundred years’, Economic Journal 404: 47–50CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harris, A. L. (1934), ‘Economic evolution: dialectical and Darwinian’, Journal of Political Economy 42(1): 34–79CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1952a), The Sensory Order: An Inquiry into the Foundations of Theoretical Psychology, London: Routledge and Kegan Paul
Hayek, F. A. (1952b), The Counter-Revolution of Science: Studies on the Abuse of Reason, Glencoe, IL: Free Press
Hayek, F. A. (1960), The Constitution of Liberty, London and Chicago: Routledge and Kegan Paul, and University of Chicago Press
Hayek, F. A. (1967a), ‘Notes on the evolution of systems of rules of conduct’, in F. A. Hayek, Studies on Philosophy, Politics and Economics, London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 66–81. [Reprinted in Witt (1993).]
Hayek, F. A. (1967b), Studies on Philosophy, Politics and Economics, London: Routledge and Kegan Paul
Hayek, F. A. (1982), Law, Legislation and Liberty, 3-volume combined edition, London: Routledge and Kegan Paul
Hayek, F. A. (1988), The Fatal Conceit: The Errors of Socialism, the Collected Works of Friedrich August Hayek, vol. 1, edited by W. W. Bartley Ⅲ, London: Routledge
Hejl, P. (1995), ‘The importance of the concepts of “organism” and “evolution” in Emile Durkheim's Division of Social Labor and the influence of Herbert Spencer’, in S. Maasen, E. Mendelsohn and P. Weingart (eds.), Biology as Society, Society as Biology: Metaphors, Sociology of the Sciences Yearbook, vol. 18, Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 155–91
Hennis, W. (1988), Max Weber: Essays in Reconstruction, London: Allen and Unwin
Herbst, J. (1965), The German Historical School in American Scholarship: A Study in the Transfer of Culture, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press
Hesse, M. B. (1966), Models and Analogies in Science, Paris: University of Notre Dame Press
Hirshleifer, J. (1977), ‘Economics from a biological viewpoint’, Journal of Law and Economics 20 (1): 1–52. [Reprinted in Hodgson (1995).]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirshleifer, J. (1978), ‘Natural economy versus political economy’, Journal of Social and Biological Structures 1: 319–37CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirst, P. Q., and P. Woolley (1982), Social Relations and Human Attributes, London: Tavistock
Hobson, J. A. (1929), Wealth and Life: A Study in Values, London: Macmillan
Hodgson, G. M. (1988), Economics and Institutions: A Manifesto for a Modern Institutional Economics, Cambridge: Polity Press
Hodgson, G. M. (1992), ‘Thorstein Veblen and post-Darwinian economics’, Cambridge Journal of Economics 16(3): 285–301Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (1993a), ‘The Mecca of Alfred Marshall’, Economic Journal 417: 406–15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (1993b), Economics and Evolution: Bringing Life Back Into Economics, Cambridge and Ann Arbor, MI: Polity Press and University of Michigan Press
Hodgson, G. M. (1994), ‘Optimization and evolution: Winter's critique of Friedman revisited’, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 18(4): 413–30CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (ed.) (1995), Economics and Biology, Aldershot: Edward Elgar
Hodgson, G. M. (1997), ‘Metaphor and pluralism in economics: mechanics and biology’, in A. Salanti and E. Screpanti (eds.), Pluralism in Economics: New Perspectives in History and Methodology, Aldershot: Edward Elgar, 131–54
Hodgson, G. M. (1999), Evolution and Institutions: On Evolutionary Economics and the Evolution of Economics, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar
Hodgson, G. M. (2001a), ‘Is social evolution Lamarckian or Darwinian?’, in J. Laurent and J. Nightingale (eds.), Darwinism and Evolutionary Economics, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar, 87–118
Hodgson, G. M. (2001b), How Economics Forgot History: The Problem of Historical Specificity in Social Science, London and New York: Routledge
Hofstadter, R. (1959), Social Darwinism in American Thought, rev. edn., New York: Braziller
Hoover, K. D. (1995), ‘Why does methodology matter for economics?’, Economic Journal 430: 715–34CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hunt, E. K. (1975), Property and Prophets: The Evolution of Economic Institutions, New York: M. E. Sharpe
Hutchison, T. W. (1992), Changing Aims in Economics, Oxford: Basil Blackwell
Hutter, M. (1994), ‘Organism as a metaphor in German economic thought’, in P. Mirowski (ed.), Natural Images in Economic Thought: Markets Read in Tooth and Claw, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 289–321CrossRef
Ingrao, B., and G. Israel (1990), The Invisible Hand: Economic Equilibrium in the History of Science, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press
Jackson, W. A. (1995), ‘Naturalism in economics’, Journal of Economic Issues 29(3): 761–80CrossRefGoogle Scholar
James, W. (1893), The Principles of Psychology, 2nd edn. New York: Holt
Joravsky, D. (1970), The Lysenko Affair, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press
Keynes, J. M. (1936), The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, London: Macmillan
Joravsky, D. (1973), The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol. ⅩⅣ, The General Theory and After: Defence and Development, London: Macmillan
Khalil, E. L. (1993), ‘Neoclassical economics and neo-Darwinism: clearing the way for historical thinking’, in R. Blackwell, J. Chatha and E. J. Nell (eds.), Economics as Worldly Philosophy: Essays in Political and Historical Economics in Honour of Robert L. Heilbroner, London: Macmillan, 22–72. [Reprinted in Hodgson (1995).]
Kirman, A. P. (1989), ‘The intrinsic limits of modern economic theory: the emperor has no clothes’, Economic Journal 395: 126–39CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirman, A. P. (1992), ‘Whom or what does the representative individual represent?’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 6(2): 117–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klamer, A., and T. C. Leonard (1994), ‘So what's an economic metaphor?’, in P. Mirowski (ed.), Natural Images in Economic Thought: Markets Read in Tooth and Claw, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 20–51
Knies, K. (1853), Politische Ökonomie vom Standpunkt der geshichtlichen Methode [Political Economy from the Perspective of the Historical Method], Braunschweig: Schwetschke
Knight, F. H. (1952), ‘Institutionalism and empiricism in economics’, American Economic Review 42(2): 45–55Google Scholar
La Vergata, A. (1995), ‘Herbert Spencer: biology, sociology, and cosmic evolution’, in S. Maasen, E. Mendelsohn and P. Weingart (eds.), Biology as Society, Society as Biology: Metaphors, Sociology of the Sciences Yearbook, vol. 18, Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 193–229CrossRef
Lawson, T. (1994), ‘Hayek and realism: a case of continuous transformation’, in M. Colunna, H. Haggemann and O. Hamouda (eds.), Capitalism, Socialism and Knowledge: The Economics of F. A. Hayek, Aldershot: Edward Elgar
Lawson, T. (1997), Economics and Reality, London: Routledge
Lewin, S. B. (1996), ‘Economics and psychology: lessons for our own day from the early twentieth century’, Journal of Economic Literature 34(3): 1293–323Google Scholar
Lilienfeld, P. (1873–81), Gedanken über zur Sozialwissenshaft der Zukunft [Thoughts on the Social Science of the Future], Hamburg
Maasen, S. (1995), ‘Who is afraid of metaphors?’, in S. Maasen, E. Mendelsohn and P. Weingart (eds.), Biology as Society, Society as Biology: Metaphors, Sociology of the Sciences Yearbook, vol. 18, Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 11–35CrossRef
Marshall, A. (1890), Principles of Economics, London: Macmillan. [8th edn., 1920, London: Macmillan. 9th variorum edn., 1961, London: Macmillan.]
Matson, F. W. (1964), The Broken Image, New York: Doubleday
Mayhew, A. (1987), ‘The beginnings of institutionalism’, Journal of Economic Issues 21(3): 971–98CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayhew, A. (1989), ‘Contrasting origins of the two institutionalisms: the social science context’, Review of Political Economy 1(3): 319–33CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maynard Smith, J. (1982), Evolution and the Theory of Games, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
Mayr, E. (1980), ‘Prologue: some thoughts on the history of the evolutionary synthesis’, in E. Mayr and W. B. Provine (eds.), The Evolutionary Synthesis: Perspectives on the Unification of Biology, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1–48CrossRef
McDougall, W. (1908), An Introduction to Social Psychology, London: Methuen
McDougall, W. (1921), ‘The use and abuse of instinct in social psychology’, Journal of Abnormal Psychology and Social Psychology 16: 331–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McFarland, F. B. (1985), ‘Thorstein Veblen versus the institutionalists’, Review of Radical Political Economics 17(4): 95–105CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Medvedev, Z. (1986), ‘Clarence Ayres and his gospel of technology’, History of Political Economy 18(4): 593–613Google Scholar
Medvedev, Z. (1969), The Rise and Fall of T. D. Lysenko, New York: Columbia University Press
Menger, C. (1883), Untersuchungen über die Methode der Sozialwissenschaften und der politischen Ökonomie insbesondere, Tübingen: Mohr. [Translated by F. J. Nock (1963), Problems of Economics and Sociology, Urbana, IL: University of Illinois Press.]
Metcalfe, J. S. (1988), ‘Evolution and economic change’, in A. Silberston (ed.), Technology and Economic Progress, Basingstoke: Macmillan, 54–85. [Reprinted in Witt (1993).]
Mirowski, P. (1989), More Heat Than Light: Economics as Social Physics, Physics as Nature's Economics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
Mises, L. von (1957), Theory and History: An Interpretation of Social and Economic Evolution, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press
Mitchell, W. C. (1910), ‘The rationality of economic activity’, Journal of Political Economy 18(2–3), parts Ⅰ and Ⅱ, 97–113 and 197–216CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitchell, W. C. (1937), The Backward Art of Spending Money and Other Essays, New York: McGraw-Hill
Moggridge, D. E. (1992), Maynard Keynes: An Economist's Biography, London: Routledge
Morgan, L. H. (1877), Ancient Society, Chicago: Charles Kerr. [Reprinted in 1964 with an introduction by L. A. White, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.]
Morgan, M. (1995), ‘Evolutionary metaphors in explanations of American industrial competition’, in S. Maasen, E. Mendelsohn and P. Weingart (eds.), Biology as Society, Society as Biology: Metaphors, Sociology of the Sciences Yearbook, vol. 18, Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 311–37
Moss, S. J. (1984), ‘The history of the theory of the firm from Marshall to Robinson and Chamberlin: the source of positivism in economics’, Economica 51(August): 307–18CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myrdal, G. (1972), Against the Stream: Critical Essays in Economics, New York: Pantheon Books
Nelson, R. R. (1994), personal communication to G. M. Hodgson, 21 September
Nelson, R. R., and Winter, S. G. (1973), ‘Towards an evolutionary theory of economic capabilities’, American Economic Review 63(2): 440–49Google Scholar
Nelson, R. R., and Winter, S. G. (1974), ‘Neoclassical vs. evolutionary theories of economic growth: critique and prospectus’, Economic Journal 336: 886–905. [Reprinted in Freeman (1990).]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, R. R., and S. G. Winter (1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press
Neumann, J. von, and O. Morgenstern (1944), Theory of Games and Economic Behaviour, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
Nightingale, J. (1993), ‘Solving Marshall's problem with the biological analogy: Jack Downie's competitive process’, History of Economics Review 20 (Summer): 75–94. [Reprinted in Hodgson (1995).]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Niman, N. B. (1991), ‘Biological analogies in Marshall's work’, Journal of the History of Economic Thought 13(1): 19–36. [Reprinted in Hodgson (1995).]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ormerod, P. (1994), The Death of Economics, London: Faber and Faber
Penrose, E. T. (1952), ‘Biological analogies in the theory of the firm’, American Economic Review 42(4): 804–19Google Scholar
Persons, S. (ed.) (1950), Evolutionary Thought in America, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press
Pigou, A. C. (1922), ‘Empty economic boxes: a reply’, Economic Journal 128: 458–65CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pigou, A. C. (1928), ‘An analysis of supply’, Economic Journal 150: 238–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quine, W. van O. (1953), From a Logical Point of View, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press
Rapport, D. J., and Turner, J. E. (1977), ‘Economic models in ecology’, Science 195: 367–73. [Reprinted in Hodgson (1995).]CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rizvi, S. A. T. (1994), ‘The microfoundations project in general equilibrium theory’, Cambridge Journal of Economics 18(4): 357–77CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robbins, L. (1932), An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science, London: Macmillan
Robbins, L. (1970), Evolution of Modern Economic Theory, London: Macmillan
Roscher, W. (1854), Das System der Volkswirtschaft [The System of the Folk-Economy], Stuttgart: Cotta
Rose, S., L. J. Kamin and R. C. Lewontin (1984), Not in Our Genes: Biology, Ideology and Human Nature, Harmondsworth: Penguin
Ross, D. (1991), The Origins of American Social Science, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
Rutherford, M. H. (1984), ‘Thorstein Veblen and the processes of institutional change’, History of Political Economy 16(3): 331–48. [Reprinted in M. Blaug (ed.) (1992), Thorstein Veblen (1857–1929), Aldershot: Edward Elgar.]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, M. H. (1994), Institutions in Economics: The Old and the New Institutionalism, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
Rutherford, M. H. (1997), ‘American institutionalism and the history of economics’, Journal of the History of Economic Thought 19(2): 178–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, M. H. (1999), ‘Institutionalism as “scientific economics”’, in R. E. Backhouse and J. Creedy (eds.), From Classical Economics to the Theory of the Firm: Essays in Honour of D. P. O'Brien, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 223–42
Rutherford, M. H. (2000), ‘Institutionalism between the wars’, Journal of Economic Issues 34(2): 291–303CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. (1938), ‘A note on the pure theory of consumer's behaviour’, Economica, New Series, 5(17): 61–71CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sanderson, S. K. (1990), Social Evolutionism: A Critical History, Oxford: Blackwell
Schaffer, M. E. (1989), ‘Are profit-maximisers the best survivors? A Darwinian model of economic natural selection’, Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization 12(1): 29–45. [Reprinted in Hodgson (1995).]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schäffle, A. (1881), Bau und Leben des socialen Körpers [Anatomy and Life of the Social Body], Tübingen: Lapp
Scheffler, I. (1974), Four Pragmatists: A Critical Introduction to Peirce, James, Mead, and Dewey, London: Routledge and Kegan Paul
Schumpeter, J. A. (1934), The Theory of Economic Development: An Inquiry into Profits, Capital, Credit, Interest, and the Business Cycle [translated by R. Opie from the German edition of 1912], Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. [Reprinted 1989 with a new introduction by J. E. Elliott, New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction.]
Schumpeter, J. A. (1954), History of Economic Analysis, Oxford: Oxford University Press
Sebba, G. (1953), ‘The development of the concepts of mechanism and model in physical science and economic thought’, American Economic Review 43(2): 259–68. [Reprinted in Hodgson (1995).]Google Scholar
Seckler, D. (1975), Thorstein Veblen and the Institutionalists: A Study in the Social Philosophy of Economics, London: Macmillan
Shove, G. F. (1942), ‘The place of Marshall's Principles in the development of economic theory’, Economic Journal 208: 294–329CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sowell, T. (1967), ‘The “evolutionary” economics of Thorstein Veblen’, Oxford Economic Papers 19(2): 177–98. [Reprinted in M. Blaug (ed.) (1992), Thorstein Veblen (1857–1929), Aldershot: Edward Elgar.]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, G. J., Stigler, S. M. and Friedland, C. (1995), ‘The journals of economics’, Journal of Political Economy 105(2): 331–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stoneman, W. (1979), A History of the Economic Analysis of the Great Depression, New York: Garland
Streissler, E. W. (1990), ‘The influence of German economics on the work of Menger and Marshall’, History of Political Economy 22, Annual Supplement, 31–68Google Scholar
Sugden, R. (1986), The Economics of Rights, Co-operation and Welfare, Oxford: Blackwell
Tang, A. M., F. M. Westfield and J. S. Worley (eds.) (1976), Evolution, Welfare and Time in Economics: Essays in Honor of Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen, Lexington, MA: Lexington Books
Thomas, B. (1991), ‘Alfred Marshall on economic biology’, Review of Political Economy 3(1): 1–14. [Reprinted in Hodgson (1995).]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tilman, R. (1990), ‘New light on John Dewey, Clarence Ayres, and the development of evolutionary economics’, Journal of Economic Issues 24(4): 963–79CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tilman, R. (1992), Thorstein Veblen and His Critics, 1891–1963: Conservative, Liberal, and Radical, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
Tool, M. R. (1994), ‘Ayres, Clarence E.’, in G. M. Hodgson, W. J. Samuels and M. R. Tool (eds.), The Elgar Companion to Institutional and Evolutionary Economics, Aldershot: Edward Elgar, vol. 1, 16–22
Tullock, G. (1979), ‘Sociobiology and economics’, Atlantic Economic Journal, September, 1–10. [Reprinted in Hodgson (1995).]Google Scholar
Tylor, E. B. (1871), Primitive Culture, 2 volumes, London. [Reprinted in 1958, New York: Harper.]
Veblen, T. B. (1898), ‘Why is economics not an evolutionary science?’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 12(3): 373–97. [Reprinted in Veblen (1919).]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veblen, T. B. (1899), The Theory of the Leisure Class: An Economic Study in the Evolution of Institutions, New York: Macmillan
Veblen, T. B. (1904), The Theory of Business Enterprise, New York: Charles Scribner's. [Reprinted in 1975 by Augustus Kelley.]
Veblen, T. B. (1909), ‘Fisher's rate of interest’, Political Science Quarterly 24(June): 296–303. [Reprinted in T. B. Veblen (1934), Essays on Our Changing Order, edited by L. Ardzrooni, New York: The Viking Press.]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veblen, T. B. (1919), The Place of Science in Modern Civilisation and Other Essays, New York: Huebsch. [Reprinted in 1990 with a new introduction by W. J. Samuels, New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction.]
Vining, R. (1939), ‘Suggestions of Keynes in the writings of Veblen’, Journal of Political Economy 47(5): 692–704CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Waller, W. J. Jr. (1988), ‘Habit in economic analysis’, Journal of Economic Issues 22(1): 113–26. [Reprinted in G. M. Hodgson (ed.) (1993), The Economics of Institutions, Aldershot: Edward Elgar.]CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ward, B. (1972), What's Wrong With Economics? London: Macmillan
Ward, L. F. (1893), The Psychic Factors of Civilization, Boston: Ginn
Whitehead, A. N. (1926), Science and the Modern World, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
Wilson, E. O. (1975), Sociobiology: The New Synthesis, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press
Winslow, E. A. (1989), ‘Organic interdependence, uncertainty and economic analysis’, Economic Journal 398: 1173–82CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winter, S. G. (1964), ‘Economic “natural selection” and the theory of the firm’, Yale Economic Essays 4(1): 225–72Google Scholar
Wispé, L. G., and Thompson, J. N. (1976), ‘The war between the words: biological versus social evolution and some related issues’, American Psychologist 31(5): 341–51CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Witt, U. (ed.) (1993), Evolutionary Economics, Aldershot: Edward Elgar
Wunderlin, C. E., Jr. (1992), Visions of a New Industrial Order: Social Science and Labor Theory in America's Progressive Era, New York: Columbia University Press

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×