Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-zzh7m Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-27T21:56:03.479Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Political regimes and firms' decisions to pay bribes: theory and evidence from firm-level surveys

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  12 June 2023

Shuichiro Nishioka*
Affiliation:
John Chambers College of Business and Economics, West Virginia University, Morgantown, WV, USA
Sumi Sharma
Affiliation:
Independent Researcher
Tuan Viet Le
Affiliation:
College of Business, University of Findlay, Findlay, OH, USA
*
*Corresponding author. E-mail: shuichiro.nishioka@mail.wvu.edu
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This paper makes the most of the observed actions of bribe takers and givers from the World Bank Enterprise Surveys and studies how a taker's action influences a giver's decision to pay bribes. To motivate our empirical study, we consider Kaufmann and Wei's (1999) Stackelberg game between a tax authority and a firm that undergoes tax inspection. The model predicts that, when the authority can use its action as a credible threat for the firm's profitability, the authority disturbs the firm by inspecting more, and the firm is more likely to pay bribes. Consistent with the theoretical prediction, we find correlational evidence that the propensity to pay bribes increases with the number of inspection visits, particularly for non-democratic countries.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Millennium Economics Ltd.

Introduction

In the past several decades, autocratic countries have enmeshed themselves into the global economy.Footnote 1 However, their integration into the global economy has failed to alter the corrupt nature of their governments and businesses. The literature identifies several channels through which autocratic regimes induce corruption. Autocratic leaders exercise their power to avoid regime change at the expense of transparency and fair competition (Treisman, Reference Treisman2000). Politicians in autocratic countries have no incentives to fight against corruption because their voting processes lack transparency (Adserà et al., Reference Adserà, Boix and Payne2003) and their legal system is not dependable (Rose-Ackerman, Reference Rose-Ackerman1999).

To better understand why and how corruption occurs in autocratic countries, we use firm-level World Bank surveys from 138 countries and examine how governmental authorities' actions shape the distribution of red tape and bribe givers in each country.Footnote 2 To guide our empirical investigation, we use Kaufmann and Wei's (Reference Kaufmann and Wei1999) Stackelberg game between a tax authority and a firm that undergoes tax inspection. The model predicts that when the authority is able to disturb the firm by threatening to impose a severe penalty, the authority has an incentive to impose more red tape, and the firm is more likely to pay in order to reduce the red tape. The World Bank surveys provide us with the two key variables from the theory: an authority's action to impose red tape (e.g., ‘how many times was this establishment either inspected by tax officials or required to meet with them?’); and a firm's response to the authority (e.g., ‘in any of these inspections or meetings was a gift or informal payment expected or requested?’).

Figure 1 illustrates the normalised levels of red tape by bribe payment status for seven public services. Consistent with the findings of Kaufmann and Wei (Reference Kaufmann and Wei1999) and Freund et al. (Reference Freund, Hallward-Driemeier and Rijkers2016), the figure shows that bribe givers are those subjected to more red tape by their authority. The findings, however, mask the fact that the relationship between the incidence of bribe payments and red tape differs systematically across countries with different political regimes. Figure 2 illustrates the binned scatter plots and the fitted lines to visualise the relationships between the share of bribe givers and red tape from tax inspections for the sample of full democracies, partial democracies, and limited democracies in Panels A, B, and C, respectively.Footnote 3 The slope of the fitted line is steeper for limited democracies than for full democracies, meaning that firms in autocratic countries in which their authority has the power to disturb private firms are more likely to pay bribes when faced with more red tape.

Figure 1. Red tape by bribe payment status.

Notes: (1) There are four government services: tax inspections (tax), construction permits (con), import licenses (imp), and operation licenses (ope). There are three utility services: electrical connections (ele), telephone connections (tel), and water connections (wtr). (2) Red tape is the normalised log number of wait days or authority visits for each country.

Figure 2. Red tape and the share of bribe givers by democracy index.

Notes: (1) We use the data from tax audits. (2) Red tape is the normalised log number of tax audit visits for each country. (3) We define 29 (32) countries as full democracies (limited democracies) if their Freedom House index (civil liberties, 1995) is 1–2 (6–7). We define the remaining 77 countries as partial democracies. (4) The slope of the fitted line is 0.012 (standard error clustered at the country level is 0.004) in Panel A, 0.036 (standard error clustered at the country level is 0.011) in Panel B, and that is 0.048 (standard error clustered at the country level is 0.014) in Panel C.

Since corruption could arise from factors other than a country's political status, we use the linear probabilistic model and estimate the difference in the slopes by controlling for firm characteristics and country-level control variables. After controlling for these variables, we find that a one-standard-deviation difference in the log number of tax inspection visits causes the payment propensity to differ by 2.7 percentage points across non-democratic (limited and partially democratic) versus fully democratic countries. The results are robust when we (1) control for unobserved country-specific factors using country fixed effects, (2) use the sample of democratic countries from Acemoglu et al. (Reference Acemoglu, Naidu, Restrepo and Robinson2019),Footnote 4 (3) check outlier countries by estimating for each country, (4) control for unobserved firm-specific factors by using the pooled sample of all public services available in the surveys and introducing firm fixed effects, and (5) use Oster's (Reference Oster2019) method to account for omitted variable bias arising from unobservable variables.

Our paper is related to the literature that examines corruption using firm-level surveys. Most of the studies (e.g., Alexeev and Song, Reference Alexeev and Song2013; Alm et al., Reference Alm, Martinez-Vazquez and McClellan2016; Diaby and Sylwester, Reference Diaby and Sylwester2015; Gauthier et al., Reference Gauthier, Goyette and Kouaméc2021; Svensson, Reference Svensson2003) examine how firm characteristics determine the general rates of bribery or how corruption influences firm performance. We follow Kaufmann and Wei (Reference Kaufmann and Wei1999) and Freund et al. (Reference Freund, Hallward-Driemeier and Rijkers2016) and examine the relationship between a government authority's action and a firm's response. Making the most of the large cross-country variation, we show that the relationship systematically differs based on political status.

Our paper is also related to the literature that examines corruption under different political and economic regimes. Using an endogenous growth model, Ehrlich and Lui (Reference Ehrlich and Lui1999) examine the links between corruption, government, and growth. The equilibrium growth rate of their model depends on the relative importance of human capital versus political capital accumulation, according to alternative political regimes. Méndez and Sepúlveda (Reference Méndez and Sepúlveda2006) find that the relationship between corruption and growth is nonlinear for a sample of free countries. Aidt et al. (Reference Aidt, Dutta and Sena2008) explore the possibility that differences in the quality of political institutions (i.e., their capacity to hold political leaders accountable for their actions) are the source of the nonlinear relationship between corruption and growth. Saha and Sen (Reference Saha and Sen2021) find evidence that the corruption–growth relationship differs based on the type of political regime, and the growth-enhancing effect of corruption is more likely to occur in autocracies than in democracies.Footnote 5 While the literature generally uses macroeconomic data, we use firm-level data and show that authorities in countries that have concentrated power are more likely to disturb private firms for their private gains at the expense of efficiency.

The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. In Section ‘A model of bribe payment’, we describe the model. Section ‘Data’ explains the development of corruption and democracy variables. In Section ‘Empirical analysis’, we provide empirical results, and the final section concludes the paper.

A model of bribe payment

Aidt (Reference Aidt2003) categorises the theoretical analysis of corruption into four approaches: (1) efficient corruption; (2) corruption with a benevolent principal; (3) corruption with a non-benevolent principal; and (4) self-reinforcing corruption. Our theory is closely related to corruption with a non-benevolent principal. While Aidt (Reference Aidt2003) introduces a license model with entry regulation, we use Kaufmann and Wei's (Reference Kaufmann and Wei1999) Stackelberg game between a government authority and a firm that needs to go through tax inspection. The theory can be generalised to other government permits and public services. In the game, the authority is a leader, and the firm is a follower. The tax authority moves first to set red tape, the expected number of visits for tax inspection. The firm moves next to maximise its post-bribery profit by choosing the optimal amount of bribes.Footnote 6

In the first meeting of the inspection, the government authority has an opportunity to inform the firm with the expected number of meetings, which is the authority's initial harassment level and is defined as endogenous red tape (r) over the minimum number of required meetings (r). The authority and the firm share the bribe schedule, s(b), that specifies how bribes can reduce red tape. We assume diminishing marginal returns to the amount of bribes: the first derivative is positive (s b > 0); and the second derivative is negative (s bb < 0). Bribes can reduce the number of meetings, but it gets more and more difficult to do so by paying more bribes. This assumption implies that the firm is not willing to pay an enormous amount of bribes. We also define red tape after paying bribes ($\bar{r}$):

(1)$$\bar{r} = \underline{r} + r-s( b ) $$

where $\bar{r}$ and r are non-negative values.

A firm's pre-bribery profit (π) is predetermined.Footnote 7 The firm's post-bribery profit is

(2)$$\pi \ast = [ {1-t( {\bar{r}} ) } ] \pi -b.$$

where $t( {\bar{r}} )$ captures the penalty rate after paying bribes.

The penalty function plays a crucial role in theoretical predictions. We assume t r > 0 and t rr > 0. The first and second derivatives combined imply that, as the number of inspection meetings (r) increases, the authority can scrutinise the firm's tax files and impose an exponentially higher penalty rate.

We use the backward induction method and identify the sub-game perfect Nash equilibrium. The firm observes equations (1) and (2) and chooses the optimal amount of bribes (b). The first-order condition is

(3)$$t_r( {r, \;b} ) s_b( b ) \pi = 1, \;$$

and, conditional on the firm's profit, the firm's reaction function depends on the red tape imposed by the authority:

(4)$$b = b( r ).$$

By differentiating the firm's reaction function (4) with respect to r, we can obtain the following condition, which indicates that the authority has the incentive to set more red tape to increase their bribe intakes:

(5)$$\displaystyle{{\partial b} \over {\partial r}} = \displaystyle{{t_{rr}s_b} \over {t_{rr}s_b^2 -t_rs_{bb}}} > 0$$

where ∂b/∂r is strictly increasing with t rr.Footnote 8

The authority observes the firm's reaction function and moves first to choose the red tape (r) using equation (5). Then, the firm moves next to choose its best response (b) to maximise its post-bribery profit.

From equations (1) and (5), we can predict the post-bribery number of inspection meetings:

(6)$$\displaystyle{{\partial \bar{r}} \over {\partial b}} = \displaystyle{{\partial r} \over {\partial b}}-s_b > 0.$$

The equilibrium conditions from equations (5) and (6) suggest that when the authority has the ability to impose a severe penalty (t r > 0 and t rr > 0), conditional on the high red tape imposed by the authority, the number of meetings remains high even after paying bribes.

While the authority cares about their bribe intakes, the bribery-corruption deal involves the risk for the authority, including law enforcement and criminal justice (e.g., Fisman and Miguel, Reference Fisman and Miguel2007). As such, we define the authority's objective function:

(7)$$U = b( r ) -cr$$

where c > 0 represents the cost of harassment.

The authority's decision to impose more red tape depends on the following condition:

(8)$$\displaystyle{{\partial U} \over {\partial r}} = \displaystyle{{\partial b} \over {\partial r}}-c > 0.$$

The equilibrium conditions from equations (5) and (8) suggest that, when corruption is not costly, the authority is more likely to impose red tape to induce the firm's bribe payments.

To show that the authority without power does not have an incentive to harass the firm by imposing more red tape, we consider the equilibrium when t r > 0 and t rr ≤ 0. This assumption means that the authority's threat to increase the penalty rate is not credible.

Because ∂b/∂r in equation (6) is strictly increasing with t rr, the authority's harassment does not induce the firm's bribe payments: ∂b/∂r = 0 when t rr = 0 and ∂b/∂r < 0 when t rr < 0. Thus, while equation (6) suggests that paying bribes would reduce red tape as in the efficient grease literature (e.g., Leys, Reference Leys1965; Lui, Reference Lui1985), equation (8) suggests that the authority has no incentives to do so because it is costly for the authority (∂U/∂r < 0).

Data

We use the firm-level survey data from the World Bank Enterprise Surveys (WBES).Footnote 9 The original sample consists of 124,940 observations from 139 countries over the period of 2006–2016. After excluding observations from SwedenFootnote 10 and those without data on firm-level employment, we have 122,855 observations from seven sectorsFootnote 11 and 138 countries.Footnote 12 Some countries have three years of survey results, but most of the countries report only one year of results. The average gross domestic product (GDP) per capita (in current international dollars converted by purchasing power parity) within our sample is $9,230; Israel is the most advanced country in the sample with an average GDP per capita of $34,324, and the Democratic Republic of the Congo is the least developed country with an average GDP per capita of $642. The World Bank database is one of the most reliable data sources for corruption studies because it surveys managing directors, business owners, accountants, and other relevant staff members who have firsthand experience of the issues.

Corruption variables

Using the survey data, some studies (e.g., Alexeev and Song, Reference Alexeev and Song2013; Diaby and Sylwester, Reference Diaby and Sylwester2015; Kraay and Murrell, Reference Kraay and Murrell2016) focus on the question of the general rates of bribery (e.g., the amount of bribes divided by sales). To examine the bribery-corruption deal between an authority and a firm, we use the following survey questions. The surveys, for example, ask ‘over the last 12 months, was this establishment visited or inspected by tax officials?’ and then ask ‘how many times was this establishment either inspected by tax officials or required to meet with them?’ and ‘in any of these inspections or meetings was a gift or informal payment expected or requested?’ Therefore, we can examine the sequence of bribery-corruption actions without facing identification problems the survey data typically face.Footnote 13 Of course, the variables we use are not perfect either. In the surveys, we cannot clearly distinguish red tape imposed by the authority from red tape after paying bribes. Respondents may also choose to refuse, misreport, or not report for many reasons. For example, around 3% of the firms refused to answer or do not respond to the bribe payment question.Footnote 14

Following the survey structure of the WBES, we study seven types of public services: (1) tax inspection; (2) construction permit application; (3) import license application; (4) operation license application; (5) electrical connection; (6) telephone connection; and (7) water connection. Among the public services available from the surveys, we believe that tax inspection best describes the Stackelberg game above. The tax authority in countries with concentrated power could use a severe penalty as a credible threat for firms and individuals. As such, we use tax inspection as our baseline results.Footnote 15 Nevertheless, we report the results including other public services.

Using the sample of the firms that used a public service, we develop a service-specific bribe payment indicator variable (p i), defined as one when firm i made a gift or informal payment to government officials, and zero otherwise. Table 1 reports the summary statistics of bribe payment indicator variables. In the last 12 months, 66,428 firms in the sample were visited by tax officials. Among these firms, 14.6% paid or had bribes requested. Table 1 also illustrates that there is a significant cross-firm variation in the number of tax inspection visits (r i). The average number of visits is 3.4 with a median of 2 and a standard deviation of 4.8, suggesting that most of the firms were visited only a few times.

Table 1. Summary statistics of corruption variables

Notes: (1) The ‘payment’ dummy variable is one if a firm makes an informal gift and zero otherwise. (2) We replace outlier values (99.5-percentile values or higher) with the 99.5-percentile value for each of the red tape in a country.

Democracy index

The Freedom House has assessed the condition of political rights and civil liberties around the world. Similar data are reported by the Center for Systemic Peace as well as the University of Gothenburg, V-Dem Institute. We use the Freedom House democracy index because it covers all 138 countries in our data set.Footnote 16 Their numerical ratings, ranging from 1 to 7, cover more than 200 countries and territories and are assigned by analysts who assess research, consultations with local contacts, and information from news articles, nongovernmental organisations, governments, and a variety of other sources. We use the index from 1995 because transitions towards democracy allow the old-regime elites to sustain their political power (e.g., Martinez-Bravo et al. (Reference Martinez-Bravo, Mukherjee and Stegmann2017) for evidence from Indonesia and González et al. (Reference González, Muñoz and Prem2021) for evidence from Chile). For each country, the analysts study the electoral process, political pluralism and participation, the functioning of the government, freedom of expression and of belief, associational and organisational rights, the rule of law, and personal autonomy and individual rights. For example, the subset of the not-free rating (i.e., the index is 6 or 7) in our sample includes China, Indonesia, and Nigeria in 1995, while the subset of the free rating (i.e., the index is 1 or 2) includes Poland and Uruguay.Footnote 17 Most of the countries in our data set are countries without complete democracy. 29 countries are in the range of 1–2, which we refer to as full democracy, 77 countries are in the range of 3–5, which we refer to as partial democracy, and 32 countries are in the range of 6–7, which we refer to as limited democracy.

Since there are different ways to define and measure democracy, we also use the democratic country list from Acemoglu et al. (Reference Acemoglu, Naidu, Restrepo and Robinson2019) for the robustness check. Acemoglu et al. (Reference Acemoglu, Naidu, Restrepo and Robinson2019) follow Papaioannou and Siourounis (Reference Papaioannou and Siourounis2008) and develop an indicator variable of democracy. They combine several sources including the Freedom House democracy index. We merge their democracy index with the 134 countries in our data set, of which 78 countries are democracies and 56 countries are non-democracies. See Table 2 for the summary statistics for these variables. Across the regions, countries in the Americas and the European Union tend to be more democratic than those in the Middle East (see Appendix Table A1 for the regional summary statistics).

Table 2. Summary statistics of key explanatory variables

Notes: See Appendix I for the definitions of the variables.

Empirical analysis

In this section, we first illustrate how we derive the empirical specification from our theory. We then examine how red tape imposed by a government authority is associated with firms' propensity to pay bribes.

Empirical strategy

Our theory suggests that the second derivative of the penalty rate schedule (t rr) captures the threatening power of a government authority.

The equilibrium conditions we derived do not necessarily guarantee that a firm would pay the optimal amount of bribes to reduce red tape. While Kaufmann and Wei (Reference Kaufmann and Wei1999) assume that a firm has an arbitrary threshold to tolerate the authority's harassment, we consider the possibility that a firm has an opportunity to walk away from the bribery-corruption deal because such a deal is not always enforceable. To derive our empirical specification, we assume that a firm would pay bribes if its benefits exceed its costs of bribery:

(9)$$[ {t( {\bar{r} + s( b ) } ) -t( {\bar{r}} ) } ] \pi > b$$

where the firm's benefits, $[ {t( {\bar{r} + s( b ) } ) -t( {\bar{r}} ) } ] \pi$, are the penalty payment saved due to the bribery payment.

To understand the firm's decision to actually pay bribes, we define the latent variable from equation (9):

(10)$$Z = t_r\displaystyle{\pi \over b}$$

where $t_r\approx t( {\bar{r} + s( b ) } ) -t( {\bar{r}} )$.Footnote 18

Equation (10) is the ratio of the firm's benefits to costs surrounding bribery-corruption acts. The firm would pay bribes if and only if the benefit-to-cost ratio is greater than one: Z > 1. We are particularly interested in the empirical correlation between the propensity to pay (Z) and the first derivative of the penalty rate (t r). When an authority's action is not a threat for severe penalties (see Panel A in Figure 3), the propensity to pay should not strongly correlate with red tape because t rr increases slowly with $\bar{r}$. When an authority's action is a threat to a firm (see Panel B in Figure 3), more red tape induces firms to pay bribes. Thus, the propensity to pay and the red tape should be positively correlated because t rr increases strongly with $\bar{r}$.

Figure 3. The theoretical relationship between red tape and penalty rate.

Notes: The solid vertical line is a situation where a firm is imposed a one-standard deviation more or less red tape by an authority.

Equation (10) indicates that a firm's bribe amount and pre-bribery profit are determinants for the firm's decision to pay bribes. Because the bribe amount for tax inspections is not available, and the profit is not accurately reported in the surveys, we need to control for these unobservables. The selection of control variables is a critical aspect of our study. We adhere to the literature and use six firm-level (e.g., employment, export status, and technology certificates) and ten country-level variables (e.g., per capita GDP, oil share, the size of government, and legal origins) throughout our analysis.Footnote 19 We also include year fixed effects to control for survey years. Although we include a wide range of observable control variables, our results could be biased due to the omitted variable bias arising from unobservables. Therefore, we use Oster's (Reference Oster2019) strategy and show that the omitted variable bias is not significant in our study (see Section ‘Omitted variable bias’).

In our paper, we do not attempt to identify the causality of the explanatory variables. Rather, we want to examine if the propensity to pay bribes differs systematically with red tape across countries with different political regimes. We define the bribe payment indicator variable where p i = 1 when Z i > 1, otherwise p i = 0. And we use the log of the latent variable to derive the following empirical model:

(11)$$p_i = \beta _1D_c + \beta _2\ln ( {{\bar{r}}_i} ) + \beta _3D_c \times \ln ( {{\bar{r}}_i} ) + X_i + X_c + \varepsilon _i$$

where D c is the country-level democracy dummy variable from the Freedom House or Acemoglu et al. (Reference Acemoglu, Naidu, Restrepo and Robinson2019), $\ln ( {{\bar{r}}_i} )$ is the normalised log number of tax inspection visits by the authority, X i includes the firm-specific control variables, X c captures the country-specific control variables, and $\varepsilon _i$ is a random error term.

Figure 2 gives us some insights on the expected signs of the coefficients (β 1, β 2, and β 3) in equation (11). In the figure, the horizontal axis represents the normalised number of tax inspection visits, and the vertical axis represents the propensity to pay bribes. We find these two variables are positively associated for full democracies, partial democracies, and limited democracies. These three subsets of countries, however, are different in the slope of the fitted line, meaning that firms in less democratic countries are more likely to pay bribes when more red tape is imposed on them. This is because t rr is greater for these countries. Thus, we expect that β 1 < 0, β 2 > 0, and β 3 < 0. Intuitively, a firm that faces harassment from the authority has a strong incentive to pay bribes to reduce the red tape imposed by the authority because the firm understands that payment would substantially reduce the risk of enormous tax penalty payments.

Main results

By limiting the sample to the firms that were visited by tax officials, we use the linear probabilistic modelFootnote 20 and estimate equation (11).Footnote 21 Throughout the paper, we use standard errors that are clustered at the country level.

To start, Table 3 reports the results from tax inspection when we use the sub-samples of countries with different political regimes. Columns (1)–(3) report the results when we use the samples of 29 fully democratic countries, 77 partially democratic countries, and 29 limited democracies from the Freedom House. Columns (4)–(5) report the results when we use the samples of 78 democratic and 56 non-democratic countries from Acemoglu et al. (Reference Acemoglu, Naidu, Restrepo and Robinson2019). Because we use the subsets of the sample, we set β 1 = 0 and β 3 = 0 in equation (11) and check if firms in democracies are less likely to pay bribes when they face more red tapes. The results in columns (1)–(3) suggest that a one-standard-deviation difference in red tape causes the payment likelihood to differ by 1.3, 3.7, and 4.8 percentage points in full, partial, and limited democracies, respectively.Footnote 22 Firms in less democratic countries are more likely to pay bribes when they face more red tape. This is because red tape imposed by the authority is a credible threat to a severe penalty in countries with concentrated power. We find consistent results from the samples of democratic versus non-democratic countries from Acemoglu et al. (Reference Acemoglu, Naidu, Restrepo and Robinson2019). The results from alternative measures of democracy are reported in Table A2 in the Appendix.Footnote 23

Table 3. Red tape and propensity to pay bribes

Notes: (1) We regress the bribe payment indicator variable with red tape. Red tape is the normalised log number of tax inspection visits for each country. (2) In columns (1), (2), and (3), we use the sample of 29 fully democratic, 77 partially democratic, and 32 limited democratic countries, respectively, from the Freedom House index. In columns (4) and (5), we use the sample of 78 democratic and 56 non-democratic countries from Acemoglu et al. (Reference Acemoglu, Naidu, Restrepo and Robinson2019). (3) Standard errors clustered at the country level are reported in parentheses. ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% confidence levels, respectively.

Column (1) in Table 4 reports the results from equation (11) using the full sample of countries. Consistent with the results in Table 3, firms that faced substantially higher numbers of tax inspection visits are more likely to pay bribes, and firms that faced higher numbers of visits in fully democratic countries are less likely to pay bribes than those in non-democratic (partial and limited democratic) countries. In particular, the results indicate that a one-standard-deviation difference in the log number of tax inspection visits causes the payment propensity to differ by 2.7 percentage points across democratic versus non-democratic countries.Footnote 24

Table 4. The results with fixed effects

Notes: (1) We regress the bribe payment indicator variable with red tape, the democracy indicator variable (full democracy countries) from the Freedom House index, and the interaction between red tape and the democracy variable. (2) Columns (1)–(2) report the results from tax inspection, and columns (3)–(4) report the results from the pooled sample of seven public services. (3) Standard errors clustered at the country level are reported in parentheses. ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% confidence levels, respectively. (4) The number of observations declines from column (3) to (4) because the firm age variable is not available for all firms.

Robustness checks

Fixed effects

Since unobservable country and firm characteristics could bias the results, we use various fixed effects and show the robustness of the baseline results in column (1) in Table 4. Column (2) reports the results when we use country and sector fixed effects. Columns (3) and (4) report the results when we follow Freund et al. (Reference Freund, Hallward-Driemeier and Rijkers2016) and stack seven public services for each firm, which enables us to introduce firm fixed effects.Footnote 25 Column (3) reports the results when we use the same control variables from the baseline results in column (1) as well as public service fixed effects. Column (4) reports the results when we use firm fixed effects. The results reported in column (2) indicate that our results are robust to the introduction of country fixed effects, suggesting that our macroeconomic control variables created from the literature (e.g., Fisman and Miguel, Reference Fisman and Miguel2007; Shleifer and Vishny, Reference Shleifer and Vishny1993; Svensson, Reference Svensson2005) adequately capture cross-country variation in the propensity to pay bribes. The results reported in column (4) indicate that, even if we control unobservable firm characteristics, we find consistent results.

Omitted variable bias

In this section, we examine the omitted variable bias arising from unobservables. The selection of control variables is a critical aspect of our study. We use six firm-level and ten country-level control variables; however, several important variables, including political linkages and profitability, are not observable. A common technique to assess the robustness of the results to determine if there is omitted variable bias is to observe the movement of the coefficient on the variable of interest before and after including the control variables. As shown in columns (1) and (2) of Table 5, the coefficient for red tape remains stable across all subsets of the data, both before and after accounting for the control variables. This suggests that omitted variable bias is not a significant issue in our study.

Table 5. Oster's (Reference Oster2019) bias-adjusted coefficient

However, relying solely on coefficient movements using observable variables is not sufficient to determine the extent of omitted variable bias. To measure the magnitude of bias arising from unobservables, Altonji et al. (Reference Altonji, Elder and Taber2005a, Reference Altonji, Elder and Taber2005b) develop an empirical method to test the robustness of the results. The relationship between the variable of interest and the observables contains information about the relationship between the variable and the unobservables. Their test statistic is derived under the assumption that (1) the selection of observables is proportional to the selection of unobservables and (2) the variance of the outcome variable would be fully explained by unobservables (i.e., an R 2 value of one). The second assumption, however, is not realistic for our study because of the idiosyncratic nature of firm-level responses to corruption. Therefore, we follow Oster (Reference Oster2019) and estimate the bias-adjusted coefficient from the two different assumptions of maximum R 2 values that unobservables could possibly explain.Footnote 26 Columns (3) and (4) in Table 5 report the bias-adjusted coefficient of the red tape. The adjusted coefficient is nearly identical to the results in column (2), indicating that the omitted variable bias arising from both observables and unobservables is not significant.

Country-level results

Thus far, we report the results when we pool the countries in the data set. The results, however, could possibly depend on some outlier countries. Therefore, we estimate equation (11) for each country using the following equation:

(12)$$p_i = \beta _2\ln ( {{\bar{r}}_i} ) + X_i + \varepsilon _i.$$

We report the results from the two fully democratic countries (Poland and Uruguay) in columns (1) and (2), the two partially democratic countries (Ukraine and Russia) in columns (3) and (4), and the three limited democracies (Indonesia, Nigeria, and China) in columns (5)–(7) in Table 6.

Table 6. Propensity to pay bribes for selected countries

Notes: See Table 4.

We first compare the results from Poland and Ukraine. After the collapse of the Soviet Union, Poland, Ukraine, and other Easter European countries started their transition to democracy. Poland was among the first countries that prepared to join the European Union. As a result, it carried out economic and political reform to meet the requirements. The Freedom House index of Poland is 2 and that of Ukraine is 4 in 1995. Thus, Poland was more democratic than Ukraine in 1995. We find that the red tape variable carries a statistically significant positive coefficient only for Ukraine, suggesting that corruption problems arising from the authority's threat are much more prevalent in Ukraine. Moreover, we find consistent results from another example of democratic countries in the data: Uruguay.Footnote 27

Column (4) reports the results from Russia, confirming that firms are more likely to pay bribes when they face high red tape. The results are consistent with anecdotal evidence for the authority's ability to disturb private firms. Yukos Oil Company was a successful oligarch until the owner criticised President Vladimir Putin for spreading corruption in Russia in 2003. Soon after his statement, the Russian tax authority launched eight investigations and charged the company with $27 billion tax penalties. The anecdote suggests that the Russian authority displayed the ability to impose a severe penalty on firms and individuals.

The results in columns (5)–(6) from Indonesia and Nigeria indicate that red tape is a significant determinant for the propensity to pay bribes. Indonesia is considered one of the most corrupt countries in the world. Following the Asian Financial Crisis of 1997, Indonesia sought financial aid from the International Monetary Fund (IMF). In exchange, Indonesia had to implement anti-corruption reforms, including transitioning to a democracy. Pertiwi and Ainsworth (Reference Pertiwi and Ainsworth2021), however, find that democratisation did not reduce corruption. Corruption has been a persistent public issue in Nigeria for a long time. Diamond (Reference Diamond1991) argues that Nigerian officials are induced into corruption merely in pursuit of economic security, and democratic transition is the key to reducing corruption.

The results in column (7) indicate that the coefficient on red tape in China is smaller than those from Indonesia and Nigeria. According to our theoretical discussion, this suggests that bribery-corruption deals in China are much more like greasing the wheels. Indeed, Bai et al. (Reference Bai, Hsieh and Song2019) argue that China's special deals institutions emerged in the early 1990s, which enabled private firms to make special deals with political elites. They argue that China's special deals institutions contribute to China's rapid economic growth.

Figure 4 illustrates the box plots of the country-level estimates on red tape (β 2) from tax inspection by the Freedom House index. The figure confirms that firms in less democratic countries are more likely to pay bribes when they face more red tape. Table 7 further summarises the results from country-level estimates for each public service. Consistent with our theoretical prediction, the table shows that mean values on β 2 in equation (12) from the sample of non-democratic countries are greater than those from the sample of democratic countries. For example, we report the summary statistics from tax inspection in column (1). 90.6% of the limited democracies carry a positive sign, and 53.1% of the sample carry a positive and statistically significant coefficient. These numbers are very different for the sample of full democracies. 62.1% of these countries carry a positive sign, and 24.1% of the sample carries a positive and statistically significant coefficient. We find consistent results across all the public services.

Figure 4. The Freedom House index and country-level estimates on β 2 from tax inspection.

Notes: The bottom and top values of the boxes are the 25th percentile and 75th percentile values, respectively.

Table 7. Summary statistics for country-level estimates on β2

Notes: (1) See Table 6 for the estimation results for selected countries for tax inspections. (2) We use the coefficient on normalised log red tape for country-level results.

Conclusion

This paper used firm-level surveys from the World Bank and studied how a government authority's threat for a severe penalty shapes the distributions of red tape and bribe givers. Our model predicts that when the authority has the ability to intimidate firms by threatening to impose a severe penalty, the authority imposes more red tape, and the firm is more likely to pay bribes. Consistent with the prediction, we found a statistically significant positive association between red tape and the propensity to pay bribes, particularly for non-democratic countries. Our results suggest that authorities in countries with concentrated power including autocratic countries are able to disturb private firms for their private gains at the expense of efficiency.

Data Appendix

Variable list

Bribery variables

The WBES ask the bribery-related questionnaire items associated with the following public services: tax inspection, three government services (construction permit application, import license application, and operation license application), and three utilities (electrical connection, telephone connection, and water connection).

Using the sample of the firms that used a public service, we develop a payment variable (p i), defined as one when a firm made a gift or informal payment, and zero otherwise. We also use the number of tax inspection visits or the number of wait days (r i) that are our proxies for red tape. Table 1 reports the summary statistics of these variables.

Firm-level variables

We prepare six firm-level control variables that can possibly influence a firm's decision to pay bribes. The firm-level variables we use are log labour, log firm age, exporter, state-owned enterprise (SOE), foreign-owned, and technology certificate variables. Except for indicator variables, the variables are normalised within each country.

We develop the firm age from the firm's establishment year and survey year. We create the exporter indicator variable that is one if a firm exports (indirect and direct) at least 5% of its total sales, and zero otherwise. The SOE (foreign-owned firm) variable is one if the firm's share of government (foreign capital) is greater than or equal to 50%, and zero otherwise.Footnote 28 The technology certificate variable is one if a firm has an internationally-recognised quality certification, and zero otherwise.

Using firm-level data from the Ugandan enterprise survey, Svensson (Reference Svensson2003) shows that the amounts of bribes can be explained by firms' ability to pay and their refusal power. Clarke and Xu (Reference Clarke and Xu2004) and Rand and Tarp (Reference Rand and Tarp2012) show that firms are more likely to pay bribes when they are more profitable. The proxy variables for a firm's profitability (e.g., the number of competitors, markups, and accounting profits) are not widely available. Thus, we approximate it using the exporter and technology certificate variables (e.g., Melitz, Reference Melitz2003). Table 2 provides the summary statistics.

Macroeconomic variables

The democratic process is not the only country-level variable that is relevant to corruption. To control for various country-level factors that can possibly influence corruption (e.g., Shleifer and Vishny, Reference Shleifer and Vishny1993; Svensson, Reference Svensson2005), we prepare ten contemporary variables: per capita GDP, total population, government size (the government final consumption expenditure as a share of GDP), trade share (the sum of exports and imports of goods and services measured as a share of GDP), oil share (the difference between the value of crude oil production at regional prices and total costs of production as a share of GDP), and education (the compulsory years of education) variables from the World Bank World Development Indicators (WDI). If the data from the WDI is not available, we use supplemental data from several sources, including the Penn World Table. If the data from the survey year is not available, we utilise the data from the nearest year to the survey year. To proxy legal systems and institutions (e.g., Fisman and Miguel, Reference Fisman and Miguel2007), we derive the World Trade Organization (WTO) membership as well as legal system dummy variables from Head et al. (Reference Head, Mayer and Ries2010). Finally, we prepare the state capability index from Kar et al. (Reference Kar, Pritchett, Roy and Sen2022) by computing the mean of the six variables from the World Governance Index (voice and accountability, rule of law, regulatory quality, political stability, government effectiveness, and corruption control).

Country list

The World Bank Enterprise Surveys

The data we use was released on September 6, 2016. We have 122,855 observations from 138 countries over the 2006–2016 period. The survey year for each country is reported in parentheses below.

African countries (43 countries): Angola (2006 and 2010), Benin (2009), Botswana (2006 and 2010), Burkina Faso (2009), Burundi (2006 and 2014), Cameroon (2009), Cape Verde (2009), Central African Republic (2011), Chad (2009), the Republic of the Congo (2009), Djibouti (2013), the Democratic Republic of the Congo (2006, 2010, and 2013), Eritrea (2009), Ethiopia (2011 and 2015), Gabon (2009), Gambia (2006), Ghana (2007 and 2013), Guinea (2006), Guinea-Bissau (2006), Ivory Coast (2009), Kenya (2007 and 2013), Lesotho (2009), Liberia (2009), Madagascar (2009 and 2013), Malawi (2009 and 2014), Mali (2007 and 2010), Mauritania (2006 and 2014), Mauritius (2009), Mozambique (2007), Namibia (2006 and 2014), Niger (2009), Nigeria (2007 and 2014), Rwanda (2006 and 2011), Senegal (2007 and 2014), Sierra Leone (2009), South Africa (2007), South Sudan (2014), Eswatini (2006), Tanzania (2006 and 2013), Togo (2009), Uganda (2006 and 2013), Zambia (2007 and 2013), and Zimbabwe (2011).

American countries (31 countries): Antigua and Barbuda (2010), Argentina (2006 and 2010), Bahamas (2010), Barbados (2010), Belize (2010), Bolivia (2006 and 2010), Brazil (2009), Chile (2006 and 2010), Colombia (2006 and 2010), Costa Rica (2010), Dominica (2010), Dominican Republic (2010), Ecuador (2006 and 2010), El Salvador (2006 and 2010), Grenada (2006), Guatemala (2010), Guyana (2006 and 2010), Honduras (2006 and 2010), Jamaica (2010), Mexico (2006 and 2010), Nicaragua (2006 and 2010), Panama (2006 and 2010), Paraguay (2006 and 2010), Peru (2006 and 2010), St. Kitts and Nevis (2010), St. Lucia (2010), St. Vincent and the Grenadines (2010), Suriname (2009), Trinidad and Tobago (2010), Uruguay (2006 and 2010), and Venezuela (2006 and 2010).

Asian and Pacific countries (25 countries): Afghanistan (2008 and 2014), Bangladesh (2007 and 2013), Bhutan (2009 and 2015), Cambodia (2013 and 2016), China (2012), Fiji (2009), India (2014), Indonesia (2009 and 2015), Laos (2009, 2012, and 2016), Malaysia (2015), Micronesia (2009), Mongolia (2009 and 2013), Myanmar (2013), Nepal (2009 and 2013), Pakistan (2007 and 2013), Papua New Guinea (2015), the Philippines (2009 and 2015), Samoa (2009), Solomon Islands (2015), Sri Lanka (2011), Thailand (2016), Timor-Leste (2009 and 2015), Tonga (2009), Vanuatu (2009), and Vietnam (2009 and 2015).

Non-EU European countries (18 countries): Albania (2007 and 2013), Armenia (2009 and 2013), Azerbaijan (2009 and 2013), Belarus (2008 and 2013), Bosnia and Herzegovina (2009 and 2013), North Macedonia (2009 and 2013), Georgia (2008 and 2013), Kazakhstan (2009 and 2013), Kosovo (2009 and 2013), Kyrgyzstan (2009 and 2013), Moldova (2009 and 2013), Montenegro (2009 and 2013), Russia (2009 and 2012), Serbia (2009 and 2013), Tajikistan (2008 and 2013), Turkey (2008 and 2013), Ukraine (2008 and 2013), and Uzbekistan (2008 and 2013).

European Union countries (11 countries): Bulgaria (2007, 2009, and 2013), Croatia (2007 and 2013), Czech Republic (2009 and 2013), Estonia (2009 and 2013), Hungary (2009 and 2013), Latvia (2009 and 2013), Lithuania (2009 and 2013), Poland (2009 and 2013), Romania (2009 and 2013), Slovakia (2009 and 2013), and Slovenia (2009 and 2013).

Middle East countries (10 countries): Egypt (2013), Iraq (2011), Israel (2013), Jordan (2013), Lebanon (2013), Morocco (2013), Sudan (2014), Tunisia (2013), Palestine (2013), and Yemen (2010 and 2013).

The Freedom House index (civil liberties) in 1995

Rating 1 (5 countries): Barbados, Belize, Dominica, Micronesia, and St. Vincent and the Grenadines.

Rating 2 (24 countries): Bahamas, Benin, Botswana, Bulgaria, Cape Verde, Chile, Costa Rica, Czech Republic, Estonia, Grenada, Guyana, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Mauritius, Poland, Samoa, Slovenia, Solomon Islands, South Africa, St. Kitts and Nevis, St. Lucia, Trinidad and Tobago, and Uruguay.

Rating 3 (22 countries): Antigua and Barbuda, Argentina, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, El Salvador, Fiji, North Macedonia, Honduras, Israel, Jamaica, Malawi, Mali, Mongolia, Namibia, Panama, Paraguay, Romania, Slovakia, Suriname, Tonga, Vanuatu, and Venezuela.

Rating 4 (33 countries): Albania, Armenia, Bangladesh, Bolivia, Brazil, Burkina Faso, Central African Republic, Colombia, the Republic of the Congo, Croatia, Eritrea, Gabon, Ghana, Guinea-Bissau, India, Jordan, Kyrgyzstan, Lesotho, Madagascar, Mexico, Moldova, Mozambique, Nepal, Nicaragua, Papua New Guinea, Peru, the Philippines, Russia, Thailand, Timor-Leste, Uganda, Ukraine, and Zambia.

Rating 5 (22 countries): Belarus, Cameroon, Chad, Ethiopia, Georgia, Guatemala, Guinea, Ivory Coast, Kazakhstan, Lebanon, Malaysia, Morocco, Niger, Pakistan, Senegal, Sri Lanka, Eswatini, Tanzania, Togo, Tunisia, Turkey, and Zimbabwe.

Rating 6 (19 countries): Angola, Azerbaijan, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Cambodia, Djibouti, the Democratic Republic of the Congo, Egypt, Gambia, Indonesia, Kenya, Laos, Liberia, Mauritania, Montenegro, Rwanda, Serbia, Sierra Leone, Palestine, and Yemen.

Rating 7 (13 countries): Afghanistan, Bhutan, Burundi, China, Iraq, Kosovo, Myanmar, Nigeria, South Sudan, Sudan, Tajikistan, Uzbekistan, and Vietnam.

The democracy index in 1995 from Acemoglu et al. (Reference Acemoglu, Naidu, Restrepo and Robinson2019)

Democracies (78 countries): Albania, Antigua and Barbuda, Argentina, Armenia, Bahamas, Bangladesh, Barbados, Belize, Benin, Bolivia, Botswana, Brazil, Bulgaria, Cape Verde, Central African Republic, Chile, Colombia, the Republic of the Congo, Costa Rica, Czech Republic, Dominica, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, El Salvador, Estonia, Ethiopia, Fiji, North Macedonia, Georgia, Grenada, Guatemala, Guinea-Bissau, Guyana, Honduras, Hungary, India, Israel, Jamaica, Latvia, Lesotho, Lithuania, Madagascar, Malawi, Mali, Mauritius, Moldova, Mongolia, Mozambique, Namibia, Nepal, Nicaragua, Niger, Pakistan, Panama, Papua New Guinea, Paraguay, Peru, the Philippines, Poland, Romania, Russia, Slovakia, Slovenia, Solomon Islands, South Africa, Sri Lanka, St. Kitts and Nevis, St. Lucia, St. Vincent and the Grenadines, Suriname, Thailand, Trinidad and Tobago, Turkey, Ukraine, Uruguay, Vanuatu, Venezuela, and Zambia.

Non-democracies (54 countries): Afghanistan, Angola, Azerbaijan, Belarus, Bhutan, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cambodia, Cameroon, Chad, China, Croatia, Djibouti, the Democratic Republic of the Congo, Egypt, Eritrea, Gabon, Gambia, Ghana, Guinea, Indonesia, Iraq, Ivory Coast, Jordan, Kazakhstan, Kenya, Kosovo, Kyrgyzstan, Laos, Lebanon, Liberia, Malaysia, Mauritania, Mexico, Montenegro, Morocco, Myanmar, Nigeria, Rwanda, Samoa, Senegal, Serbia, Sierra Leone, Sudan, Eswatini, Tajikistan, Tanzania, Togo, Tonga, Tunisia, Uganda, Uzbekistan, Vietnam, Yemen, and Zimbabwe.

Table A1. The sample by regions

Table A2. The results from alternative democratic indicators

Table A3. The results from other services

Footnotes

*

We thank the editor Geoffrey Hodgson and three anonymous referees for helpful comments. We have benefitted from discussions with Eugene Bempong Nyantakyi, Brian Cushing, Stratford Douglas, and Sara E. Guffey.

1 For example, China joined the World Trade Organization (WTO) on December 11, 2001, and the Russian Federation joined the WTO on August 22, 2012.

2 Aidt et al. (Reference Aidt, Hillman and Liu2020) emphasise that it is not regions or countries but individuals who are corrupt. They examine the characteristics of Chinese government officials who received bribes and find that high-ranked officials were more likely to receive bribes.

3 We use the democracy index in 1995 from the Freedom House. We define 29 countries as fully democratic countries, 77 countries as partially democratic countries, and 32 as limited democratic countries. See Appendix II for detail.

4 We also report the results from the Polity5 and V-dem indices in the Appendix.

5 See also Paraioannou and van Zanden (Reference Paraioannou, van and Zanden2015) who find that long years of dictatorships have negative impacts on economic growth particularly in young countries.

6 Gauthier et al. (Reference Gauthier, Goyette and Kouaméc2021) empirically examine the determinants of demand- versus supply-side corruption by categorizing non-bribe paying firms into two groups: non-complying to requests versus non-paying for requests.

7 A firm's profit and the amount of bribes could be endogenously determined. See, for example, Bliss and Di Tella (Reference Bliss and Di Tella1997) who build a model in which both the equilibrium number of firms and the level of bribes are endogenously determined and show that bribery may not decline with the competition.

8 We can derive the following condition: ${{\partial ( {\partial b/\partial r} ) } \over {\partial t_{rr}}} = {{-t_rs_bs_{bb}} \over {{( {t_{rr}s_b^2 -t_rs_{bb}} ) }^2}} > 0$.

9 The data we use was released on September 6, 2016.

10 This is because all the firms in the Swedish sample reported that they did not pay bribes for tax inspection.

11 We organise the manufacturing and service industries into the following seven broad industries: (1) textile, leather, and garments; (2) food; (3) chemicals and plastic materials; (4) machinery; (5) wood and other manufacturing; (6) retail; wholesale, hotel and restaurants; and (7) all other service industries.

12 See Appendix II for the list of countries and survey years.

13 The results from bribe rates may suffer identification problems. Consider the most-used questionnaire item in the World Bank surveys, which asks ‘we've heard that establishments are sometimes required to make gifts or informal payments to public officials to get things done with regard to customs, taxes, licenses, regulations, services etc. On average, what percent of total annual sales, or estimated total annual value, do establishments like this one pay in informal payments or gifts to public officials for this purpose?’ From this item, we are unable to identify a type of public service (because it refers to various services at a time) and a certain firm (because it refers to establishments like yours).

14 Using data from the WBES, Jensen, Li, and Rahman (Reference Jensen, Li and Rahman2010) show that both at the national and firm levels, countries with lower levels of political freedom are more likely not to answer bribe-related questions and are more likely to provide false responses. Kraay and Murrell (Reference Kraay and Murrell2016) show that surveys tend to underestimate the prevalence of corruption because respondents are often reticent to tell the truth about sensitive subjects like corruption.

15 For similar reasons, Alm et al. (Reference Alm, Martinez-Vazquez and McClellan2016) use tax inspection data from the surveys, and Gauthier et al. (Reference Gauthier, Goyette and Kouaméc2021) use tax inspection and operation license application. We include all seven services because our theory is applicable to these services. For example, public officials can use the delay in granting an import license as a threat to firms' losses arising from the lost business opportunities.

16 We need to drop 4 countries when we use the index in Acemoglu et al. (Reference Acemoglu, Naidu, Restrepo and Robinson2019), 14 countries when we use the Polity2 index from the Center for Systemic Peace, and 11 countries when we use the V-Dem index from the University of Gothenburg.

17 See Appendix II for the list of countries by rating.

18 Here, we assume that the amount of bribes is small because the firm understands that it gets more and more difficult to reduce red tape by paying more bribes (s bb < 0).

19 See Svensson (Reference Svensson2003), Clarke and Xu (Reference Clarke and Xu2004), and Rand and Tarp (Reference Rand and Tarp2012) for firm-level variables and Shleifer and Vishny (Reference Shleifer and Vishny1993), Svensson (Reference Svensson2005), and Fisman and Miguel (Reference Fisman and Miguel2007) for country-level variables. Appendix I reports the complete list of the control variables.

20 The results from the Probit and Logit models are similar to our OLS results. Thus, to save space, we do not report the results.

21 See Appendix I for the definitions of the firm-level variables and country-specific macroeconomic variables.

22 We use the chi-squared test and examine if we can reject the null hypothesis that the coefficients on red tape in columns (1)–(3) from the sub-samples are identical. We reject the null hypothesis at the 1% confidence level when we test 0.013 in column (1) versus 0.037 in column (2) and test 0.013 in column (1) versus 0.048 in column (3). We cannot reject the null hypothesis at the 10% confidence level when we test 0.037 in column (2) versus 0.048 in column (3). We can reject the null hypothesis at the 10% confidence level when we test 0.031 in column (4) and 0.048 in column (5).

23 We report the results from the Freedom House index using both the survey year and ten years prior to it, as well as those from the Polity5 and V-Dem indices.

24 See Table A3 in the Appendix for other public services.

25 Here, our outcome bribe payment indicator variable is firm- and service-specific (p is).

26 See Table 5 in Oster (Reference Oster2019).

27 Although the Freedom House ranked Uruguay and Chile in the same rating of democracy, we find a positive correlation from Chile. Chile's democratisation process began in 1990; however, González et al. (Reference González, Muñoz and Prem2021) show that the democratisation changed the distribution of de jure political power but has limited changes in de facto political power.

28 Batra et al. (Reference Batra, Kaufmann and Stone2003) find that private firms are more likely to bribe, pay a higher revenue share as bribes, and more likely to consider bribery as an obstacle. Clarke and Xu (Reference Clarke and Xu2004) find that SOE workers in the utility sector are more likely to accept bribes.

Notes: (1) See Appendix II for the country list. (2) We use the Freedom House index and Acemoglu et al. (Reference Acemoglu, Naidu, Restrepo and Robinson2019) for the democracy index. (3) GDP per capita, PPP (current international $) is from the World Development Indicators.

Notes: Columns (1) and (2) use the Freedom House index from 10 years before the WBES survey year. Countries with an index value of 1–2 from 10 years before the WBES survey year are democratic countries. Columns (3) and (4) use the Freedom House index from the survey year. Countries with an index value of 1–2 are democratic countries. Columns (5) and (6) use the polity2 index from the Polity IV project. The index classifies regimes from −10 to +10. Countries with a Polity2 index value from 6 to 10 are democratic countries. Columns (7) and (8) use the liberal democracy index from the Varieties of Democracy (V-Dem) database. Countries with an electoral democracy index greater than 0.5 are democratic countries.

Notes: See column (1) Table 4.

References

Acemoglu, D., Naidu, S., Restrepo, P. and Robinson, J.A. (2019) Democracy does cause growth. Journal of Political Economy 127(1), 47100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adserà, A., Boix, C. and Payne, M. (2003) Are you being served? Political accountability and quality of government. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization 19(2), 445490.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aidt, T.S. (2003) Economic analysis of corruption: A survey. Economic Journal 113(491), F632F652.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aidt, T.S., Hillman, A.L. and Liu, Q. (2020) Who takes bribes and how much? Evidence from the China corruption conviction databank. World Development 133, 104985.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aidt, T., Dutta, J. and Sena, V. (2008) Governance regimes, corruption and growth: Theory and evidence. Journal of Comparative Economics 36, 195220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alexeev, M. and Song, Y. (2013) Corruption and product market competition: An empirical investigation. Journal of Development Economics 103, 154166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alm, J., Martinez-Vazquez, J. and McClellan, C. (2016) Corruption and firm tax evasion. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 124, 146163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Altonji, J.G., Elder, T.E. and Taber, C.R. (2005a) An evaluation of instrumental variable strategies for estimating the effects of catholic schooling. Journal of Human Resources 40, 791821.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Altonji, J.G., Elder, T.E. and Taber, C.R. (2005b) Selection on observed and unobserved variables: Assessing the effectiveness of catholic schools. Journal of Political Economy 113(1), 151184.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bai, C.E., Hsieh, C.T. and Song, Z. (2019) Special deals with Chinese characteristics. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 34(1), 341379.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Batra, G., Kaufmann, D. and Stone, A.H.W. (2003) Investment Climate Around the World: Voices of the Firms from the World Business Environment Survey. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bliss, C. and Di Tella, R. (1997) Does competition kill corruption? Journal of Political Economy 105(5), 10011023.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clarke, G.R. and Xu, L.C. (2004) Privatization, competition, and corruption: How characteristics of bribe takers and payers affect bribes to utilities. Journal of Public Economics 88, 20672097.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diaby, A. and Sylwester, K. (2015) Corruption and market competition: Evidence from post-communist countries. World Development 66, 487499.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamond, L. (1991) Political corruption: Nigeria's perennial struggle. Journal of Democracy 2(4), 7385.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ehrlich, I. and Lui, F.T. (1999) Bureaucratic corruption and endogenous economic growth. Journal of Political Economy 107(S6), S270–S293. https://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/250111CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisman, R. and Miguel, E. (2007) Corruption, norms, and legal enforcement: Evidence from diplomatic parking tickets. Journal of Political Economy 115, 10201048.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freund, C., Hallward-Driemeier, M. and Rijkers, B. (2016) Deals and delays: Firm-level evidence on corruption and policy implementation times. World Bank Economic Review 30(2), 354382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gauthier, B., Goyette, J. and Kouaméc, W.A.K. (2021) Why do firms pay bribes? Evidence on the demand and supply sides of corruption in developing countries. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 190, 463479.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
González, F., Muñoz, P. and Prem, M. (2021) Lost in transition? The persistence of dictatorship mayors. Journal of Development Economics 151, 102669.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Head, K., Mayer, T. and Ries, J. (2010) The erosion of colonial trade linkages after independence. Journal of International Economics 81(1), 114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, N., Li, Q. and Rahman, A. (2010) Understanding corruption and firm responses in cross-national firm-level surveys. Journal of International Business Studies 41(9), 14811504.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kar, S., Pritchett, L., Roy, S. and Sen, K. (2022) Doing business in a deals world: The doubly false premise of rules reform. Journal of Economic Policy Reform 25(4), 361387.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaufmann, D. and Wei, S.J. (1999) Does grease money speed up the wheels of commerce? IMF Working Paper 00/64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kraay, A. and Murrell, P. (2016) Misunderestimating corruption. Review of Economics and Statistics 98(3), 455466.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leys, C. (1965) What is the problem about corruption? Journal of Modern African Studies 3(2), 215230.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lui, Francis T. (1985) An equilibrium queuing model of bribery. Journal of Political Economy 93(4), 760781.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martinez-Bravo, M., Mukherjee, P. and Stegmann, A. (2017) The non-democratic roots of elite capture: Evidence from Soeharto mayors in Indonesia. Econometrica 85(6), 19912010.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Melitz, M.J. (2003) The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica 71(6), 16951725.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Méndez, F. and Sepúlveda, F. (2006) Corruption, growth and political regimes: Cross country evidence. European Journal of Political Economy 22, 8298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oster, E. (2019) Unobservable selection and coefficient stability: Theory and evidence. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 37(2), 187204.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Papaioannou, E. and Siourounis, G. (2008) Democratisation and growth. Economic Journal 118, 15201551.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paraioannou, K.J. and van, and Zanden, J.L. (2015) The dictator effect: How long years in office affect economic development. Journal of Institutional Economics 11(1), 111139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pertiwi, K. and Ainsworth, S. (2021) Democracy is the cure?: Evolving constructions of corruption in Indonesia 1994–2014. Journal of Business Ethics 173, 507523.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rand, J. and Tarp, F. (2012) Firm-level corruption in Vietnam. Economic Development and Cultural Change 60(3), 571595.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1999) Corruption and Government: Causes, Consequences, and Reform. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saha, S. and Sen, K. (2021) The corruption–growth relationship: Does the political regime matter? Journal of Institutional Economics 17(2), 243266.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R.W. (1993) Corruption. Quarterly Journal of Economics 108(3), 599617.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svensson, J. (2003) Who must pay bribes and how much? Evidence from a cross section of firms. Quarterly Journal of Economics 118(1), 207230.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svensson, J. (2005) Eight questions about corruption. Journal of Economic Perspectives 19(3), 1942.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Treisman, D. (2000) The causes of corruption: A cross-national study. Journal of Public Economics 76(3), 399457.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Red tape by bribe payment status.Notes: (1) There are four government services: tax inspections (tax), construction permits (con), import licenses (imp), and operation licenses (ope). There are three utility services: electrical connections (ele), telephone connections (tel), and water connections (wtr). (2) Red tape is the normalised log number of wait days or authority visits for each country.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Red tape and the share of bribe givers by democracy index.Notes: (1) We use the data from tax audits. (2) Red tape is the normalised log number of tax audit visits for each country. (3) We define 29 (32) countries as full democracies (limited democracies) if their Freedom House index (civil liberties, 1995) is 1–2 (6–7). We define the remaining 77 countries as partial democracies. (4) The slope of the fitted line is 0.012 (standard error clustered at the country level is 0.004) in Panel A, 0.036 (standard error clustered at the country level is 0.011) in Panel B, and that is 0.048 (standard error clustered at the country level is 0.014) in Panel C.

Figure 2

Table 1. Summary statistics of corruption variables

Figure 3

Table 2. Summary statistics of key explanatory variables

Figure 4

Figure 3. The theoretical relationship between red tape and penalty rate.Notes: The solid vertical line is a situation where a firm is imposed a one-standard deviation more or less red tape by an authority.

Figure 5

Table 3. Red tape and propensity to pay bribes

Figure 6

Table 4. The results with fixed effects

Figure 7

Table 5. Oster's (2019) bias-adjusted coefficient

Figure 8

Table 6. Propensity to pay bribes for selected countries

Figure 9

Figure 4. The Freedom House index and country-level estimates on β2 from tax inspection.Notes: The bottom and top values of the boxes are the 25th percentile and 75th percentile values, respectively.

Figure 10

Table 7. Summary statistics for country-level estimates on β2

Figure 11

Table A1. The sample by regions

Figure 12

Table A2. The results from alternative democratic indicators

Figure 13

Table A3. The results from other services