Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-lj6df Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-19T01:25:31.316Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Child obesity: what can be done and who will do it?

Symposium on ‘Behavioural nutrition and energy balance in the young’

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 August 2008

Tim Lobstein*
Affiliation:
International Obesity TaskForce of the International Association for the Study of Obesity, 231 North Gower Street, London NW1 2NR, UK
*
Corresponding author: Dr Tim Lobstein, fax +44 207 387 6033, email tlobstein@iaso.org
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Among the measures recommended by the WHO to reduce the risk of obesity and non-communicable disease, the consumption of a diet rich in micronutrients but with a relatively-low energy density features prominently. However, only a small percentage of the UK population (<1) appears to be consuming the recommended diet. Dietary behaviour is strongly influenced by the dietary environment, shaped by food supplies, investment policies and advertising, to create an obesogenic food market. Substantial resources have been invested in food production of a sort that does not promote better health; agriculture and food supply sectors have benefited from decades of public-sector support, but this practice has encouraged the production of meat, dairy, oils and sugar and the withdrawal from sale of fruit, vegetables and fish. The result is an ‘obesogenic economy’, i.e. a market economy that encourages weight gain, in which children are a prime target. Interventions in the obesogenic market need to be considered and several opportunities are described in the present paper. Recent moves to strengthen national and international food policies aimed to promote healthier behaviour have been undertaken, but they will need political support if they are to be fully implemented. Alliances of public health interests can help to create that political support and promote health-enhancing environments.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Author 2008

The present paper argues that current dietary patterns are falling far short of those needed for health, and that market mechanisms do not encourage industry to make the major investments needed to ensure that populations are able to meet healthy eating targets. Policy interventions are required that can change the food supply through influencing the market. A focus on children can help to persuade policy-makers to take action.

Although the extent of the change required is not easy to establish, analyses of food balance sheets from twenty-nine Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development developed economies(Reference Srinivasan, Irz and Shankar1, 2) indicate that only approximately one-quarter of countries are likely to meet the WHO recommendations(3) for adult population intakes for fat, or for sugar, or for fruit and vegetables (see Table 1).

Table 1. Levels of fat, sugar and fruit and vegetable consumption in Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development countries (data from Srinivasan et al. (Reference Srinivasan, Irz and Shankar1) and Food and Agriculture Organization(2))

* Values are those achieving dietary guidelines: <30% dietary energy from fat; <10% dietary energy from sugars, >780 g per capita per d supplied fruit and vegetables (equivalent to consumption of >400 g per capita per d(Reference Lobstein and James6)); <61 g animal fat per capita per d (equivalent to saturated fat consumption of <10% dietary energy(Reference Lobstein and James6)).

Food balance sheets report what is marketed for consumption (rather than what is actually consumed) but nutrient intake surveys also indicate that only a small proportion of adults are meeting population targets. Typically, when one dietary target is being reached, such as that for fat, individuals may fail to achieve another target, such as that for sugar; i.e. the ‘Jack Sprat’ problem:

Jack Sprat would eat no fat
His wife would eat no lean
And so betwixt the two of them
They meet the recommended adult population mean!
Anonymous

In the 1987 survey of UK dietary intakes of British adults, fewer than one per 1000 was meeting four dietary targets (for fat, saturated fat, sugar and dietary fibre)(Reference Mills4). Data from the UK National Diet and Nutrition Survey of Adults, 2000–2001(5), show an improvement; however, further analysis shows that seven adults per 1000 were likely to be eating a diet that met the recommendations for health in terms of five specific criteria (see Table 2).

Table 2. Percentage of UK adults eating healthy diets (from Food Standards Agency and National Statistical Office(5))

NME, non-milk extrinsic.

Trends in food supplies are only partially encouraging. The supply of fruit and vegetables is rising in many developed countries, but the supply of fats and overall food energy is also rising, to the detriment of traditionally-healthy diets, such as the Mediterranean diet. For example, food supplies in Italy in 1965 provided (g per capita per d) approximately 720 fruit and vegetables, 38 saturated fat and 90 total fat(Reference Lobstein and James6), which reflects a Mediterranean diet with adequate fruit and vegetables and relatively low levels of fats. By the year 2000, Italy enjoyed a fruit and vegetable supply of 860 g per capita per d, but the animal-fat supply had risen dramatically to 70 g per capita per d and the total fat to 152 g per capita per d. Health policy-makers can immediately see that this trend is in the wrong direction. For health services, it may be time to train more heart surgeons!

An obesogenic economy

In a perfect market economists might argue that food supplies would be completely ‘demand-led’, meaning that the supply chain would reflect the changing tastes and demands of consumers. Fat and sugar supplies would rise simply because individuals want more sweet and fatty products in their diet. The economists might say that they only supply what the consumers want, but there are several reasons why the market is not that simple. The first is that food companies spend a large amount of their income trying to influence what the consumer wants. Data from the UK in 2003 show that food companies spent >£740×106 on marketing their products(7), mostly high in fats, sugar and/or salt, and low in fresh fruit or vegetables. On the other hand, only approximately £7×106 was spent by government on promoting healthy diets.

Second, there is considerable government funding to support, and hence distort, the food marketplace. In Europe, for example, the Common Agricultural Policy has been spending between €30×109 and €40×109 annually for four decades, much of which has been used to ensure high levels of production of meat, grain for animal feed, milk, butter and cheese, sugar and oil (see Fig. 1)(Reference Schäfer8). The relatively small budget for fruit and vegetable production is partly used to pay for the destruction of fruit and vegetables (through market withdrawal, green harvesting and non-harvesting) to protect producers and maintain high market prices(9). A similar policy operates for fish, whereby much of the catch may be destroyed to protect markets(10).

Fig. 1. The distribution of Common Agricultural Policy funds across food sectors. (From European Commission(27).)

Food industries are the main purchasers of these commodities from agriculture. They have the role of developing the commodities into profitable goods and promoting these goods on the market. Large investments are put into the production and distribution of these types of foods, such as bottling plants for soft drinks, distributed through refrigerated cabinets in every corner shop and chains of fast-food outlets. The process is easily seen when new opportunities arise as they did in Eastern Europe in the 1990s. There, approximately US $5×109 investment capital from the big international companies was spent on developing the food sector in the late 1990s, of which 60% was for soft drinks and confectionery(11).

Capital investment in farming and food production is tax deductible, and so are the marketing costs for promoting mass-produced foods and beverages. Producers do not pay for the environmental pollution costs, road or airport construction costs or the costs of traffic accidents and injuries resulting from the extensive freighting of food commodities, nor the environmental costs from food packaging and waste disposal, nor many of the regulatory costs (e.g. veterinary control measures, food inspections) and a host of other consequential costs(Reference Robertson, Tirado, Lobstein, Jermini, Knai, Jensen, Ferro-Luzzi and James12). This externalisation of production and marketing costs generally brings greatest benefit to the larger-scale ‘factory’ farmers and mass-producers of more-processed lower-nutrient foods in place of fresh local produce(Reference Pretty, Ball, Lang and Morison13).

Furthermore, the marketplace is not a balanced one between the producer and the consumer. When it comes to purchasing power, some consumers have more power than others; for example, the manufacturers of processed food are the ‘consumers’ of much of the primary agricultural produce from farmers and from commodity importers. The supermarket chains are also the ‘consumers’ of the products of farms as well as purchasing the output of processed food manufacturers. Between them, manufacturers and retailers make their corporate purchasing choices based on price and volume, not nutritional quality; indeed, most companies are legally bound to pursue financial competitive success and to provide investment returns on behalf of their shareholders before any consideration of wider social policies(14).

Similar arguments apply to catering outlets, including restaurants and fast-food chains, but also caterers in the workplace and public sector services, who purchase substantial quantities of the food passing along the food chain, choosing what they put on their menus and basing their choices on economic rather than nutritional criteria.

Even at household level, the individual who does the shopping may be making choices for several other members of the household, particularly when it comes to children's food, and may need to take account of price and availability, cultural and personal needs as well as purely nutritional criteria when making purchasing choices. Thus, the actual ‘consumer’, the individual who eats the food, plays only a minor role in shaping what is available to them and may have little or no influence on the nutritional qualities of the food coming from the farmers and growers. This situation is especially true for children.

Other distortions can also be noted. From the farmers' point of view, the best income is received from crops and livestock that have high yields, are disease-resistant, can be harvested easily and have other technical advantages(Reference Zepeda15). Subsidies aside, farmers are rewarded for the market value of what they produce, not for the nutritional quality of their products(16).

Food technologies can give advantages to processed foods over fresh foods. Food preservation techniques, once a valuable means of ensuring food supplies during times of scarcity, are widely used by manufacturers to supply food at a lower cost and with a longer shelf-life compared with fresh perishable food(Reference Shafiur17). This practice reduces the price of mass-produced food and can give such food a market advantage. Similarly, colouring and flavouring agents are used to increase the attractiveness of foods; these cosmetic additives are particularly appealing to children and are found in many foods that are marketed to children(Reference Fitzhugh and Lobstein18), but they may also provide a potentially unfair marketing advantage to the manufacturers of processed foods over the suppliers of fresh less-processed foods.

These distortions in the market put important barriers between the supplier of healthier foods and the consumer who might want to eat them. They add to the difficulties consumers face, making it hard for ‘the healthiest choices to be the easiest choices’. These market distortions must be tackled if dietary health is to be taken seriously. Several measures can be suggested to help to balance the marketplace more fairly in favour of healthier nutrition.

Steps to counter the obesogenic marketplace

Many policies can be implemented to help change the current food supply trends to encourage better health. Some examples are:

  1. 1. review the assistance provided from the public purse for food research and technology. In particular, prioritise research into improved nutritional profiles of agricultural produce, and prioritise the supply of fresh perishable foods so that they can better compete with highly-processed long-shelf-life foods, e.g. by increasing production in localised small horticultural units, improve the development of cold chains and small food preparation units;

  2. 2. internalise the externalised costs of production; for example, requiring the producers to bear the full costs of environmental pollution caused by intensive farming practices and long-haul food miles, which are currently paid from public funds;

  3. 3. remove tax-deductible marketing expenses for energy-dense micronutrient-poor foods, to ensure that companies pay full costs for the promotion of these foods. This measure should be designed to help smaller producers of more-nutritious foods to gain access to the market;

  4. 4. improve market feedback. The long food chain from farmer to processor to supermarket to shopper prevents effective feedback. For farmers to be more aware of consumers' needs and preferences there needs to be better support for consumer advocacy agencies; from public funds if necessary;

  5. 5. introduce clear front-of-pack ‘traffic light’ labelling information to ensure that consumers are making properly informed decisions. The move may initially need public support for consumer education;

  6. 6. make greater use of public purchasing power. Local and national authorities purchase ⩽25% of all food and have sufficient contractual power to improve food quality for their clients, and thereby reduce the production costs of better food products, strengthening their position in the market;

  7. 7. provide explicit marketing advantages for better products; for example, by sponsoring health award schemes, promoting nutrition-friendly schools' suppliers and identifying better private-sector caterers. Equally, poorly-performing suppliers and caterers can be named-and-shamed; for example, on dedicated web sites;

  8. 8. review the use of non-nutritive additives in foods. The claim that a colouring or flavouring provides a ‘technological purpose’ simply because it gives a marketing advantage to a product should not be allowed as a justification for the use of a non-nutritive additive;

  9. 9. control investment in food supplies; for example, consider whether any categories of food can be designated as special national, regional or local dishes or components so that they might be protected from competing products with lower standards;

  10. 10. consider the opportunities within the Sanitary and Phytosanitary Instruments that can be invoked under the World Trade Organization Agreement, which permits the restriction of food imports if they pose a possible threat to health, justifiable scientifically(19). Products containing high levels of salt, saturated fats or trans-fats might be susceptible to this approach;

  11. 11. review development aid; consider withholding local, regional or external development assistance to projects that undermine nutrition and physical activity policies. Consider providing development aid to investment programmes that promote healthier food supplies;

  12. 12. use Codex (an international regulating body set up jointly by the WHO and FAO to assist trade in food products) to improve international trading standards(20). For example, ensure Codex standard-setting activities support high-quality food supplies, do not undermine national standards, accept precautionary principles for health protection and promote labelling requirements that assist healthy choices;

  13. 13. strengthen moves by the WHO to implement healthier food supplies. The regional Food and Nutrition Action Plan(21) and Obesity Charter(22) have been accepted by all governments, but need political support to be implemented;

  14. 14. control advertising to children so that health messages are consistent with public health policies. UK regulations on TV advertising need strengthening and new measures on non-broadcast advertising need to be introduced;

  15. 15. strengthen children's rights; support moves to extend the Rights of the Child(23) to include freedom from commercial inducements that are detrimental to good health.

Alliances for health

The current economic and political climate has emphasised relatively unrestricted economic growth and free producer access to markets with little concern for the health effects of these economic policies. Political pressure is needed to change the status quo, and political pressure increases if organisations can form alliances to achieve their ends.

In support of the WHO's moves to protect children's health and promote the regional obesity strategy, the International Association for the Study of Obesity, in alliance with Consumers International, has proposed an International Code of Marketing Food and Beverages to Children(24). Further alliances of health professionals and other bodies are also being sought, e.g. with paediatricians, nutritionists, diabetologists and cardiologists. The intention is to develop common strategies and action plans at local as well as global level.

Broader alliances can also be considered. The changes in diet needed to meet the WHO guidelines(3) (e.g. reduced meat consumption and greater consumption of plant-based foods) bear close similarities to those promoted by environmental specialists and proponents of more-sustainable agricultural production(Reference Pimentel, Westra and Noss25). It also complies with the changes called for by organisations promoting animal welfare(Reference Gold26), while greater reliance on local production can support rural development and reduce road use. The opportunities for a coherent movement to promote public health are numerous, and everyone can play a role in building that movement.

Last, the present paper has focused on food supplies, but similar arguments could be made for the built environment, which can also be described in terms of an obesogenic marketplace. Interventions can be considered in various forms; for example, by looking at transport subsidies, the hidden costs of road use (accidents, pollution, lost amenities), car taxation and bicycle subsidisation. A child's environment contains many incentives for sedentary behaviour, including multiple television channels, video games, home movies and use of the internet, and market interventions here may be justified. Parts of the built environment are not directly market-driven, and in this respect interventions can be made directly; for example, grants for active-transport-friendly redesign of junctions, pedestrianisation of neighbourhoods and the creation and improvement of open spaces.

In conclusion, it can be seen that the present-day environment for children and adults alike is rich with inducements for sedentary behaviour and for the consumption of processed energy-dense foods and less fresh food. Policy-makers have certain tools available to change these environments, and a focus on children's limited ability to select the healthier choices for themselves creates a political pressure for change. Advocacy organisations concerned with public health, consumer and family issues, in conjunction perhaps with those groups seeking greener environments and less meat production, may find common cause through the promotion of children's wellbeing and convince policy-makers of the need to act.

Acknowledgements

The author is grateful for discussions with Mark Suhrke of the WHO concerning economic interventions. The views expressed here are the author's alone.

The author declares no conflicts of interest. He is employed by the International Obesity TaskForce of the International Association for the Study of Obesity (www.iaso.org), which is a not-for-profit professional body that has ethical policies regarding corporate donations.

References

1.Srinivasan, CS, Irz, X & Shankar, B (2006) An assessment of the potential consumption impacts of WHO dietary norms in OECD countries. Food Policy 31, 5377.Google Scholar
2.Food and Agriculture Organization (2006) Food balance sheets 1963–2003. http://faostat.fao.org/site/502/default.aspx (accessed September 2006).Google Scholar
3.World Health Organization (2002) Diet, Nutrition and the Prevention of Chronic Diseases. Joint WHO/FAO Expert Consultation. WHO Technical Report Series no. 916. Geneva: WHO.Google Scholar
4.Mills, A (1994) Dietary and Nutritional Survey of British Adults: Further Analysis. London: H. M. Stationery Office.Google Scholar
5.Food Standards Agency and National Statistical Office (2005) National Diet and Nutrition Survey: Adults aged 19 to 64 years, 2000–2001. First edition data set released 03.05.2005. http://www.data-archive.ac.uk/findingData/snDescription.asp?sn=5140 (accessed June 2007).Google Scholar
6.Lobstein, T & James, WPT (2003) Can food supplies meet nutritional targets? Ann Nutr Metab 47, 428429.Google Scholar
7.Department of Health (2004) Choosing Health. Making Healthy Choices Easier. London: The Stationery Office.Google Scholar
8.Schäfer, Elinder L (2005) Obesity, hunger, and agriculture: the damaging role of subsidies. Br Med J 331, 13331336.Google Scholar
9.European Commission (2007) CAP reform: Fruit and vegetable reform will raise competitiveness, protect producers from crisis, increase consumption, improve environmental protection and simplify rules. http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=IP/07/75&format=HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=enGoogle Scholar
10.European Commission (2008) About the Common Fisheries Policy: Reducing by-catches and eliminating discards. http://ec.europa.eu/fisheries/cfp/management_resources/conservation_measures/reducing_by_catches_en.htmGoogle Scholar
11.Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (1998) Impediments to Efficiency in the Agro-food Chain in Bulgaria, Romania and Slovenia, Agricultural. Policy Paper no. 1998–02. CCNM/AGR/PP(98)50. Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
12.Robertson, A, Tirado, C, Lobstein, T, Jermini, M, Knai, C, Jensen, JH, Ferro-Luzzi, A & James, WPT(editors) (2004) Food security and sustainable development. In Food and Health in Europe: A New Basis for Action. World Health Organization Regional Publications European Series no. 96, pp. 155219. Copenhagen: WHO Regional Office for Europe; available at http://www.euro.who.int/document/E82161.pdf.Google ScholarPubMed
13.Pretty, JN, Ball, AS, Lang, T & Morison, JIL (2005) Farm costs and food miles: An assessment of the full cost of the UK weekly food basket. Food Policy 30, 119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
14.UK Parliament (2006) The Companies Act 1985 (Small Companies' Accounts and Audit) Regulations 2006. Statutory Instrument 2006 no. 2782. London: The Stationery Office.Google Scholar
15.Zepeda, L (2001) Agricultural Investment and Productivity in Developing Countries. FAO Economic and Social Development Paper no. 148. Rome: FAO.Google Scholar
16.Department for Environment, Food and Rural Affairs and National Statistics Office (2008) Joint announcement by the Agricultural Departments of the United Kingdom. Provisional estimates of farm incomes. Press release 31 January 2008. http://statistics.defra.gov.uk/esg/statnot/account.pdf (accessed June 2008).Google Scholar
17.Shafiur, Rahman M (2007) Handbook of Food Preservation, 2nd ed. London and Boca Raton: CRC Press.Google Scholar
18.Fitzhugh, K & Lobstein, T (2000) Children's Food Examined – An Examination of the Nutritional Values of 358 Foods Aimed at Children. London: The Food Commission.Google Scholar
19.World Trade Organization (2008) Understanding the WTO: the agreements. Standards and safety. http://www.wto.org/english/thewto_e/whatis_e/tif_e/agrm4_e.htm (accessed June 2008).Google Scholar
20.World Health Organization and Food and Agriculture Organization (2008) Codex alimentarius. http://www.codexalimentarius.net/web/index_en.jsp (accessed June 2008).Google Scholar
21.World Health Organization Regional Office for Europe (2007) The Second WHO European Action Plan for Food and Nutrition Policy 2007–2012. Adopted at the European Regional World Health Assembly, Belgrade, 19 September 2007. http://www.euro.who.int/document/RC57/epres_nut.pdfGoogle Scholar
22.World Health Organization Regional Office for Europe (2006) European Charter on Counteracting Obesity. Adopted at the WHO European Ministerial Conference on Counteracting Obesity, Istanbul, 17 November 2006. http://www.euro.who.int/Document/E89567.pdfGoogle Scholar
23.Office of the United Nations Commissioner for Human Rights (1989) Convention on the Rights of the Child. http://www.unicef.org/crc/Google Scholar
24.International Association for the Study of Obesity and Consumers International (2008) An International Code of Marketing of Food and Beverages to Children. London: IASO and CI; available at http://www.iotf.org/IASOmarketingreleaseMarch1508.htmGoogle Scholar
25.Pimentel, D, Westra, L & Noss, RF (2000) Ecological Integrity: Integrating Environment, Conservation and Health. Washington, DC: Island Press.Google Scholar
26.Gold, M (2004) The Global Benefits of Eating Less Meat. A Report to Compassion in World Farming. Petersfield, Hants.: CWF.Google Scholar
27.European Commission (2006) 35th Financial Report, European Agricultural Guidance and Guarantee Fund Guarantee Section. COM(2006) 512 final. Brussels: European Commission.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Levels of fat, sugar and fruit and vegetable consumption in Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development countries (data from Srinivasan et al.(1) and Food and Agriculture Organization(2))

Figure 1

Table 2. Percentage of UK adults eating healthy diets (from Food Standards Agency and National Statistical Office(5))

Figure 2

Fig. 1. The distribution of Common Agricultural Policy funds across food sectors. (From European Commission(27).)