Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-pjpqr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-06T17:37:10.742Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Buy-ins, buy-outs, longevity bonds, and the creation of value

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  10 August 2023

Richard MacMinn*
Affiliation:
Department of Information, Risk, and Operations Management, McCombs Schools of Business, The University of Texas, Austin, Texas, USA, and Risk and Insurance Research Center, National Chengchi University, Taipei, Taiwan
Yijia Lin
Affiliation:
Department of Finance, College of Business, University of Nebraska, Lincoln, Nebraska, USA
Tianxiang Shi
Affiliation:
Department of Risk, Actuarial Science, and Legal Studies, Fox School of Business, Temple University, Philadelphia, PA 19122, USA
*
Corresponding author: Richard MacMinn; Email: richard@macminn.org

Abstract

Longevity risk is the risk that people on average will live longer than expected. That potential increase in life expectancy exposes corporations and pension funds to the risk of having insufficient funds to pay a more extended stream of annuity benefits. Buy-ins, buy-outs, and longevity bonds provide pension funds with insurance and financial market instruments to hedge their longevity risk. The most straightforward instruments and the most robust markets are currently for buy-ins and buy-outs. The model developed here shows that these instruments transfer value to pension holders and, other things being equal, would not be used by firms since shareholder value is reduced. The analysis, however, also shows that these instruments can be used to solve the under-investment problem created by underfunded pension plans and so increase not only the pension fund value but also the corporate stock value.

Type
Research Paper
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain 2023

1. Introduction

One of the largest sources of risk faced by corporations and their pension funds is longevity risk. Longevity risk is the risk that members of a population might live longer on average than expected. For example, suppose the population is a pool of annuitants. In that case, longevity risk is the risk that annuitants live longer on average than predicted in the mortality tables, which are used to price the annuities. Longevity risk is an important problem because of the uncertainty associated with longevity projections and the large number of liabilities exposed to longevity risk. The uncertainty of longevity projections is illustrated by the fact that life expectancy for men aged 60 was more than five years longer in 2005 than it was predicted to be in mortality projections made in the 1980s.Footnote 1 The amounts at risk are illustrated by the U.S. defined benefit plans that have been estimated to be valued at approximately 2.2 trillion dollars in 2007Footnote 2 and to cover 42 million participants. Swiss Re estimates that the total global exposure to longevity risk is approximately $21 trillion.Footnote 3

Exposure to longevity risk is a serious issue, yet traditionally, corporations and pension funds have had few means of managing it. Until recently, longevity risks were not securitized, and there were no longevity derivatives that these institutions could use to hedge their longevity risk exposures. This state of affairs has changed, and the new life market for longevity-linked financial instruments is continuing to develop.Footnote 4 However, the new life markets have been slow to grow due to agency costs associated with the securitization of longevity risk, e.g., see Zelenko (Reference Zelenko2014) and MacMinn and Brockett (Reference MacMinn and Brockett2017). In the interim, insurers and reinsurers have provided a means of transferring longevity risks through instruments such as buy-ins and buy-outs. These instruments transfer longevity and other risks from the corporate pension fund to the insurer. The buy-in or buy-out transfers the pension liability from the corporation to the insurer for a fee, and the insurer assumes the longevity and other risks associated with the pension fund. If the corporation must issue debt to finance the buy-in or buy-out, that corporation replaces the random liability with a known fixed payment on the bond. There are other instruments designed to hedge the longevity risk, including longevity swaps and q-forward contracts.Footnote 5 The swap pays the difference between the indemnity payoff and the index payoff at each date, while the q-forward exchanges the risky payoff then with a certain payoff, much like the buy-in or buy-out.

Interest in the notion of longevity risk and survivor or longevity bonds was initiated by Blake and Burrows (Reference Blake and Burrows2001). The literature on mortality and longevity risks and capital market instruments designed to hedge those risks has grown significantly since then. In 2003 Swiss Re successfully introduced a mortality-based security designed to hedge mortality changes in its life book of business. The concern was mortality risk, i.e., the risk of premature death. Since then, mortality bonds have become standard instruments for transferring mortality risk to the capital markets. The development of financial instruments to hedge longevity risk has generated academic and institutional interest. Longevity bonds have been designed but never issued due to a lack of demand. Forward contracts designed to hedge longevity risk have also lacked sufficient demand to make a market. On the other hand, buy-ins and buy-outs have been used by corporations to transfer longevity risk and so have generated an active market for longevity risk transfer.

Several reasons have been proposed for the failure of most longevity risk transfer instruments, including longevity bonds and q-forwards, etc. Blake et al. (Reference Blake, Cairns and Dowd2006) provides several possible reasons for the failure of longevity bonds. The reasons include (i) too short a time horizon on the bond to create an effective hedge, (ii) an excessive capital cost imposed on the hedgers, (iii) longevity risk that was transferred to a reinsurer rather than the capital markets, (iv) credit risk that would rest with the hedgers, and (v) too much basis risk relative to the price. These are primarily comments about the design of the longevity bond. While also noting basis risk, Lin and Cox (Reference Lin and Cox2008) provide a different rationale for these failures; they price the 2003 Mortality bond provided by Swiss Re through the special purpose vehicle Vita Capital I and then use the same model to price the European Investment Bank's longevity bond issue. They find that the risk premium in the mortality bond is less than that in the longevity bond. More importantly, the latter's high-risk premium was higher than the premium required by reinsurers, and so they claim that the high premium effectively caused the market failure. Chen and Cummins (Reference Chen and Cummins2010) also build a pricing model but claim that previous failures were due to design flaws; their model provides the same type of tail protection for hedgers as found in the mortality bond. Finally, Zelenko (Reference Zelenko2014), who was involved in the design and construction of the two attempted longevity bond issues in Chile, concluded in his piece that the reason for the market failures of those two attempted issues was the moral hazard problem. In referring to longevity risk, his explanation of the problem was “… it is remote and of low probability, and while it could jeopardize the firm's solvency, the government would have no choice but to intervene and bail out insurers, since all firms would be hit at the same time. Therefore, the optimal rational choice is to keep going or ‘keep dancing.’” The “keep dancing” is the moral hazard problem. The analysis here provides a simple model that captures longevity risk and the moral hazard problem; the moral hazard problem generates what is referred to as an agency problem in finance, e.g., see Jensen and Meckling (Reference Jensen and Meckling1976) for a discussion of agency costs. The agency problem exists even in the absence of any perceived government bailout. The optimal corporate choice, ceteris paribus, is to not hedge longevity risk. The analysis shows that the insolvency risk caused by the longevity risk yields an agency problem that is also called the under-investment problem. Finally, the analysis contributes to the literature by showing that the buy-in, buy-out or longevity bond can hedge the risk, solve the under-investment problem and create value for the pension fund and the current shareholders.

The paper is structured as follows: the financial market model for a corporation and its pension fund is constructed in the next section. The model is a complete financial market model like that first constructed by Arrow (Reference Arrow1963), Debreu (Reference Debreu1959), and subsequently by MacMinn (Reference MacMinn1987) and others. Some of the financial instruments for hedging longevity risk, i.e., buy-in and buy-out contracts, are considered in subsequent sections. The buy-ins and buy-outs are considered because the market for these instruments have been successful while those for other longevity risk transfer instruments such as longevity bonds have failed. The choice of a buy-in or buy-out contract is made because of the simplicity of the contracts and the active markets for them. The longevity bond is also modeled here even though there has not been a successful issue. The analysis of the longevity bond shows that it may also be used to successfully hedge the longevity risk and solve the under-investment problem even if there is basis risk. For each hedging instrument, we show that the stock value of the hedged firm is less than that of the unhedged firm, ceteris paribus, if the firm faces insolvency risk. It is the insolvency risk in conjunction with limited liability that introduces an agency cost for corporate management. Although hedging with the buy-ins, buy-outs, or longevity bond increases pension fund value, that same hedging, ceteris paribus, reduces the value of the current shareholders' stake in the firm. Since corporate management acts in the interests of current shareholders,Footnote 6 that management chooses not to hedge the longevity risk. Next, we show that if the firm has risky investment opportunities that yield sufficiently positive risk-adjusted net present values, hedging the longevity risk with these instruments may solve what would otherwise have been an under-investment problem. The solution to the under-investment yields an increase in value for the pension fund and for the current shareholders. The last section provides concluding remarks.

2. The financial market model

Consider a corporation in a competitive economy operating between the dates t = 0 and 1. The dates t = 0 and 1 are subsequently referred to as now and then, respectively. Decisions are made now, and payoffs on those decisions are received then. The economy is composed of corporations and risk-averse investors. Investors make portfolio decisions to maximize their expected utility subject to a budget constraint.Footnote 7 The corporation of interest here is a firm operating in a market for goods and services, making an investment decision and managing its corporate pension plan.

The firm is assumed to operate in competitive markets and makes investment decisions to advance its operations. The firm also has a pension plan for its employees that consists of an asset portfolio to cover the pension liabilities. Let Π (I,  ω) denote the random payoff then on the investment of I dollars now; suppose that the investment frontier Π is increasing and concave in the dollar investment. Let A and L denote the asset and liability values then for the pension fund. Suppose the asset and liability values increase in state.Footnote 8

The firm also faces common capital market risks such as interest rate and insolvency risks in addition to the longevity risk on its pension plan. The returns on its pension asset portfolio payoff then, and the liability portfolio is composed of the pension payouts made then. The following partially summarizes the notation used in the development of the model:

The corporation is managed by an individual who makes decisions now. This individual will be referred to as the chief executive officer (CEO). The CEO makes the same decisions that other investors make and, in addition, makes decisions on behalf of the corporation. To distinguish between the two sets of decisions, the investor decisions on a portfolio are called decisions on personal account while the CEO decisions on investment, financing, and risk management are called decisions on corporate account. The CEO, like the investors, has an increasing concave utility function that expresses preferences for consumption now and then. The CEO makes decisions to maximize expected utility subject to a budget constraint and the corporate financing constraint. All decisions on personal and corporate account are made now, and the payoffs on those decisions occur then. We assume that the CEO is paid in salary and stock; it follows that the CEO makes decisions on corporate account to maximize the current shareholder value subject to any financing constraint.Footnote 10

3. The unhedged firm

Suppose the financial markets are competitive. In the absence of any hedge and letting b denote the promised payment on debt issued to finance the firm's capital investment, the stock market value of the firm may be expressed as:Footnote 11

(1)$$S^u = \int_0^\zeta {max\{ {0, \;\Pi + A-L-b} \} } dP$$

where max{0, Π + A − L − b} is the firm's payoff in the absence of any hedging instrument.

3.1 No insolvency risk

First, consider the firm with no insolvency risk due to its investment decisions or pension plan. Suppose the firm finances any investment decision with debt. No insolvency provides a base case in which the firm makes decisions in the interests of all the stakeholders, i.e., stockholders, bondholders, and pension holders. The stock value in this case is

(2)$$S^u = \int_0^\zeta {( {\Pi + A-L-b} ) } dP$$

The stock value may also be expressed as

(3)$$\eqalign{S^u& = \int_0^\zeta \Pi dP + \int_0^\zeta {( {A-L} ) } dP-\int_0^\zeta b \,dP \cr & = V^{\rm e} + \Delta -B( b) } $$

where V is the corporate value, Δ is the over or underfunding of the pension plan, and B(b) is the value of the safe debt issue used to finance the firm's investment decision. The firm's constrained maximization problem is

(4)$$\eqalign{& maximize\,S^u( 1) \cr & subject\,to\,B( b) = I} $$

The Lagrange function is

$$L( {I, \;b, \;\lambda } ) = S^u( I) + \lambda ( B( b) -I) $$

and we have the following first order conditions:

(5)$$D_1L = \int_0^\zeta {D_1\Pi dP-\lambda = 0} $$
(6)$$D_2L = {-}\int_0^\zeta {dP + \lambda } \int_0^\zeta {dP = 0} $$
(7)$$D_3L = B( b) -I = 0$$

It follows by (6) and (5), that the optimal investment is the socially efficient level I e implicitly defined by

(8)$$\int_0^\zeta {D_1\Pi ( I^e, \;\omega ) dP( \omega ) -1 = 0} $$

The investment I e maximizes the stock value of the corporation without changing the value of the debt or pension plan. Given the financing constraint in (4), it follows that the stock market value of the firm may also be expressed as

(9)$$\eqalign{S^u& = V^e-B( b) + \Delta \cr & = npv( {I^e} ) + \Delta } $$

where npv is the risk-adjusted net present value of the investment I e. This investment maximizes the npv while Δ is the over or underfunding of the pension plan; if the plan is underfunded, then the firm invests if and only if the net present value covers the underfunding and provides a return for shareholders.

3.2 Insolvency risk

From the firm's perspective, the pension plan exposes the corporation to the risk that the pensioners live longer than expected, and so we refer to it as longevity risk. The longevity risk may yield insolvency risk if the pension asset portfolio and corporate payoff are insufficient to cover the pension liability.

To note the pension and insolvency risk it is instructive to rewrite the stock value. Observe that max{0,  Π + A − L − b} = Π + A − L − b + max{0,  L + b − (Π + A)} and so the stock value may also be expressed as follows:

(10)$$\eqalign{S^u& = \int_0^\zeta {( {\Pi + A-L-b} ) dP \;+ } \int_0^\zeta {max\{ {0, \;L + b-( {\Pi + A} ) } \} } dP \cr & = V + V_A-V_L-B( b) + ( {P^b + P^u} ) } $$

where V is the corporate value, V A and V L are pension asset and liability portfolio values and (P b + P u) is the put option value.Footnote 12 Letting γ be implicitly defined by the condition Π(I,  γ) + A(γ) − L(γ) = 0 and δ is implicitly defined by the condition Π(I,  δ) + A(δ) − L(δ) − b = 0, these values are

$$V_A = \int_0^\zeta {A\,} dP\,and\,V_L = \int_0^\zeta L \,dP$$

and

$$\eqalign{P^b + P^u& = \int_0^\delta {( {L + b-( {\Pi + A} ) } ) dP} \cr & = \left({\int_0^\gamma {( {L + b-L} ) dP + \int_\gamma^\delta {( {L + b-( {\Pi + A} ) } ) } } dP} \right)\cr & \quad + \int_0^\gamma {( {L-( {\Pi + A} ) } ) } dP} $$

The pension liability value and put option values are shown in Figures 1 and 2. Given insolvency risk, the firm puts P b to bondholders and P u to the pension holders.

Figure 1. The Unhedged Firm.

Figure 2. The Option Values.

If there is an implicit or explicit guarantee by the government, then the difference is put to the government rather than the annuity holders.

Now consider the investment decision made by the corporate manager. Given appropriately aligned incentives, the manager will select the investment to maximize the stock value subject to a financing constraint.Footnote 13 Without loss of generality, suppose the firm issues debt to cover the investment expenditure; let D(b) denote the value of the debt, and b represent the promised payment then. The manager's constrained maximization problem is

$$\eqalign{& maximize\,S^u \cr & subject\,to\,D( b) = I} $$

where

(11)$$S^u = \int_\delta ^\zeta {( {\Pi + A-L-b} ) dP} $$

and

(12)$$D( b ) = \int_\gamma ^\delta {( {\Pi + A-L} ) } dP + \int_\delta ^\zeta b \,dP$$

Let L(I,  b,  λ) = S u + λ(D(b) − I) be the Lagrange function for the constrained maximization problem. Then the first order conditions are as follows:

(13)$$D_1L = \int_\delta ^\varsigma {D_1\Pi \,dP + \lambda \left({\int_\gamma^\delta {D_1\Pi \,dP-1} } \right) = 0} $$
(14)$$D_2L = {-}\int_\delta ^\zeta {dP + \lambda \int_\delta ^\zeta {dP} = 0} $$
(15)$$D_3L = D( b ) -I = 0$$

Let I u denote the optimal investment decision for the manager. Note that by (14), the Lagrange multiplier is one, and so the first-order condition for the optimal investment is

(16)$$D_1L = \int_\gamma ^\zeta {D_1} \Pi dP-1 = 0.$$

It is useful to compare the investment decision with the same decision made in the absence of insolvency risk. Let I e denote that decision and call it the socially efficient investment; the socially efficient decision is made in the interests of all stakeholders in the corporation rather than just the stockholders. The socially efficient investment will satisfy the following condition:

(17)$$\int_0^\zeta {D_1\Pi dP-1 = \int_0^\gamma {D_1\Pi dP + \int_\gamma ^\zeta {D_1\Pi dP-1 = 0} } } $$

(8) implicitly defines the socially efficient investment. If (17) is evaluated at the optimal investment level for the unhedged firm, i.e., I u, then the first term on the right-hand side of (17) remains and makes (17) positive; it follows by the second-order condition that the manager selects I u < I e. Therefore, the unhedged firm underinvests relative to the socially efficient level of investment. The stock market value of the unhedged firm may also be written as follows:

(18)$$\eqalign{S^u& = V + V_A-V_L-B( b ) + ( {P^b + P^u} ) \cr & = V-( {B( b ) -P^b} ) + \Delta + P^u \cr & = V-D( b ) + \Delta + P^u \cr & = V-I + \Delta + P^u \cr & = npv( I ) + \Delta + P^u} $$

Given insolvency risk due to the pension fund and debt liabilities, the CEO only makes the capital investment decision if the risk-adjusted net present value exceeds any underfunding plus the pension put value.

It is also possible to obtain the value of the pension fund for the unhedged firm. If the value of the pension asset portfolio is less than the liability value, then the pension plan is underfunded, and Δ is negative. The value of the pension fund is then F u = V L − P u.

4. The buy-in

The liability claims in the pension plan are one source of the insolvency risk for the firm. This risk becomes more of a problem for the firm as longevity increases. The firm can absorb the risk or chose to manage it in some way. Buy-in and buy-out instruments represent a growing segment of the markets for longevity risk transfer. The buy-in is considered first.

A buy-in is a transaction with an insurer in which the firm purchases an annuity that pays the pension claims as they are realized. Without loss of generality, we will suppose that the firm uses debt to finance the annuity purchase from an insurer. Then the constraint in the constrained maximization problem becomes

$$D( b ) = I + \int_0^\zeta {L\,} dP$$

Hence, a debt instrument replaces the pension liability as well as providing funds for the capital investment. The stock value for the buy-in becomes

$$S^i = \int_\gamma ^\zeta {( {\Pi + A-L-b + L} ) dP = \int_\gamma ^\zeta {( {\Pi + A-b} ) dP} } $$

where S i denotes the hedged corporate equity value (Figure 3). Similarly, let I i denote the stock value maximizing investment decision. The Lagrange function is

$$L^i( {I, \;b, \;\lambda } ) = S^i + \lambda \left({D( b ) -I-\int_0^\zeta L \,dP} \right)$$

and the first order conditions are as follows:

(19)$$D_1L^i = \int_\gamma ^\zeta {D_1\Pi dP-\lambda } \left({\int_0^\gamma {D_1\Pi dP-1} } \right) = 0$$
(20)$$D_2L^i = {-}\int_\gamma ^\zeta {dP + \lambda } \int_\gamma ^\zeta {dP} = 0$$
(21)$$D_3L^i = D( b ) -I-V_L = 0$$

Figure 3. The Hedged Firm.

From (20) and (19) it follows that I i = I e > I u and so the buy-in resolves the under-investment problem. This under-investment problem is similar to that noted by Myers (Reference Myers1977); also, see Mayers and Smith (Reference Mayers and Smith1987), Garven and MacMinn (Reference Garven and MacMinn1993), MacMinn and Garven (Reference MacMinn, Garven and Dionne2011) for insurance schemes designed to alleviate the under-investment. Also, see Jensen and Meckling (Reference Jensen and Meckling1976), Green (Reference Green1984), MacMinn (Reference MacMinn1993) and MacMinn (Reference MacMinn2005b) for earlier examples of the agency costs of publicly traded firms and the impact of those costs on production, investment and financing decisions.

The shareholder value may also be expressed as

(22)$$\eqalign{S^i& = \int_0^\zeta {( {\Pi + A-b} ) dP + \int_0^\zeta {max\{ {0, \;b-( {\Pi + A} ) } \} dP} } \cr & = V + V_A-( {B( b ) -P^i} ) \cr & = V + V_A-D( b ) \cr & = V + V_A-( {V_L + I^i} ) \cr & = V-I^i + V_A-V_L \cr & = npv( {I^i} ) + \Delta } $$

where B(b) is the safe debt value and P i is the put option value, npv is the risk-adjusted net present value of the investment and Δ = V A − V L is the under or over funding of the pension plan. The difference in stock value between the unhedged and hedged firms is

(23)$$\eqalign{S^i-S^u& = npv( {I^i} ) + \Delta -( {npv( {I^u} ) + \Delta + P^u} ) \cr & = npv( {I^i} ) -npv( {I^u} ) -P^u} $$

Using (23), it may be noted that if the CEO managed the firm's longevity risk with a buy-in but maintained the same investment level at I u then the difference in stock value would be −P u since the buy-in would eliminate that put option value. Hence, the CEO acting in the interests of current shareholders would not transfer the longevity risk with a buy-in.

The CEO, however, has the ability to make a capital investment on behalf of the firm. Equation (22) shows that the CEO making the investment decision to maximize current shareholder value will equivalently make the corporate investment decision to maximize the risk adjusted net present value of the project. It follows, using (23), that the CEO will make the socially efficient investment decision and complete the buy-in if the increase in risk-adjusted net present value exceeds the loss in pension option value.

5. The buy-out

Consider a buy-out. In this case, the pension plan is transferred to another firm, e.g., insurer or reinsurer. The pension asset and liability portfolios that compose the plan are transferred. Suppose further that the pension plan is under-funded in the sense that the value of the asset portfolio is less than that of the liability portfolio, i.e.,

$$\int_0^\zeta {( {A-L} ) dP = \Delta } $$

In the under-funded case, Δ is negative, and the firm must raise −Δ dollars as part of the payment for the buy-out. The buy-out consists of this payment plus the transfer of the pension plan portfolios. The corporate payoff was Π + A − L before the buy-out while it is Π − b after the buy-out, where b is the promised payment on a bond issue needed to raise the −Δ dollars plus any investment expenditure. The constrained maximization problem for the firm in planning the buy-out and investment is

$$\eqalign{& maximize\,S^o( I ) \cr & subject\,to\,D( b ) = {-}\Delta + I} $$

where

(24)$$\eqalign{S^o& = \int_\delta ^\zeta {( {\Pi -b} ) dP} \cr D( b ) & = \int_0^\delta {( {\Pi + A} ) dP + \int_0^\zeta b } \,dP} $$

Letting the Lagrange function in this case be L(I,  b,  λ) = S o + λ(D + Δ − I). Then

(25)$$D_1L = \int_\delta ^\zeta {D_1\Pi \,dP + \lambda \left({\int_0^{^\delta } {D_1\Pi \,dP-1} } \right) = 0} $$
(26)$$D_2L = {-}\int_\delta ^\zeta {dP + \lambda \int_\delta ^\zeta {dP} = 0} $$
(27)$$D_3L = D( b ) + \Delta -I = 0$$

From (26) it follows that λ = 1 and so by (25) it follows that

$$D_1L = \int_0^\zeta {D_1\Pi \,} dP-1 = 0$$

Therefore, the investment level that maximizes this constrained maximization problem is I o which is implicitly defined by (25). It also follows then that I o = I i = I e. The buy-out solves the under-investment problem just as the buy-in does.

Next, recall that the stock value of the firm after the buy-out is

(28)$$\eqalign{S^o& = \int_\delta ^\zeta {( {\Pi -b} ) dP} \cr & = \int_0^\zeta {max\{ {0, \;( {\Pi -b} ) } \} dP} \cr & = \int_0^\zeta {( {\Pi -b} ) dP + \int_0^\zeta {max\{ {0, \;b-\Pi } \} dP\,0} } \cr & = V-B( b ) + P^o \cr & = V-D( b ) \cr & = V + \Delta -I^o \cr & = npv( {I^o} ) + \Delta } $$

It may be noted that the net present value of the firm investment in the buy-in and buy-out cases is the same, and so the stock value of the firm will also be the same in each case.

6. Longevity bonds without basis risk

Finally, consider a longevity bond. Let B(ω) be the longevity bond payoff then in state ω. Suppose there is no basis risk so that the bond payoff matches the pension claims then, i.e., B(ω) = L(ω) for each state ω ∈ Ω. If the corporation hedges the longevity risk with a longevity bond, the corporate payoff becomes Π + A − L + B − b = Π + A − b. Without loss of generality, suppose the corporation raises the money for investment and the longevity bond with a debt issue. Then the financing constraint is

$$D( b ) = I + \int_0^\zeta B ( \omega ) dP( \omega ) $$

where the debt value is

$$D( b ) = \int_0^\delta {( {\Pi + A} ) dP + \int_\delta ^\zeta b } \,dP$$

and the stock value given the longevity bond is

$$S^l = \int_\delta ^\zeta {( {\Pi + A-b} ) dP} $$

The Lagrange function for this constrained maximization problem is

$$L( {I, \;b, \;\lambda } ) = S^l( {I, \;b} ) + \lambda \left({D( b ) -I-\int_0^\zeta {B( \omega ) dP} } \right)$$

and the first order conditions are:

$$D_1L = \int_\delta ^\zeta {D_1} \Pi \,dP + \lambda \left({\int_0^\delta {D_1\Pi \,dP-1} } \right) = 0$$
$$D_2L = {-}\int_\delta ^\zeta {dP + \lambda } \,\int_\delta ^\zeta {dP} = 0$$
$$D_3L = D( b ) -I-\int_0^\zeta {BdP = 0} $$

It follows from these first order conditions that the optimal investment I l is implicitly defined by the condition:

$$\int_0^\zeta D _1\Pi \,dP = 1$$

and so, it also follows that the longevity bond hedge with no basis risk solves the under-investment problem and makes I l = I e > I u. It may be noted that the stock value of the corporation hedged with a longevity bond may be equivalently expressed as

$$\eqalign{S^l& = \int_0^\zeta {max\{ {0, \;\Pi + A-b} \} dP} \cr & = \int_0^\zeta {( {\Pi + {\rm A}-b} ) dP + \int_0^\zeta {max\{ {0, \;b-( {\Pi + A} ) } \} dP} } \cr & = V + V_A-B( b ) + P^b \cr & = V + V_A-D( b ) \cr & = V-I + V_A-V_L \cr & = npv + \Delta } $$

Hence the longevity bond with no basis risk solves the under-investment problem that exists for the unhedged firm and yields I l = I e > I u.

7. Longevity bond with basis risk

If there is basis risk, then the payoff on a longevity bond is tied to a longevity index that is not perfectly correlated with the longevity of the pension fund. The corporation will not be able to perfectly hedge the longevity risk of the pension fund. It may, however, be able to reduce the longevity risk and alleviate the under-investment problem.

Let the basis risk be denoted by L(ω) − L I(ω). This represents the difference between the realized liability of the pension fund in a particular state versus the realized value of a longevity index where the index is based on a similar but not identical population. Suppose that longevity index over-estimates the pension fund liability then for lower states while the index under-estimates the pension fund liability then for higher states as shown in Figure 4. Let B l denote the risk adjusted market value of the longevity bond so that (Figure 5)

$$B^l = \int_0^\zeta {L_I( \omega ) } \,dP( \omega ) \equiv V_I$$

Figure 4. Basis Risk.

Figure 5. Corporate Payoff with Basis Risk.

If the corporation hedges with this longevity bond, then the shareholder payoff becomes

$$\eqalign{& max\{ {0, \;\Pi + A-( {L-L_I} ) -b} \} \cr & = \Pi + A-( {L-L_I} ) -b \cr & \quad\hskip 1pt+ max\{ {0, \;b-( {\Pi + A-( {L-L_I} ) } ) } \} } $$

and the stock market value of the hedged corporation with a longevity bond is

$$S^l = \int_\delta ^\zeta {( {\Pi + A-( {L-L_I} ) -b} ) dP} $$

and the bond value of a new issue is

$$D( b ) = \int_0^\delta {( {\Pi + A-( {L-L_I} ) } ) dP + \int_\delta ^\zeta {bdP} } $$

The constrained maximization problem becomes

$$\eqalign{& maximize\,S^l \cr & subject\,to\,D( b) = I + B^l} $$

The Lagrange function is

$$L( {I, \;b, \;\lambda } ) = S^l + \lambda ( {D( b ) -I-B^l} ) $$

and the first order conditions are as follows:

$$D_1L = \int_\delta ^\zeta {D_1\Pi } \,dP + \lambda \left({\int_0^\delta {D_1\Pi \,dP-1} } \right) = 0$$
$$D_2L = {-}\int_\delta ^\zeta {dP + \lambda \int_\delta ^\zeta {dP = 0} } $$
$$D_3L = D( b ) -I-\int_0^\zeta {BdP = 0} $$

As before the stock market value of the corporation hedging with the longevity bond is

$$\eqalign{S^l& = V + V_A-( {V_L-V_I} ) -B( b ) + P^b \cr & = V + V_A-( {V_L-V_I} ) -D( b ) \cr & = V + V_A-( {V_L-V_I} ) -( {I + V_I} ) \cr & = npv( {I^l} ) + \Delta } $$

where npv(I l) is the risk adjusted net present value of the investment I l = I e. The last equality follows by the financing constraint that makes the debt value equal to the investment expenditure plus the value of the indexed longevity bond. Here again, the longevity bond solves the under-investment problem and allows the firm to select the efficient investment level if the risk adjusted net present value of the efficient investment is greater than the net present value plus the put option value of the unhedged corporation. The basis risk introduces a costFootnote 14 but if the longevity bond hedges the insolvency risk, then the longevity bond will reduce or eliminate the under-investment problem.

8. Concluding remarks

The analysis here has shown that the buy-in and buy-out instruments purchased from insurers can be used to manage the longevity risk of the corporate pension plan. These instruments transfer the risk and increase the value of the pension plan, but ceteris paribus, such hedging was shown to reduce shareholder value. Furthermore, the analysis has shown that if the corporation has an investment opportunity but a pension plan that exposes it to insolvency risk, it faces an under-investment problem. The CEO invests to the point at which the marginal risk-adjusted present value of the investment equals one plus the marginal agency cost of the under-investment problem; the marginal agency cost is represented by the marginal loss in the put option value P u. Effective risk management instruments eliminate or reduce the marginal agency cost. The model introduced here is the first theoretical model to show that buy-ins and buy-outs eliminate the agency cost and so the under-investment.

The model predictions are supported by some empirical evidence. For example, the deals by GM and Verizon with Prudential in 2012. These two deals are two of the largest buy-out transactions to date. Prior to the pension buy-out announcement, GM shares had gone down by 3.4% as it released weaker-than-expected auto sales figures. However, the stock recouped its losses and rose as much as 5.1% on the news of the pension buy-out on June 1, 2012, i.e., see Seetharaman and Klayman (Reference Seetharaman and Klayman2012). Similarly, on October 17, 2012, Verizon shares closed at $44.72, up 1.5%, after it announced its buy-out deal with Prudential.Footnote 15 Also, consistent with the model's prediction, after the pension buy-outs, both companies increased their investments significantly.

The analysis also shows that a longevity bond with or without basis risk can be used to manage the longevity risk. With no basis risk, the results are equivalent to those of the buy-in and buy-out. With basis risk, the risk management becomes more difficult because the index used for the liability payoff does not perfectly match the actual liability; this, in turn, increases the cost of the risk management. Despite this cost, the analysis shows in a simple setting that an instrument with basis risk can be used to manage the longevity risk and eliminate the under-investment problem.

Here the longevity risk was the source of the insolvency risk and so the longevity linked financial instruments could be used to manage that risk. An expanded model in which there are more sources of insolvency risk will make the instruments considered here possibly less effective. Such a model while possibly showing that the longevity linked instruments cannot eliminate the agency cost associated with the under-investment problem may also show that those instruments will reduce the agency cost and that other hedging instruments used in conjunction with them can eliminate the agency cost.

Footnotes

4 See Blake et al. (Reference Blake, Cairns, Coughlan, Dowd and MacMinn2013). for a discussion of the new life market.

5 q is common notation for the mortality rate in actuarial science and so is used here to identify the mortality rate forward contract.

6 Corporate management has a fiduciary responsibility to make decisions in the interests of current shareholders, but it may also be shown that if management is compensated with a salary and corporate stock then that management will make all decisions on corporate account to maximize current shareholder value, e.g., see MacMinn (Reference MacMinn2005a).

7 The investor portfolio decisions yield the demands for all the stock and so determine the basis for the stock prices which in turn form the means to value other financial instruments.

8 The states may be ordered so that the corporate payoff as well as the asset and liability portfolio payoffs are increasing in state. This describes an economy that yields larger dollar payoffs as the state increases, i.e., bigger payoffs yield larger payoffs on capital investments, on portfolio returns and on liability portfolio payoffs since economic improvement leads to longer lives and so bigger payouts on the pension liability portfolio.

9 Partial derivatives will be denoted by D jΠ and D ijΠ. D will denote derivative.

10 See MacMinn (Reference MacMinn1984) and MacMinn (Reference MacMinn2005a).

11 The lines in the figures are straight for simplicity. The shaded areas are proportional to the values. To show this, note that the pension liability value in Figure 1 may be expressed as $V_L = \int_\Omega {p( \omega ) L( \omega ) d\omega } = p( \xi ) \int_\Omega {L( \omega ) d\omega }$ for some ξ ∈ Ω; this follows by the intermediate value theorem of integral calculus.

12 Expressing the corporate stock value using the put value was the method used earlier to motivate the failure of some instruments designed to transfer longevity risk, e.g., see MacMinn and Brockett (Reference MacMinn and Brockett2017). This follows because hedging the longevity risk reduces the put value and so, ceteris paribus, the stock value.

13 The chief executive officer (CEO) of the corporation making a portfolio decision on personal account plus financing, operating and investment decisions on corporate account will make the decision on corporate account to maximize the current shareholder value if he or she is compensated with a salary and corporate stock. If the CEO is compensated in salary and stock options, then the corporate objective function is no longer the current shareholder value. See MacMinn (Reference MacMinn2005a).

14 The basis risk cost is borne by bondholders. To see this let bn be the promised payment on the bond issue in the no basis risk case while bb is the promised payment on the bond issue in the basis risk case. Then D(b n) − D(b b) = (I + V L) − (I + V I) = V L − V I.

15 A search of the news around the GM and Verizon buyout announcement dates was conducted to identify other explanations for the price changes. Except for GM's auto sales announcement, there were no other major events.

References

Arrow, K. J. (1963) The role of securities in the optimal allocation of risk-bearing. Review of Economic Studies 31, 9196.10.2307/2296188CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blake, D. and Burrows, W. (2001) Survivor bonds: Helping to hedge mortality risk. Journal of Risk and Insurance 68(2), 339348.10.2307/2678106CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blake, D., Cairns, A., Coughlan, G., Dowd, K. and MacMinn, R. (2013) The new life market. Journal of Risk and Insurance 80(3), 501558.10.1111/j.1539-6975.2012.01514.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blake, D., Cairns, A. J. and Dowd, K. (2006) Living with mortality: longevity bonds and other mortality-linked securities. British Actuarial Journal 12(1), 153197.10.1017/S1357321700004736CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burne, K. (Jan 6, 2011) Swiss Re Longevity-Risk Deal Opens Door to More. Wall Street Journal – U.S. Edition. New York, NY.Google Scholar
Chen, H. and Cummins, J. D. (2010) Longevity bond premiums: the extreme value approach and risk cubic pricing. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 46(1), 150161.Google Scholar
Debreu, G. (1959) Theory of Value: An Axiomatic Analysis of Economic Equilibrium. Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics, Yale University: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Garven, J. R. and MacMinn, R. D. (1993) The underinvestment problem, bond covenants and insurance. Journal of Risk and Insurance 60(4), 635646.10.2307/253383CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Green, R (1984) Investment incentives, debt, and warrants. Journal of Financial Economics 13, 115136.10.1016/0304-405X(84)90034-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hardy, M. (2005) A matter of life and death. Financial Engineering News: No. 46 November-December 2005: 2017, 2020, p. 17.Google Scholar
Jensen, M. C. and Meckling, W. H. (1976) Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3(4), 305360.10.1016/0304-405X(76)90026-XCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lin, Y. and Cox, S. H. (2008) Securitization of catastrophe mortality risks. Insurance Mathematics & Economics 42(2), 628637.10.1016/j.insmatheco.2007.06.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacMinn, R. (1984) Financial Markets and the Fisher Model. Austin, TX: The University of Texas.Google Scholar
MacMinn, R. (1987) Insurance and corporate risk management. Journal of Risk and Insurance 54(4), 658677.10.2307/253115CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacMinn, R. D. (1993) On the risk shifting problem and convertible bonds. Advances in Quantitative Analysis of Finance and Accounting 2, 181200.Google Scholar
MacMinn, R. D. (2005a) The Fisher Model and Financial Markets. Singapore; Hackensack, NJ; London: World Scientific Pub.10.1142/5887CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacMinn, R. D. (2005b) On corporate risk management and insurance. Asia-Pacific Journal of Risk and Insurance 1(1), 97119.10.2202/2153-3792.1005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacMinn, R. and Brockett, P. (2017) On the failure (success) of the markets for longevity risk transfer. Journal of Risk and Insurance 84(S1), 299317.10.1111/jori.12205CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacMinn, R. and Garven, J. R. (2011) On the demand for corporate insurance: creating value. In Dionne, G. (ed.), Handbook of Insurance. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers, pp. 487516.Google Scholar
Mayers, D. and Smith, C. W. Jr. (1987) Corporate insurance and the underinvestment problem. Journal of Risk and Insurance 54(1), 4554.10.2307/252881CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myers, S. C. (1977) The determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics 5, 147175.10.1016/0304-405X(77)90015-0CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oppers, S. E., Chikada, K., Eich, F., Imam, P., Kiff, J., Kisser, M., Soto, M. and Sun, T. (2012) The financial impact of longevity risk. Global Financial Stability Report: The Quest for Lasting Stability. Washington DC: International Monetary Fund, pp. 123151.Google Scholar
Seetharaman, D. and Klayman, B. (2012) GM to cut about one-fourth of U.S. pension liability. Reuters.Google Scholar
Zelenko, I. (2014) Longevity risk and the stability of retirement systems: the Chilean longevity bond case. The Journal of Alternative Investments 17(1), 3554.10.3905/jai.2014.17.1.035CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. The Unhedged Firm.

Figure 1

Figure 2. The Option Values.

Figure 2

Figure 3. The Hedged Firm.

Figure 3

Figure 4. Basis Risk.

Figure 4

Figure 5. Corporate Payoff with Basis Risk.