Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-qsmjn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-23T11:38:31.979Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

WHY HASN’T ECONOMIC PROGRESS LOWERED WORK HOURS MORE?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 December 2017

Tyler Cowen*
Affiliation:
Economics, George Mason University

Abstract:

Why hasn’t economic progress lowered work hours more? One of Keynes’s most famous essays is his “Economic Possibilities for Our Grandchildren.” Keynes predicts that within one hundred years — which would bring us to 2030 — most scarcity will have disappeared and most individuals will work no more than fifteen hours a week. My question is a simple one: Why wasn’t Keynes right? Why have working hours remained as long as they have? Why hasn’t progress taken a more leisurely and less material form than what we have observed? Investigating that issue will help us get at the question of just how much progress has occurred. Under one view, Western life has been caught in a kind of rat race, and a lot of the gains of progress are illusory. For instance there is the argument that higher incomes are largely consumed as part of a futile race to win relative status, and living standards aren’t nearly as high as they might appear. Under some alternative scenarios, people haven’t moved to Keynes’s scenario for some good reasons, such as enjoying work more than we might think, or other hypotheses, as I will outline. In that case the observed changes in real income are robust, and measured correctly, or progress may even be greater than income measurements would indicate. I hope that addressing Keynes’s paradox can help us better understand this longstanding debate on the nature of modern progress.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Social Philosophy and Policy Foundation 2017 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

For useful comments I wish to thank Johnny Anomaly, Bryan Caplan, Robin Hanson, David Schmidtz, Alex Tabarrok, Bas van der Vossen, conference participants, and an anonymous referee.

References

1 For a starting point on British living standards in the 1930s, see Broadberry, Stephen and Burhop, Carsten, “Real Wages and Labor Productivity in Britain and Germany, 1871–1938: A Unified Approach to the International Comparison of Living Standards,” Journal of Economic History 70, no. 2 (2010): 400427CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

2 On the distinction between labor force responses at a point in time, and across long swathes of time, see Alesina, Alberto, Glaeser, Edward, and Sacerdote, Bruce, “Work and Leisure in the United States and Europe: Why So Different?” NBER Macroeconomics Annual 20 (2005): 164CrossRefGoogle Scholar; I will return to this theme.

3 Huberman, Michael and Minns, Chris, “The Times They Are Not Changin’: Days and Hours of Work in Old and New Worlds, 1870–2000,” Explorations in Economic History 44, no. 4 (2007): 538–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

4 Bick, Alexander, Fuchs-Schündeln, Nicola, and Lagakos, David, “How Do Average Hours Worked Vary With Development? Cross-Country Evidence and Implications,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 21874 (2016).Google Scholar

5 Huberman and Minns, “The Times They Are Not Changin’,” 541.

6 See for instance Roser, Max, “Working Hours,” Published online at OurWorldInData.org, http://ourworldindata.org/data/economic-development-work-standard-of-living/working-hours/Google Scholar.

7 McGrattan, Ellen R. and Rogerson, Richard, “Changes in Hours Worked, 1950–2000,” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 28, no. 1 (2004): 14Google Scholar, document these claims in detail. On some of the institutional factors behind the move to an eight-hour work day, see Whaples, Robert, “Winning the Eight-Hour Day, 1909–1919,” Journal of Economic History 50, no. 2 (1990): 393406CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

8 McGrattan and Rogerson, “Changes in Hours Worked, 1950–2000,” 16. Note that I have not found a simple way to do a 2010 updated estimate with consistent methodology.

9 This is drawing on Bureau of Labor Statistics data and Ramey, Valerie A. and Francis, Neville, “A Century of Work and Leisure,” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 1, no. 3 (2009): 189224Google Scholar. Slightly different numbers from different years, but with a similar overall trend, can be found in McGrattan and Rogerson, “Changes in Hours Worked, 1950–2000,” 16. It is worth noting that good estimates on how many hours of the workday employees actually work are hard to come by. Other scholars report an estimate of seven percent of the workday being spent not working. See Michael Burda, Katei R. Genadek, and Daniel S. Hamermesh, “Not Working at Work: Loafing, Unemployment and Labor Productivity,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 21923 (2016), 4. This is based on self-reports, however, and arguably the actual amount of shirking is higher. We also don’t know whether this shirking has gone up or down over time, which could affect our estimates of overall trend.

10 On relative female to male wages and labor supply response, see McGrattan and Rogerson, “Changes in Hours Worked, 1950–2000,” 15. For gender convergence by sector, see generally Goldin, Claudia, “A Grand Gender Convergence: Its Last Chapter,” American Economic Review 104, no. 4 (2014): 10911119CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

11 Greenwood, Jeremy and Vandenbroucke, Guillaume, “Hours Worked: Long-Run Trends,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 11629 (2005), 1.Google Scholar

12 McGrattan and Rogerson, “Changes in Hours Worked, 1950–2000,” 20.

13 For an affirmation of the relevance of the substitution effect to Keynes’s argument, see Freeman, Richard B., “Why Do We Work More than Keynes Expected?” in Pecchi, Lorenzo and Piga, Gustavo, editors, Revisiting Keynes: Economic Possibilities for our Grandchildren (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2008), 135–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

14 Costa, Dora L., “Less of a Luxury: The Rise of Recreation Since 1888,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 6054 (1997).Google Scholar

15 Brown, Richard, Coile, Courtney C., and Weisbenner, Scott J., “The Effect of Inheritance Receipt on Retirement,” Review of Economics and Statistics 92, no. 2 (2010): 425–34CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

16 Joulfaian, David and Wilhelm, Mark, “Inheritance and Labor Supply,” Journal of Human Resources 29, no. 4 (1994): 1205–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

17 Krueger, Alan B. and Pischke, Jorn-Steffen, “The Effect of Social Security on Labor Supply: A Cohort Analysis of the Notch Generation,” Journal of Labor Economics 10, no. 4 (1992): 412–37CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

18 Cesarini, David, Lindqvist, Erik, Notowidigdo, Matthew J., and Ostling, Robert, “The Effect of Wealth On Individual and Household Labor Supply: Evidence from Swedish Lotteries,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 21762 (2015)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

19 For one classic statement of this argument (which I am not endorsing), see Diamond, Jared, “The Worst Mistake in the History of the Human Race,” Discover Magazine (1987): 6466Google Scholar.

20 See Rachel Ngai, L. and Pissarides, Christopher A., “Trends in Hours and Economic Growth,” Review of Economic Dynamics 11, no. 2 (2008): 239–56CrossRefGoogle Scholar; on these points, and on the Middletown study see Greenwood and Vandenbroucke, “Hours Worked: Long-Run Trends,” 1.

21 See Ngai and Pissarides, “Trends in Hours and Economic Growth,” on Europe versus America; and on the import of labor taxation, see Prescott, Edward C., “Why Do Americans Work So Much More Than Europeans?” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 28, no. 1 (2004): 213Google Scholar. On Sweden and America, see Conny Olovsson, “Why Do Europeans Work So Little?” International Economic Review 50, no. 1 (2009): 39–61. If you are wondering, time spent with children has gone up by about two hours a week, for males and females each, when children are present; of course it can be debated how much of this is work and how much is leisure (Aguiar and Hurst, “American Time Allocation: 1965–2005,” 61).

22 Kopecky, Karen A., “The Trend in Retirement,” International Economic Review 52, no. 2 (2011): 287316, at 287.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

23 Ibid., 192.

24 See Hetschko, Clemens, Knabe, Andreas, and Schoeb, Ronnie, “Changing Identity: Retiring from Unemployment,” The Economic Journal 124, no. 575 (2013): 149–66CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

25 Alesina, Glaeser, and Sacerdote, “Why So Different?” 3.

26 Wolf, Martin, “America’s Labour Market Is Not Working,” The Financial Times, Nov. 3, 2015Google Scholar.

27 Murray, Charles A., Coming Apart: The State of White America, 1960–2010 (New York: Crown Forum, 2013)Google Scholar; Isabel V. Sawhill, “Where Have All the Workers Gone?” Brookings Institution, Nov. 17, 2015; Wolf, America’s Labour Market.”

28 Wolf, America’s Labour Market.”

29 Schrager, Allison, “An Entire Generation of Young American Workers is Missing Crucial Skills,” Quartz, Aug. 31, 2015Google Scholar.

30 See Aguiar, Mark and Hurst, Erik, “Measuring Trends in Leisure: The Allocation of Time Over Five Decades,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 122, no. 3 (2007): 9691006CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Aguiar, Mark and Hurst, Erik, “A Summary of Trends in American Time Allocation: 1965–2005,” Social Indicators Research 93, no. 1 (2009): 5764CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Dora L. Costa, “The Unequal Work Day: A Long-Term View,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 6419 (1998).

31 Prescott, “Why Do Americans Work So Much More Than Europeans?” 2.

32 Alesina, Glaeser, and Sacerdote, “Why So Different?” 29.

33 For two versions of this hypothesis, see Frank, Robert H. “Context is More Important Than Keynes Realized,” in Pecchi, Lorenzo and Piga, Gustavo, editors, Revisiting Keynes: Economic Possibilities for our Grandchildren (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2008), 143–50CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Chris Thron, “Lifestyle Tradeoffs and the Decline of Societal Well-Being: An Agent-based Model,” Physics and Society (2015), http://arxiv.org/abs/1508.03524.

34 Alpizar, Francisco, Carlsson, Fredrik, and Johansson-Stenman, Olof, “How Much Do We Care About Absolute Versus Relative Income and Consumption?” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 56, no. 3 (2005): 405–21CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

35 For one attempt to apply relative status to explain cross-national differences in labor hours, see Bowles, Samuel and Park, Hongjin, “Emulation, Inequality, and Work Hours: Was Thorstein Veblen Right?” The Economic Journal 115, no. 507 (2005): F397F412CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Note that their claim that inequality should predict higher work hours, through a status effect, need not follow. It could just as easily be that people “close together” in terms of income and background care more about their relative status; more concretely, people may care more about their status relative to the rest of their high school class, or their brother-in-law, than relative to Bill Gates. At the very least this would seem to be an open question.

36 Charles, Kerwin, Hurst, Erik, and Roussanov, Nick, “Conspicuous Consumption and Race,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 124, no. 2 (2009): 425–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

37 On this comparison, see Blodget, Henry, “Over the Past 150 Years, There Has Been a Profound Shift in What Humans Do With Their Time,” Business Insider, Dec. 27, 2014Google Scholar.

38 On the latter point, see Strulik, Holger, “How Status Concerns Can Make Us Rich and Happy,” Economica 82, no. 1 (2015): 1217–40Google Scholar.

39 See Veblen, Thornstein, The Theory of the Leisure Class (New York: Modern Library, 1934), 71.Google Scholar

40 Alpizar, Carlsson, and Johansson-Stenman, “Absolute Versus Relative Income and Consumption.”

41 For a version of this hypothesis, combined with some insights from the zero- or negative-sum status hypothesis, see Stiglitz, Joseph E., “Toward a General Theory of Consumerism: Reflections on Keynes’s Economic Possibilities for Our Grandchildren,” Pecchi, Lorenzo and Piga, Gustavo, editors, Revisiting Keynes Economic Possibilities for our Grandchildren (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2008), 4185Google Scholar.

42 Friedman, Benjamin M., “Work and Consumption in an Era of Unbalanced Technological Advance,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 21713 (2015)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

43 For two looks at monopsony, see Boal, William M. and Michael R. Ransom, “Monopsony in the Labor Market,” Journal of Economic Literature 35, no. 1 (1997): 86112Google Scholar; Orley Ashenfelter, Henry S. Farber, and Michael R. Ransom, “Modern Models of Monopsony in Labor Markets: A Brief Survey,” IZA Discussion Paper No. 4915 (2010). On Walmart, see Alessandro Bonnanno and Rigoberto A. Lopez, “Is Wal-Mart a Monopsony? Evidence from Local Labor Markets,” (2009, unpublished). For a look at why the monopsony model has not won over most economists, most of all as an explanation of medium- to long-run phenomena, see Kuhn, Peter, “Is Monopsony the Right Way to Model Labor Markets? A Review of Alan Manning’s Monopsony in Motion,” International Journal of the Economics of Business 11, no. 3 (2004): 369–78CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

44 For analyses of some related scenarios under monopsony, see Viscusi, Kip, “Union, Labor Market Structure, and the Welfare Implications of the Quality of Work,” Journal of Labor Research 1, no. 1 (1980): 175–92CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Alison L. Booth and Gylfi Zoega, “Why Do Firms Invest in General Training? ‘Good’ Firms and ‘Bad’ Firms as a Source of Monopsony Power,” (2000, unpublished); and Francis Green, Stephen Machin, and Alan Manning, “The Employer Size-Wage Effect: Can Dynamic Monopsony Provide an Explanation?” Oxford Economic Papers 48 (1996): 433–55.

45 Pencavel, John, “The Labor Supply of Self-Employed Workers: The Choice of Working Hours in Worker Co-Ops,” Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper No. 13-036 (2014), 2CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

46 See also Pencavel, John, “Whose Preferences are Revealed in Hours of Work?” Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper No. 15-025 (2015)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

47 For some evidence that women adjust better to part-time work and lower-skill work, see Gregory, Mary and Connolly, Sara, “The Price of Reconciliation: Part-Time Work, Families and Women’s Satisfaction,” The Economic Journal 118, no. 526 (2008): F1F7CrossRefGoogle Scholar. On whether evidence shows a wage gap between part-time and full-time workers by gender, see Hirsch, Barry T., “Why Do Part-time Workers Earn Less? The Role of Worker and Job Skills,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 58, no. 4 (2003): 525–51CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

48 Rogerson, Richard, “Understanding Differences in Hours Worked,” Review of Economic Dynamics 9, no. 3 (2006): 365409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar