Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-5g6vh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-26T07:15:51.687Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

16 - Reflections on Climate Governance and Federalism

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 May 2023

Alan Fenna
Affiliation:
Curtin University, Perth
Sébastien Jodoin
Affiliation:
McGill University, Montréal
Joana Setzer
Affiliation:
London School of Economics and Political Science

Summary

This chapter reflects on key findings in this book and how they enhance understanding of the relationship between climate governance and federalism around the world. federalism and federal-type arrangements work in crosscutting ways, facilitating climate governance in some respects, hindering it in others. Divided jurisdiction’s effects vary according to a range of institutional, political, social, economic and geographic factors.

Type
Chapter
Information
Climate Governance and Federalism
A Forum of Federations Comparative Policy Analysis
, pp. 328 - 336
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2023
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This content is Open Access and distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 https://creativecommons.org/cclicenses/

This book has brought together accounts of the relationship between climate change governance and federal or federal-type arrangements across a wide range of cases. Despite the considerable variation among them, it is possible to make some observations about that relationship. Specifically, we wanted to get an insight into the way a system structured into two (or occasionally three) orders of government with powers divided and shared between them might either facilitate or obstruct action addressing climate change. In Chapter 1, we noted that a considerable literature highlights the ‘double-edged’ character of federalism in this regard.

The diversity of cases is manifest in many ways, with our sample including countries at very different levels of economic development; federations based on a dual or an administrative division of powers; ethno-federations and those with a single national culture; parliamentary and presidential systems; centralised and quite decentralised federations; and regimes that range from established liberal democracies to autocracies. In addition, three of them are federations within a supra-national federation, the EU, itself one of our cases. Finally, we also included two unitary states with some form of devolved governance.

The key characteristic of federalism here is the way it creates ‘states within states’ – an arrangement that provides (a) a second set governmental actors, and (b) greater scope for territorial diversity in policymaking. In turn, this focuses attention on the way powers, responsibilities and resources are divided or shared between those constituent units and the central government, and the way in which the different governments relate to one another. How those will play out is in turn dependent on the political, economic and social characteristics of each federal system.

Countries around the world have been under pressure for many years now to mitigate climate change by reducing their greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions and to introduce adaptive measures. For most of our cases, the mitigation challenge is to transition away from hydrocarbon fuel sources – coal, petroleum and natural gas – to renewables, notably wind and solar. A number of the federations represented here are rich in fossil fuels and all of them have built industrial and consumption structures around those energy sources. Another important characteristic of those resource endowments is that they tend to be regionally concentrated within each federation. Germany has its coal states, Canada its petroleum provinces, the United States its coal and petroleum states. For those less-industrialised federations, the issue is not fossil fuels, but land use. The GHG contributions of Ethiopia, Indonesia and Brazil are much more tied to deforestation and agricultural practices. In Brazil that is also regionally concentrated, while in Ethiopia and Indonesia emissions associated with agriculture and deforestation are more broadly prevalent.

16.1 Federalism as Facilitator

In Chapter 1, we canvassed three ways in which federalism might facilitate policymaking: allowing locally tailored responses, providing opportunities for compensatory action, and opening the door to policy experimentation and learning. Climate change governance would seem particularly advantaged by such potentialities since, as is often noted, it encompasses a range of possible measures that can be implemented and operate at very different governance scales.

16.1.1 Locally-Tailored Policymaking

A virtue of federalism is often seen as being the way it invites policymaking that is customised to local circumstances, needs and preferences – the ‘decentralization theorem’, as Oates (Reference Oates1972, 35; italics in original) called it. Federal systems provide scope for such customisation to a degree unlikely in a unitary state, where ‘one-size-fits-all’ approaches may prevail.

This requires, of course, that the constituent units enjoy sufficient jurisdictional authority – and the studies in this book suggest that in climate change policy they generally do. Such a degree of autonomy unsurprisingly exists in the European Union’s (EU) supra-national proto-federal system, as Alberton emphasises. Even in Germany, though, with its administrative division of powers where the constituent units have more of an implementational role and less policy autonomy than in dual federations, Eckersley and colleagues make it clear that the Länder have had considerable scope to choose their own climate policy direction.

However, this is not the case everywhere. Pillai and Dubash emphasise the degree to which the highly centralised nature of India’s federal system reduces the scope for independent action by the constituent units. Although India’s states control several important areas of climate policy, financial and capacity constraints limit prospects for bottom-up action. Meanwhile, de Visser and du Plessis show that what they characterise as South Africa’s ‘quasi-federal’ system leaves the provinces with very little policy role at all, and the cities without the resources to pursue the climate action they contemplate. As Di Gregorio and Moeliono explain, the Indonesian case is similar: lacking the constitutional guarantees provided by federalism, the local role in forestry management there has been assumed by central government authorities, with adverse implications for outcomes.

The cases covered in this book provide numerous instances of regionally tailored climate change policy. Constituent units in Australia, Brazil, Canada, Germany, Mexico, Spain, Switzerland, the United States and other countries, have been able to adopt approaches consistent with their specific circumstances and preferences. Most important is how dependent the different constituent units are upon emissions-intensive economic activity – and therein lies the rub. As discussed below, while such flexibility has long been seen as a virtue of federalism, it has more contentious consequences for climate change governance.

16.1.2 Compensatory Federalism

The redundancy of having more than one order of government also creates potential for the constituent units to step up when the central government fails to act; they can play a ‘compensatory’ role (Derthick Reference Derthick and Rabe2010). This is something that sets federal states clearly apart from unitary ones. Given, as noted above, that constituent units typically hold a number of mitigation cards, the potential for compensatory federalism is undoubtedly there. We must be mindful, though, that the question is not whether compensatory action by constituent units is as effective or efficient as an optimal set of policies implemented across the country by the central government. It is simply whether constituent unit initiatives go some way to filling a void created by central government inaction.

The chapters in this book provide evidence of such compensating action occurring across a number of federations. Partisanship has been at the heart of the matter – fiercely so in the United States, but quite evidently so in other federations as well. All policy has its ideological inflection, and climate change is no exception. When central governments have been in the hands of those opposed to climate change action, constituent units have often taken the initiative – typically, those of a different ideological complexion. This has been the case in the United States, as Rabe shows; in Australia; in Canada as Harrison shows; in Switzerland as Kammerer and colleagues show; and Brazil as Barbi and Rei show.

For good reason, California is the best-known case of constituent unit environmental activism, but it is anomalous. There are certainly ‘leader’ jurisdictions in other federations – such as the Mexican state of Yucatan, as Corral and Heredia show – but these do not exercise the kind of systemic leverage that California has enjoyed. Prominent among the measures adopted at constituent unit level have been policies to encourage investment in renewable energy and to penalise emissions through cap-and-trade systems. Occasionally constituent units can go further and endeavour to force the central government to act, as a group of US States did via a legal challenge in 2007. However, there is little evidence of this in our other cases.

Does this compensatory action have a perverse effect by letting central governments off the hook? There is some suggestion this might be the case in Switzerland, but in general it would seem not. In the case of the EU, Alberton describes the leadership role played by those more ambitious member states, setting the agenda for the Union as a whole. To what extent has compensatory federalism filled the void created by inaction at the centre? That is a question addressed below.

Institutional realities are also a factor in some of our cases. Rabe reminds us how the presidential separation-of-powers system in the United States has helped ensure that ‘no major federal environmental legislation has been adopted in the United States since the 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments’. Kammerer and colleagues point to Switzerland’s unique system of direct democracy as playing an inhibiting role as far as the federal government is concerned. However, as the Australia case shows, it is quite possible to have inaction prevail at the federal level in a straight parliamentary federation if conservative parties hold office there. In India, the central government has taken the position that the country should not have to compromise on economic development for the sake of climate change mitigation, and has refused to implement such policies unless there are clear co-benefits. Given that India is the third largest emitter, this is clearly an issue. Pillai and Dubash show that while the states have compensated somewhat, their ability to do so is limited by the highly centralised nature of India’s federal system.

16.1.3 Laboratory Federalism

Federalism’s greatest promise for policymaking lies in the potential provided by the existence of multiple governments for policy innovation and accompanying interjurisdictional learning. Learning can take place either horizontally among the constituent units, or vertically from one or more constituent units up to the central government. In climate change governance, though, there is little reason to expect a great deal of genuine policy innovation: most of the mitigation measures have been well known for some time and the issue is not coming up with new techniques, but simply making the decision to adopt and implement them (Engel Reference Engel and Robbins2015). In that regard, federalism still provides conditions for second-order policy learning – or ‘political learning’ (May Reference May1992) – in that pioneering jurisdictions can demonstrate the political and economic feasibility of what might be otherwise eschewed as excessively adventurous initiatives.

The accounts provided here are largely consistent with this more modest interpretation of the laboratory federalism idea. There is little mention of genuine policy innovation, but numerous examples of pioneering adoptions that provide a model for other jurisdictions. Even in as centralised a federation as India, there has been some vertical diffusion of state innovations, note Pillai and Dubash. However, there are certainly examples of innovations that failed to inspire emulation. As Harrison notes, British Columbia’s message that a provincial carbon tax can work fell on deaf ears across the rest of Canada. Québec joined with California in an emissions-trading scheme, but other provinces were not queuing up. In Switzerland, the great variation in circumstances between the cantons discourages interjurisdictional learning as far as climate change policy is concerned. In China, Yi and Cao conclude that there have been many instances of innovation and leadership but not necessarily an accompanying diffusion. Leaders without followers does not make for laboratory federalism. In general, we can say that the experience here reflects the chronic challenges that generally constrain interjurisdictional policy learning: the length of time before the ‘success’ of a policy becomes evident; the absence of an objective measure of success; the role of local conditions, circumstances and interests; the impact of ideology and partisanship.

16.2 Federalism as Hindrance

On the other side of the coin, Chapter 1 suggested three ways in which federalism may hinder policymaking. First, a system of divided jurisdiction creates various potential veto points whereby initiatives can be blocked. Second, if left to the constituent units, the result may be a motley collection of policies, collectively suboptimal, or even a situation where some jurisdictions negate the efforts of other. Third, there may be competitive pressure holding all constituent units back from taking action. In the latter two scenarios, ‘vertical coordination’ is required, one scholar has argued (Gordon Reference Gordon2015, 122–3). It is easy to see how climate change governance may be complicated by any or all of these, particularly given the upfront costs mitigation measures may involve and the degree of ideological conflict surrounding them.

16.2.1 Veto Points

Federalism has been seen as obstructing policymaking because either the relevant government has inadequate jurisdictional authority or institutions of constituent-unit representation in the central government have a veto power. These cases have highlighted some instances of such obstruction. In Spain, Rodrigo and colleagues note the high degree of jurisdictional conflict that has characterised environmental issues. In the EU, Alberton notes the retarding effect of reluctant member states. In Canada, Harrison points to the ability of status quo provinces to block pan-Canadian action because of a convention requiring intergovernmental unanimity. And when the federal government did eventually take unilateral action, passing the Greenhouse Gas Pollution Pricing Act in 2018, that might have succumbed to constitutional challenge (though it was upheld by the Supreme Court of Canada). Underpinning these dynamics is the degree to which Canada stands out as an unusually decentralised federation – a consequence in the largest part of the degree to which it is bicommunal, with Québec having long played a powerfully centrifugal role (Gagnon and Simeon Reference Gagnon, Simeon, Moreno and Colino2010; Lecours Reference Lecours2019). Other than this and some jurisdictional clashes between the states and the federal government in the USA, though, the federations surveyed in this book reveal little by way of such obstacles to effective climate governance.

Indonesia, though, is a different story. There, Di Gregorio and Moeliono describe a situation where two decades of decentralisation have resulted in a misalignment of roles, responsibilities and resources that hamstrings effective action. As we emphasised in Chapter 1, Indonesia is not a federation and indeed has long evinced an ‘aversion’ to federalism. Its experimentation with decentralised governance is recent and the resulting system must be seen as a work in progress.

While Canadian provinces were able to block central government action because of their power in the federation, they have no formal veto authority through representation in the Canadian parliament. The situation is very different in Germany, where the second chamber of the federal parliament, the Bundesrat (Federal Council) is made up of delegated representatives of the Länder governments. There, the Länder do enjoy a formal veto power and a coalition of coal states could stand in the way of national mitigation strategies. Eckersley and colleagues find little evidence to this point, though, of the much-discussed politikverflechtungsfalle or ‘joint-decision trap’ being an obstacle to federal climate change policymaking in Germany – though they suggest it could become so. The Bundesrat is, however, a very unusually ‘federal’ second chamber, and thus we would not expect this kind of veto point to be a factor in other federal systems. The only other case here with German-style Council governance is the EU, where similar dynamics can be found.

16.2.2 Policy Patchwork

While constituent units may well step up and compensate for central government inaction, quite possibly only some of them will – and to varying degrees. This pattern is evident from the case studies, particularly the USA and Canada, where several jurisdictions have taken notable climate change initiatives, but, equally, a number remained steadfastly attached to the status quo. Eckersley and colleagues describe a similar situation in Germany, Alberton does likewise for the EU, Rodrigo and colleagues do for Spain, and Yi and Cao do for China – reflecting what the latter describe as ‘the conflict between local economic interests and national goals for climate governance’.

In many cases the problem goes beyond the mere existence of diverse responses. Adela and colleagues describe a situation in Ethiopia where spillover problems between ethnically defined constituent units jealous of their powers and interests undermine mitigation and adaptation efforts. Oates (Reference Oates1972) noted that the decentralisation theorem is predicated on costs and benefits of a given policy being internalised, and there being no significant external effects, or spillovers. Decentralisation becomes more problematic the more serious those externalities.

In Canada, the issue is the degree to which those jurisdictions that have not taken action are the ones where action is most needed. As Harrison emphasises, no matter how concertedly Québec or British Columbia might work to reduce their emissions, those efforts cannot compensate for the large and increasing contribution from Alberta. ‘With only 12 percent of the population, Alberta contributes over 40 percent of Canada’s emissions’ (Harrison, Chapter 4 this volume), and its economic welfare is tied to its high-emission industries. As a consequence, Canada’s emissions have continued to rise. Similarly, as Barbi and Rei show, the efforts of the southern states in Brazil cannot compensate for the large and rising emissions of their Amazonian counterparts.

In Chapter 1, we noted the view that such policy discrepancies will be fatal. ‘Attempts to reduce greenhouse gas … emissions by one jurisdiction are meaningless if others allow emissions to increase by an equal (or greater) amount. An effective response … requires vertical coordination’ (Gordon Reference Gordon2015, 122–23). This would, however, seem to exaggerate. If emissions increase in some jurisdictions on a business-as-usual basis while other members of the federation are implementing policies to reduce theirs, those reductions are nonetheless reductions in the net federation-wide output, just as they would be if there were no shirkers. While, as Harrison emphasises, mitigation efforts by BC, Québec and Ontario are overshadowed by Alberta’s large and growing emissions and thus the leaders cannot compensate for the laggards, Canada’s net emissions are still lower than they would be if those three provinces had also continued on a business-as-usual path. None of the achieved reductions is ‘meaningless’. But that’s cold comfort, Harrison argues; in a federation such as Canada’s, the central government’s heavy hand is required if emissions are to be reduced. This would seem to be the case for any federation where there are jurisdictions wedded to emissions-intensive industries of such scale.

A very different scenario is represented by the Australian case, where states have varied in their commitment but not such that some jurisdictions effectively undo the efforts of the others. Because of their coal and LNG exports, Western Australia and Queensland play a role analogous to Alberta’s, but not to the same degree. The difference lies not in the respective federal systems, but in the type and distribution of resources within those systems. Both the fossil fuel resources and the renewable alternatives are more evenly distributed in Australia and none are as dirty to produce as the oil from Alberta’s tar sands.

16.2.3 The Collective Action Problem

Given that no constituent unit ‘acting alone, is even capable of adopting emission controls that would make a dent in global emissions’, and assuming that mitigation efforts are costly, there is good reason to think that all jurisdictions would be tempted to ‘free ride’ on the efforts of others (Adler Reference Adler2008, 448). The studies in this book provide little of evidence, though, of such an effect prevailing. That seems consistent with findings that jurisdictional action on climate change is determined more by internal dynamics than by the external collective action dilemma (e.g., Aklin and Mildenberger Reference Aklin and Mildenberger2020; Matisoff Reference Matisoff2008).

16.3 Conclusion

Federalism has undoubtedly enhanced climate change governance in several of the countries examined here. It has done so primarily through its inbuilt redundancy – providing the opportunity for constituent units to step up and ‘fill the void’ should the central government fail to act. This ‘compensatory’ potential has been most evident in the Australian case, but also across other federations canvassed here: Canada, the United States and Brazil. ‘Fill the void’, however, almost inevitably overstates things. There is no example of the net effect of constituent unit action equalling what a whole-of-federation programme equivalent to that undertaken in the more ambitious constituent units would have achieved. The void gets at best only partially filled. The extent to which this occurs is powerfully influenced by the geopolitical economy of the federation in question. Constituent units whose economic self-interest is heavily tied to high-emission patterns of economic activity are very unlikely to follow the lead of those with a different resource base and economic profile.

Importantly, dysfunctionality has been much less a problem of federalism than of insufficient federalism. It has been in the highly centralised systems or those in the developmental stage of decentralisation that we have seen the most persistent challenges to climate change governance. In those cases, insufficient autonomy, resources or capabilities at the constituent unit level or a misalignment of responsibilities and incentives have presented significant obstacles.

The accounts provided in this book confirm that federalism and federal-type arrangements work in cross-cutting ways, facilitating climate governance in some respects, hindering it in others. Divided jurisdiction’s effects vary according to a range of institutional, political, social, economic and geographic factors. Some patterns have emerged, though, and not all of federalism’s mooted advantages or disadvantages have been important factors.

References

Adler, Jonathan H. 2008. ‘Hothouse Flowers: The vices and virtues of climate federalism’. Temple Political & Civil Rights Law Review 17 (2): 443–64.Google Scholar
Aklin, Michaël, and Mildenberger, Matto. 2020. ‘Prisoners of the Wrong Dilemma: Why distributive conflict, not collective action, characterizes the politics of climate change’. Global Environmental Politics 20 (4): 427.Google Scholar
Derthick, Martha. 2010. ‘Compensatory Federalism’. In Greenhouse Governance: Addressing climate change in America, ed. Rabe, Barry G., 5872. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Engel, Kirsten H. 2015. ‘The Enigma of State Climate Change Policy Innovation’. In The Law and Policy of Environmental Federalism: A comparative analysis, ed. Robbins, Kalyani, 169–87. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Gagnon, Alain-G., and Simeon, Richard. 2010. ‘Canada’. In Diversity and Unity in Federal Countries, ed. Moreno, Luis and Colino, César. Montreal & Kingston: McGill–Queen’s University Press.Google Scholar
Gordon, David J. 2015. ‘An Uneasy Equilibrium: The coordination of climate governance in federated systems’. Global Environmental Politics 15 (2): 121–41.Google Scholar
Lecours, André. 2019. ‘Dynamic De/Centralization in Canada, 1867–2010’. Publius 49 (1): 5783.Google Scholar
Matisoff, Daniel C. 2008. ‘The Adoption of State Climate Change Policies and Renewable Portfolio Standards: Regional diffusion or internal determinants?Review of Policy Research 25 (6): 527–46.Google Scholar
May, Peter J. 1992. ‘Policy Learning and Failure’. Journal of Public Policy 12 (4): 331–54.Google Scholar
Oates, Wallace E. 1972. Fiscal Federalism. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×